1 Introduction

The choice of environmental policy instruments has been extensively debated since the seminal contribution of Pigou (1920) on using taxes and subsidies to internalize welfare losses caused by externalities. The environmental economics literature distinguishes between ’command and control’ (CAC) approaches (e.g. environmental protection amendments) and ’market based incentives’ (MBI) (e.g. environmental taxes, tradable permits). Although economic theory preferred MBIs because of their cost effectiveness, CAC has been the major instrument for a long time. During the 1990s, MBIs became more popular, i.e. environmental taxes in the beginning of the 1990s and tradable permits in the late 1990s (e.g. the Kyoto protocol in 1997) (Norregaard and Reppelin-Hill 2000). Currently, environmental taxes are enjoying a renaissance (Krukowska 2020).

While almost every microeconomic textbook covers the basic models of environmental policy’s welfare implications in first-best and second-best worlds, economic theory and empirical evidence on its effects on firm behaviour and performance are sparse and provide conflicting guidance, though being fundamental for designing green tax reforms. First, the ’pollution haven hypothesis’ claims that firms relocate to countries with weak environmental standards when environmental taxes rise, reducing profits, productivity and inputs by limiting production possibilities (Commins et al. 2011). Conversely, the ’factor endowment hypothesis’ suggests that employing available clean natural resources improves production possibilities and productivity (Copeland and Taylor 2004). Similarly, the ’Porter hypothesis’ asserts that environmental regulation spurs firms to innovate, increasing productivity and investment (Porter 1991; Porter and Van der Linde 1995). To provide empirical evidence on these conflicting hypothesis, I examine the impacts of environmental taxes on company performance and behaviour employing micro-data on Central European manufacturing firms from 2009 to 2017.

Many empirical studies examine the environmental benefits of climate policies, while only few studies, primarily undertaken at country- or industry-level, analyse impacts of environmental policy on firm behaviour. Leiter et al. (2011) investigate effects of industry expenditure on environmental protection and country-level environmental tax revenue on firm investment, and find positive, but diminishing effects. Enevoldsen et al. (2007) estimate responses of competitiveness and output to energy taxes and find significantly negative impacts, whereas Henderson and Millimet (2005) observe insignificant impacts of environmental stringency on state-level output. Next, Aziz et al. (2021) conclude that environmental policy stringency negatively affects economic growth in the short-run, but positively in the long run. Besides, Franco and Marin (2017) investigate how environmental tax rates and their spillovers affect innovation and efficiency.

Conversely, only few studies employ firm-level data. Fujii et al. (2016) identify technical innovators in the area of CO2 emissions using Chinese firm-level data. Martin et al. (2014) observe insignificant effects of carbon taxation on British manufacturing firms’ employment, gross output and productivity, and observe significantly negative impacts on energy intensity and electricity use. Similarly, Yang et al. (2021) find significantly negative effects of tightening SO2 removal rates on Chinese firm- and industry-level productivity. In contrast, Commins et al. (2011) find positive effects of energy taxes on productivity and returns on capital, negative impacts on employment, and mixed effects on investment of European firms. Broberg et al. (2013) regress Swedish manufacturing firms’ productivity on distributed lags of investment in pollution control and prevention, rejecting the Porter hypothesis. Supporting the Porter hypothesis, Lanoie et al. (2008) find negative short-run and positive long-run impacts of environmental policy stringency on technical efficiency of Quebec’s manufacturing firms. Managi et al. (2005) investigate the impact of environmental policy on technical efficiency of the offshore oil and gas industry and confirm the Porter hypothesis. Last, Lundgren et al. (2015) estimate the efficiency impacts of CO2 taxes on Swedish pulp and paper manufacturers, partially observing significantly positive effects.

This work contributes to the available literature in several aspects. First, my dataset also covers smaller firms next to large or listed firms enabling a more comprehensive analysis. Second, I allow heterogeneous effects of environmental tax rates across industries. Third, to the best of my knowledge, this is the first study examining downstream and upstream environmental tax spillovers using firm-level data. Fourth, I consider endogeneity of environmental tax rates by employing lags instead of contemporaneous values.

Generally, energy and pollution tax rates significantly impact productivity in many industries. Positive impacts of taxes on productivity are observed in energy-intensive sectors, industries producing energy-consuming goods and polluting sectors, whereas negative impacts are estimated in industries declining in Europe. Conversely, input amounts significantly respond in fewer industries. Downstream energy tax rates do not affect productivity, while upstream ones decrease technical efficiency. Downstream pollution taxation decreases productivity, whereas upstream taxation spurs technical efficiency.

The paper proceeds as follows: Sect. 2 introduces the empirical framework and data, used to examine the impacts of environmental regulation on firm behaviour, while Sect. 3 provides the results of the production function estimations and the regressions of firm behaviour. Last, Sect. 4 sums up and draws conclusions.

2 Empirical strategy and data

2.1 First stage: estimation of the production function

To establish links between environmental regulation and productivity, a two-stage procedure is employed. Following the literature (e.g. Gemmell et al. 2018; Richter and Schiersch 2017; Collard-Wexler and De Loecker 2015; Lu and Yu 2015; Du et al. 2014; Del Bo and Chiara 2013; Doraszelski and Jaumandreu 2013; Crinò and Epifani 2012; De Loecker and Warzynski 2012; Arnold et al. 2011; De Loecker 2007a; Javorcik 2004), I estimate three-input revenue-based Cobb–Douglas production functions, as described in Eq. (1), with the method by Ackerberg et al. (2015) explained in Appendix 1. y denotes logged output (dependent variable), k logged capital (state variable), l logged labour (free variable), and m logged material (proxy variable). \(\zeta\) is the sum of unobserved productivity \(\omega\) and measurement errors of productivity shocks \(\psi\). Indices i and t represent firms and years. A Cobb–Douglas specification is chosen, as it is probably the most popular type in the literature, although translog specifications are more flexible, though data demanding (Syverson 2011).

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} y_{i, \, t} \, = \,&\beta _{k} \, \cdot \, k_{i, \, t} \, + \, \beta _l \, \cdot \, l_{i, \, t} \, + \, \beta _{m} \, \cdot \, m_{i, \, t} \, + \, \underbrace{\omega _{i, \, t} \, + \, \psi _{i, \, t}}_{\zeta _{i, \, t}} \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(1)

As product-level output and input quantities are usually not available, while monetary outputs and inputs are mostly provided as firm-level aggregates, I follow the literature and estimate gross output production functions using producers’ real total monetary outputs and inputs. Firm-level data are sourced from the Orbis database published by Bureau van Dijk. Orbis contains accounting data, legal form, industry activity codes, and incorporation date for a large set of public and private companies worldwide. I include active and inactive; medium sized, large and very largeFootnote 1 European manufacturing companies (NACE C1000–C3320), incorporated in five countries: Austria, the Czech Republic, Hungary, Slovakia and Slovenia. The final sample is a nine-year unbalanced panel dataset, from 2009 to 2017, containing 18,060 firms with 123,101 observations of 24 two-digit NACE industries (94 three-digit and 265 four-digit NACE industries).Footnote 2

Output is defined as real operating revenues, being the sum of net sales, other operating revenues and stock variations excluding VAT (Bureau van Dijk 2007) deflated by annual gross value added deflators from the OECD database,Footnote 3 varying across countries, two-digit NACE industries and years. Next, capital is approximated with tangible fixed assets (e.g. machinery) deflated by uniform investment good price indexes from the same database,Footnote 4 varying across countries and years. Third, labour is a physical measure of the number of employees included in the company’s payroll. Fourth, material is measured by real material expenditures, being the sum of expenditures on raw materials and intermediate goods deflated by uniform intermediate good price indexes from the same database,Footnote 5 varying across countries and years. Fifth, real investment is approximated by exploiting the law of motion of capital, i.e. depreciation, deflated by the same price index as capital, and first differences in firm-specific real tangible assets are summed (Castelnovo et al. 2019; Richter and Schiersch 2017; Newman et al. 2015; Du et al. 2014; Nishitani et al. 2014; Baghdasaryan and la Cour 2013; Javorcik and Li 2013; Crinò and Epifani 2012; Higón and Antolín 2012; Javorcik 2004).

To consider heterogenous input elasticities \(\beta\) across countries, I follow the majority of studies (e.g. Fons-Rosen et al. 2021; Levine and Warusawitharana 2021; Gemmell et al. 2018; Olper et al. 2016) and estimate Eq. (1) for each two-digit NACE industry-country combination. As productivity is the residual, it measures the shifts in output while keeping inputs constant. Owing to the logged dependent variable, productivity is also logged, as shown in Eq. (2) (Javorcik 2004; Olley and Pakes 1996).

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} log(TFP_{i, \, t}) \, = \, y_{i, \, t} \, - \, \beta _{k} \, \cdot \, k_{i, \, t} \, - \, \beta _l \, \cdot \, l_{i, \, t} \, - \, \beta _{m} \, \cdot \, m_{i, \, t} \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(2)

2.2 Second stage: determinants of firm behaviour

In the second stage, I examine the effects of environmental policy on firm behaviour. Instead of employing first-differencing as Commins et al. (2011), I use fixed effects regressions, as described in Eq. (3), primarily used in the literature (e.g. Castelnovo et al. 2019; Franco and Marin 2017). The indices i, t, s and c denote firms, years, two-digit NACE industries and countries, with S and C being the total numbers of two-digit NACE industries and countries. e and p represent the energy and pollution tax rates.

$$\begin{aligned} \begin{aligned} w_{i, \, t} \, = \,&\sum _{s \, = \, 1}^{S} \delta _{e, \, s} \, \cdot \, D_{s} \, \cdot \, \mathrm{energy \, tax \, rate}_{c, \, s, \, t-2} \\&+ \, \sum _{s \, = \, 1}^{S} \delta _{p, \, s} \, \cdot \, D_{s} \, \cdot \, \mathrm{pollution \, tax \, rate}_{c, \, s, \, t-2} \\&+ \, \phi _{e} \, \cdot \, \mathrm{downstream \, energy \, tax \, rate}_{c, \, s, \, t-2} \, + \, \rho _{e} \, \cdot \, \mathrm{upstream \, energy \, tax \, rate}_{c, \, s, \, t-2} \\&+ \, \phi _{p} \, \cdot \, \mathrm{downstream \, pollution \, tax \, rate}_{c, \, s, \, t-2} \, + \, \rho _{p} \, \cdot \, \mathrm{upstream \, pollution \, tax \, rate}_{c, \, s, \, t-2} \\&+ \, \beta \, \cdot \, X_{c, \, i, \, s, \, t-1} \, + \, \alpha _{i} \, + \, \sum _{c \, = \, 1}^{C} \sum _{t \, = \, 2010}^{2017} \gamma _{c, \, t} \, \cdot \, D_{c} \, \cdot \, D_{t} \, + \, \epsilon _{i, \, t} \end{aligned} \end{aligned}$$
(3)

The dependent variables, w, cover logged productivity, real investment, real material expenditures and employment. Tax rates are introduced in levels to avoid losing zero-value observations when logging them (Franco and Marin 2017; Lundgren et al. 2015). Like Commins et al. (2011), I estimate the effects of energy and pollution tax rates for each two-digit NACE industry by interacting them with dummies for two-digit NACE industries \(D_{s}\). Table 3 in Appendix 2 lists all two-digit NACE industries’ codes and names. Given the log-level representation, coefficients \(\delta _{e, \, s}\) and \(\delta _{p, \, s}\) quantify the dependent variables’ environmental tax rate semi-elasticities for each two-digit NACE industry.

I source data on energy and pollution tax revenues starting from 2008, in Euro, from Eurostat (Franco and Marin 2017; Commins et al. 2011).Footnote 6Footnote 7 Energy taxes cover taxes on energy production and products (e.g. petrol; diesel; electricity; biofuels; CO2, etc.), while pollution taxes include taxes related to emissions to air and water, management of waste and noise (e.g. NOX; SOX; other emissions (excluding CO2); pesticides; artificial fertilisers; packaging etc.) (Eurostat 2020). Resource and transport taxes are excluded due to multicollinearity. Tax revenues, varying across countries, two-digit NACE industries and years, are divided by nominal gross values added from the same database,Footnote 8 varying at the same level, to compute average tax rates (Franco and Marin 2017; Commins et al. 2011).

Following Franco and Marin (2017), I involve tax rates paid by all downstream and upstream industries (including agriculture, mining, services)Footnote 9 of the same country, since governments try to homogenize tax rates to avoid capital flights. Downstream spillovers are defined as weighted averages of tax rates paid by downstream sectors. I construct the weights from symmetrical input–output tables of the year 2010Footnote 10 provided by Eurostat (Du et al. 2014).Footnote 11 For each country, the weighting matrix is calculated as follows: First, the main diagonal is set to zero to avoid double counting and multicollinearity. Second, matrices are row-normalized to obtain weights for every two-digit NACE industry–country combination. Third, they are multiplied with the country-specific tax rate vectors. Conversely, upstream tax rates define weighted averages of environmental tax rates paid by suppliers and are calculated analogously, except that the matrix’s transpose is row-normalized. Like Franco and Marin (2017), regulations embodied in imports and exports are excluded, as matrices only cover domestic flows. Tax spillovers are not interacted with industry dummies to avoid multicollinearity.

Concerning endogeneity, two issues are worth discussing: First, endogeneity may be caused by reverse causality. Although the literature (e.g. Franco and Marin 2017; Broberg et al. 2013; Commins et al. 2011; Lanoie et al. 2008; Managi et al. 2005) usually employs distributed lags (including contemporaneous values) of environmental policy stringency (e.g. taxes, pollution abatement control expenditures, emissions) treating them as exogenous, governments set tax rates to affect firms’ future production processes. To overcome this problem, Franco and Marin (2017) involve environmental taxes lagged by one year arguing that, in contrast to emissions and pollution abatement control expenditures, governments set environmental tax rates exogenously. Since lagging tax rates by one year might still not suffice, I lag tax rates by two years to break reverse causality. Second, I introduce important drivers of reorganization within firms, firm-level fixed effects and nested country–year dummies to solve omitted variable biases implied by confounding factors.

If environmental tax rates affect productivity and inputs negatively, the pollution haven hypothesis is supported. Contrarily, positive effects of environmental regulation on productivity and investment favour the Porter hypothesis. Last, the factor endowment hypothesis suggests positive impacts on productivity due to reorganization of production processes (Commins et al. 2011).

Vector X introduces control variables, capturing other drivers of technological progress and reorganization within firms. They are lagged by one period to overcome reverse causality (Franco and Marin 2017; Inui et al. 2012).Footnote 12 As employment also responds to wage costs, labour market regulation and human capital, I involve logged firm-level average real wages (Del Bo 2013). In comparison, Commins et al. (2011) employ shares of aggregate labour costs in value added and Franco and Marin (2017) logged industry-specific average wages, but they suffer from multicollinearity. Data on firm-level wage costs are obtained from Orbis, deflated by country-level HCPIs sourced from EurostatFootnote 13 and divided by firm-level employment. Given these studies, I expect them to affect productivity positively, as more human capital makes firms more productive, and employment negatively due to higher costs.

Besides, I introduce two variables capturing the degrees of foreign and domestic competition. First, I include import penetration (Commins et al. 2011), varying across countries, two-digit NACE industries and years. As databases only provide country-level data, I approximate industry-specific pendants with shares of imports in the total supply of goods. The latter is defined as the sum of foreign (imports) and domestic supply (value added). Data on two-digit NACE industry-specific imports, denoted in US dollar, are obtained from the OECD databaseFootnote 14 and converted to Euro employing exchange rates from the Austrian National Bank.Footnote 15Footnote 16 Second, I involve inverted Herfindahl–Hirschman indexes (HHI), \(1-HHI\) and their squares (Atayde et al. 2021; Aghion et al. 2015). Franco and Marin (2017) introduce the share of firms with more than 250 employees, but OECD data suffer from missing observations. I calculate the variable, being a number between zero (monopoly) and one (perfect competition), from firm-level real operating revenues for every country, three-digit NACE industry and year. Given the literature (e.g. Inui et al. 2012; Van Reenen 2011; Aghion et al. 2005), I expect a concave relationship, as fiercer competition spurs firms to innovate, but also discourages innovation by deteriorating post-entry rents.

Furthermore, I include fixed effects for firms \(\alpha _{i}\), capturing unobserved firm-level heterogeneity (e.g. country, NACE industry, company size, legal form). Unlike including country-level controls as Commins et al. (2011), I involve nested country–year dummies \(D_{c} \, \cdot \, D_{t}\), capturing these countrywide shocks (e.g. profit taxes, electricity and fuel prices, institutional quality, business activity).

3 Results

In the first stage, I estimate production functions to construct productivity for every firm and year, while, in the second stage, I regress \(\log (TFP)\) and other dependent variables using fixed effects models. Summary statistics are shown in Table 4 in Appendix 3.

3.1 Estimation of the production function

Tables 59 in Appendix 4 summarize the results of the production function estimations for each two-digit NACE industry-country combination. In every table, columns (1)–(3) provide the elasticities of output with respect to the considered inputs. Columns (4) and (5) display the numbers of observations and firms. The sum of input elasticities supplies an estimate of the degree of returns to scale. Therefore, column (6) shows the p-value of the Wald tests examining whether this sum significantly differs from one (constant returns to scale). In some industries, too few firms exit the market not allowing to consider attrition. Column (7), thus, provides information on whether attrition can be and is considered or not.Footnote 17

Overall, results are consistent with the literature (e.g. Richter and Schiersch 2017; Lu and Yu 2015; Du et al. 2014; Arnold et al. 2011). Labour elasticities mostly vary between 0.20 and 0.40 (Richter and Schiersch 2017; Arnold et al. 2011). In some industries, coefficients lie between 0.05 and 0.20 as in Lu and Yu (2015) and Du et al. (2014). As in these studies, capital elasticities are usually small between 0 and 0.10. In Hungary, some of them, however, are larger, suggesting that the relevant industries produce more capital-intensively. Depending on the study, material elasticities vary between 0.40 and 0.90, confirming my results.

Nevertheless, there are some abnormalities. Particularly, three coefficients exceed one (Austria C23; Slovenia C14) and, similarly to Lu and Yu (2015), the elasticity of capital falls below zero in eight (Austria C18, C24 and C28; Czech Republic C18 and C30; Hungary C16; Slovakia C26; Slovenia C33).

3.2 Effects of environmental taxes and spillovers

Tables 1 and 2 display the estimates of equation (3). Columns (1)–(4) show the results of the regressions of logged productivity, real investment, real material expenditures and employment. Standard errors are clustered at the firm-level to overcome residual serial correlation.Footnote 18

The first block of Table 1 displays energy tax rate semi-elasticities for each two-digit industry, \(\delta _{e, \, s}\), the second block those for the pollution tax rate, \(\delta _{p, \, s}\). Given the small values, pollution tax rates are denoted in per mill. In column (1), the energy tax rate semi-elasticity in industry C16 equals 0.0680, meaning that productivity increases by 6.80%, when energy tax rates increase by one percentage point. In the same column, the pollution tax rate semi-elasticity in industry C16 is \(-0.0145\), suggesting that productivity declines by 1.45%, when the pollution tax rate increases by one per mill. Figures 1, 2, 3, 4 illustrate them graphically. Dots represent the point estimate, lines the 95%-confidence intervals and stars the significance levels. The first block of Table 2 shows the effects of tax spillovers, \(\phi\) and \(\rho\), and the last block the controls’ effects. Small values of energy tax rates are found in the industries C10–C11, C13–C15, C18, C21–C22, C25–C28 and C30–C33 with means and maximum values mostly below 0.5 and one percentage point, sometimes resulting in larger coefficients. For these industries, interpreting the coefficients as effects of a rise by one per mill or one-tenth of a per mill (C18, C21, C26–C27) is more adequate, i.e. if the energy tax rate in industry C10 increases by one per mill, dependent variables change by \(-1.41, 0.58, -0.42\) and \(-0.98\%\). Pollution tax rates’ coefficients are higher in C13–C15, C21, C25, C27 and C30 with means and maximum values mostly below 0.07–0.3 and 0.7 per mill, suggesting an interpretation as the effects of an increase by one-tenth of a per mill or a smaller unit (C13–C16, C21, C25–C28, C30, C33), i.e. if the pollution tax rate in industry C13 rises by one-tenth of a per mill, dependent variables change by 3.18, \(-2.25\), \(-0.75\) and 4.43%.

Table 1 Results of the fixed effects regressions (I)
Table 2 Results of the fixed effects regressions (II)
Fig. 1
figure 1

Impacts of energy tax rates on productivity and real investment by industry

Fig. 2
figure 2

Impacts of energy tax rates on real material expenditures and employment by industry

Fig. 3
figure 3

Impacts of pollution tax rates on productivity and real investment by industry

Fig. 4
figure 4

Impacts of pollution tax rates on real material expenditures and employment by industry

Raising energy tax rates in the chemicals (C20), metal processing (C25) and motor vehicle (C29) industries results in productivity gains, as firms significantly purchase more material and employment, favoring the factor endowment hypothesis. Keeping input amounts constant, energy tax rates change some other production processes in the wood (C16), rubber and plastics (C22), non-metallic minerals (C23), electrical equipment (C27) and machinery (C28) sectors, supporting the factor endowment hypothesis. Confirming the Porter hypothesis, firms operating in the electronics industry (C26) expand investment and material, implying efficiency gains. Plausibly, these industries benefit from productivity gains, because they operate energy-intensively (C20, C23, C24) or produce energy-using goods (C25–C29). Higher tax rates raise production costs, forcing firms to innovate. Nonetheless, I cannot reject other explanations, as energy taxes can serve as entry barriers or reduce input price volatility (Yang et al. 2021; Richter and Schiersch 2017; Fujii et al. 2016; Commins et al. 2011).

Higher energy tax rates spur firms to reduce inputs in the food (C10), wearing apparel (C14) and printing and media (C18) industries, causing efficiency losses and, thus, favouring the pollution haven hypothesis. Although the pollution haven hypothesis suggests that environmental policy decreases productivity and input amounts, relocating to other countries is costly. Hence, firms will comply with new regulations by adjusting production processes (e.g. purchasing larger input amounts, substituting inputs with each other), which is observable for the beverages (C11), pharmaceutics (C21), other transport equipment (C30), furniture (C31) and repair and installation (C33) industries. Relevant sectors are declining in Europe (C14, C21, C30–C31), spurring this trend, or produce energy-intensively, but are not able to sufficiently reduce energy intensity (C10 and C11 due to cooking and cooling, C14 due to drying, C18) (UBA 2019, 2013c, d; Commins et al. 2011).

In the food (C10), beverages (C11) and printing and media (C18) industries, companies cut inputs, when governments raise pollution taxes, resulting in efficiency gains and suggesting the factor endowment hypothesis. Confirming the factor endowment hypothesis, corporations in the textiles sector (C13) purchase larger input amounts and enjoy productivity gains. Keeping input amounts constant, other production processes are adjusted in the leather (C15), chemicals (C20), rubber and plastics (C22), metal (C24), machinery (C28), motor vehicle (C29), furniture (C31), and other manufacturing (C32) industries. These findings support the factor endowment hypothesis. When raising pollution tax rates in the wearing apparel industry (C14), firms employ larger amounts of every input, favouring the Porter hypothesis. Plausibly, relevant industries benefit from efficiency gains, as they pollute water and air and rely extensively on chemicals next to being energy-intensive (C10, C11, C14, C15, C20, C24) and producing energy consuming products (C28, C29) (UBA 2019; Richter and Schiersch 2017; UBA 2013a, b, c).

Conversely, in the metal processing sector (C25), companies reduce all inputs when pollution tax rates rise, implying productivity losses and favouring the pollution haven hypothesis. Companies operating in the wood (C16) and electrical equipment (C27) industries adjust aspects of production processes other than inputs, decreasing technical efficiency. Rising production costs, resulting from higher taxes, cannot be compensated by technological progress that fast (C16 and C25 are already obliged to filter emissions (UBA 2014, 2013d), but searching for environmentally friendly substitutes takes long) and, therefore, firms lose rents.

Concerning the spillovers, Franco and Marin (2017) find significantly positive effects of downstream total environmental tax rates and significantly negative ones of upstream total environmental tax rates on sector-level value added and productivity arguing that downstream taxes spur sellers to innovate, while upstream tax raises hamper innovation. Although energy taxes make up the largest share of total environmental taxes, my results partially confirm their conclusion. For instance, energy taxes can be shifted to customers more easily than other taxes (Commins et al. 2011). Hence, tax raises induce consumers to buy less and sellers, therefore, purchase less from their suppliers, reducing demand, but providing incentives to innovate and implying an insignificant effect of downstream taxation. Conversely, suppliers may shift rising taxes to customers who might not be able to sufficiently innovate or substitute inputs, implying efficiency losses to buyers and a negative effect of upstream taxes. Interpreted as elasticities, raising downstream or upstream energy tax rates by one percentage point results in changes of the dependent variables by \(-1.33\) to +0.48%. Contrarily, the opposite holds for pollution tax rates. Higher upstream taxes might spur suppliers to innovate, as they cannot easily shift the tax, also benefiting their customers and resulting in a significantly positive effect of upstream taxation. As customers might face difficulties when shifting taxes to their customers, they may shift them to suppliers, implying a significantly negative impact of downstream taxes. When increasing downstream or upstream pollution tax rates by one per mill, dependent variables change by \(-6.19\) to +2.79%.

Like Commins et al. (2011), average real wages significantly increase productivity, as more human capital allows to produce more efficiently, and decreases employment due to higher costs. Consequently, employment is substituted with material. If the variable rises by 1%, dependent variables change by \(-0.16\) to +0.06%. In comparison, import penetration significantly decreases employment due to the more intense competition from foreign countries. Consequently, productivity decreases, as demand for domestic products declines. An increase by one percentage point, reduces dependent variables by 0.03–0.21%. As expected, the functional form of the relationship between domestic competition and productivity diplays the concave shape, as competition boosts productivity in a less competitive market, but reduces efficiency growth in highly competitive industries (Inui et al. 2012; Van Reenen 2011; Aghion et al. 2005).

3.3 Discussion

The overriding goal of green tax reforms is to design competitive, efficient and environmentally friendly markets. Nonetheless, green tax reforms, aiming to achieve productive and allocative efficiency, are a Herculean task due to the trade-off between productive efficiency and climate protection. This study sheds light on the impacts of environmental taxation and its spillovers on firm behaviour and performance, and highlights strong effects on productivity. In many industries, firms adjust production processes, suggesting that regulation induces innovation. Developing new technologies and innovating, however, takes more time in particular industries such that firms lose rents.

Concerning the magnitudes, effects of energy tax rates are not directly comparable with those by Commins et al. (2011). First, they only involve energy tax rates as the single variables of interest and exclude real material expenditures and tax spillovers. Second, they estimate elasticities, while I regress semi-elasticities. Third, production functions are estimated differently. Fourth, they introduce country-level control variables, while I employ nested country–year dummies. Fifth, I use fixed effects regressions considering endogeneity of environmental policy instead of employing first-differencing treating policy variables as exogenous. Nonetheless, I observe fewer significant effects on input amounts, but the results generally, as productivity responds positively to taxation in industries that are energy-intensive or polluting, produce energy consuming products or rely heavily on chemicals, while negative effects are observed in industries declining in Europe. Concerning energy tax rates, my results are in line with Fujii et al. (2016) who conclude that energy conservation laws raised productivity in the metals and machinery sectors. My results confirm those by Broberg et al. (2013) in the sense that the Porter hypothesis does not hold for European manufacturing sectors. Though Franco and Marin (2017) use total environmental tax rates and sector-level data, the results for energy taxation, making up the largest part of the former, partially agree.

However, one set of econometric issues results from employing deflated monetary output values instead of quantities. Potential differences in input prices across firms, originating from differences in the access to input markets or monopsonies, might cause ’input price biases’ (negatively biased coefficients, upwards biased productivity). Like the literature, I implicitly assume that all firms of a given country face identical input prices. In case of input price differences, my estimates suffer from input price biases, because I rely on two deflated monetary inputs (De Loecker and Goldberg 2014).

Last, another set of econometric issues stems from using deflated monetary values of output instead of quantities, called ’omitted price variable bias’. Unfortunately, price indices are only available at industry-level, while firm-level or product-level price indices would be required. Applying industry-level price indices to firm-level operating revenues implies biased production function coefficients, if product- or firm-level prices deviate from the development of industry-level price indexes, which are captured by the error term. The direction of each coefficient’s bias is not straightforward and can go in either direction (De Loecker and Goldberg (2014), De Loecker (2007b), Klette and Griliches (1996)). To solve this problem, in the spirit of Klette and Griliches (1996), De Loecker (2007b) proposes a framework, based on including industry-specific aggregate demand shifters, which, however, fails to correctly identify coefficients, because multiplying all asymmetrically biased input coefficients with a constant cannot yield unbiased coefficients (Ornaghi 2006).

4 Conclusion

I investigate the effects of environmental taxes on firm behaviour to provide policy lessons for designing green tax reforms. Therefore, in the first stage, Cobb–Douglas production functions are estimated with the algorithm by Ackerberg et al. (2015), using data on Central European manufacturing firms, from 2009 to 2017. In the second stage, I estimate the impacts of environmental taxation on productivity and firm behaviour with fixed effects models.

The results show that productivity significantly responds in many industries that are energy-intensive or polluting, produce energy consuming products, rely heavily on chemicals or are declining in Europe. In few industries, the pollution haven hypothesis holds, while other industries respond by substituting inputs with each other, purchasing larger input amounts or changing other processes, thereby decreasing productivity, as relocating to other countries is not easy. Downstream energy tax rates do not affect productivity, while upstream ones decrease technical efficiency. Downstream pollution taxation decreases productivity, whereas upstream taxation spurs technical efficiency. Policy makers should consider significantly negative impacts of environmental taxes and their spillovers on productivity. First, I suggest to implement green tax reforms raising environmental tax rates to spur innovation and, consequently, technical efficiency. Second, I recommend to complement them with the introduction of investment incentives, wage tax cuts or other compensations to bolster negative impacts on productivity, investment and employment.