Skip to main content
Log in

A classical-evolutionary model of technological change

  • Regular Article
  • Published:
Journal of Evolutionary Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Technological change is a central concern for evolutionary economics, which combines detailed empirical studies and conceptual frameworks with mathematical modeling, among them the NK model from evolutionary biology. Technological change is also a central concern for classical and Marxian economics, where it is studied under the rubric of “cost share-induced technological change.” Among the contributions from classical economists is a classical-evolutionary model first introduced by Duménil and Lévy. This paper strengthens the classical-evolutionary model’s microeconomic foundations by deriving it from an underlying NK model. The result is an aggregate model suitable for macroeconomic analysis that is grounded in evolutionary microeconomic theory. This explicit micro-to-macro link opens avenues for further research. The paper presents new results for the classical-evolutionary model, including a “generating function” method for creating candidate functional forms, and provides three illustrative applications.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7

Similar content being viewed by others

Data availability

Not applicable

Code availability

Not applicable

Notes

  1. Weitzman (1996, 1998) also finds Harrod-neutral change emerging endogenously in a model of innovation. However, the mechanism is quite different: rather than being driven by cost and profitability considerations, diminishing returns are overcome by the combinatorially expanding possibilities opened through successive rounds of innovation.

  2. Evolutionary economics admits the possibility of exploratory but highly uncertain “long-jumps” on rugged fitness landscapes (Levinthal 1997), but that is a quite different process from taking a large step towards a well-defined technological frontier.

  3. An alternative would be to use products, rather than firms or divisions, as the unit of analysis (as in Cantner et al. 2012).

  4. This section treats TFP growth strictly as a measured quantity, with no theoretical commitment to growth accounting. For a critique of growth accounting and the production function approach, see (Felipe and McCombie 2013; Felipe and Fisher 2003).

  5. See https://mathworld.wolfram.com/HeavisideStepFunction.html for more on the Heaviside function.

  6. It is here that changes in the term c in Eq. 1 would appear if, contrary to the assumption in this paper, that term were not constant. The sum would then be over \(\boldsymbol {\sigma }(s^{\prime })\cdot \hat {\boldsymbol {\nu }}(s^{\prime }\rvert s_{k}) h(\boldsymbol {\sigma }(s^{\prime })\cdot \hat {\boldsymbol {\nu }}(s^{\prime }\rvert s_{k}) - {\Delta } c_{k})\).

  7. The underlying NK model has N elements, each with multiple variants. Denoting the number of variants per element by V, there are VN possible combinations. Even for modest numbers that can yield a large value; 10 elements with 5 variants each yields nearly 10 million possible combinations. Yet, even that understates the size of the search space, since those numbers are typical of what (Murmann and Frenken 2006) term the “first-order subsystem technology cycle” (e.g., for early glider design as shown in their Table 3 on page 940). Below that level are second-order subsystems and components, each of which has its own potentially large search space.

  8. The density function can be defined formally as

    $${f}_d^k\left(\hat{\boldsymbol{v}}\right)=\underset{\boldsymbol{\varepsilon} \to \textbf{0}}{\lim}\frac{1}{\prod_{i=0}^n{\varepsilon}_i}\frac{\epsilon_d^k\left({s}_k\right)}{\left|{\mathcal{N}}_d^{k,\textrm{impr}}\left({s}_k\right)\right|}\left|\left\{{s}^{\prime}\in {\mathcal{N}}_d^{k,\textrm{impr}}\left({s}_k\right)\left|\hat{\boldsymbol{v}}-\frac{\boldsymbol{\varepsilon}}{2}\leq\hat{\boldsymbol{v}}\left(\left.{s}^{\prime}\right|{s}_k\right)<\hat{\boldsymbol{v}}+\frac{\boldsymbol{\varepsilon}}{2}\right.\right\}\right|\cdot $$

     

    Due to the granularity of actual innovation processes, the elements of the vector ε cannot in fact be taken arbitrarily close to zero. The assumption is that they can be brought close enough to zero to justify a continuum model for aggregate analysis.

  9. This is also true by construction, since the matrix of second derivatives of a smooth scalar function is symmetric.

  10. This assumption is compatible with using national accounts data for empirical macroeconomic modeling. No matter how disaggregated the input-output table may be, the sectors that enter into it include a very large number of firms with different characteristics. Nevertheless, the sectoral price indices and sector-by-sector technical coefficients are taken to be broadly representative.

  11. Those papers embed technological change within larger agent-based models in order to explore the interaction between Keynesian and Schumpterian dynamics (Dosi et al. 2010) and between inequality and innovation (Caiani et al. 2019). This paper takes inspiration from the way in which they introduced R&D expenditure into their technological change sub-models, but does not explore them further.

  12. There are conditions under which prices or productivities will not stabilize. Hence the claim is that cost share-induced technological change can, but not necessarily will, stabilize prices in a multi-sector economy.

  13. The Scilab script is available from the author upon request.

  14. According to the World Bank’s methodology (World Bank 2011), fossil resource rents are effectively the profits of fossil extractive sectors as a share of GDP.

  15. Data from the Monthly Energy Review can be downloaded from https://www.eia.gov/totalenergy/data/browser/. The heat content of natural gas is available from https://www.eia.gov/dnav/ng/ng_cons_heat_dcu_nus_a.htm. The time series for heat content begin in 2003; the 2003 values were used for earlier years.

References

  • Altenberg L (1997) NK Fitness landscapes. In: Back T, Fogel D, Michalewicz Z (eds) The Handbook of Evolutionary Computation. Oxford University Press, Oxford

  • Aspromourgos T (2004) Sraffian research programmes and unorthodox economics. Rev Polit Econ 16(2):179–206. https://doi.org/10.1080/0953825042000183181

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Auerswald P, Kauffman S, Lobo J, Shell K (2000) The production recipes approach to modeling technological innovation: An application to learning by doing. J Econ Dyn Control 24(3):389–450. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0165-1889(98)00091-8

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhaduri A, Marglin S (1990) Unemployment and the real wage: The economic basis for contesting political ideologies. Camb J Econ 14(4):375–393

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caiani A, Russo A, Gallegati M (2019) Does inequality hamper innovation and growth? An AB-SFC analysis. J Evolut Econ 29(1):177–228. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-018-0554-8

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cantner U (2017) Foundations of economic change: an extended Schumpeterian approach. In: Pyka A, Cantner U (eds) Foundations of Economic Change. Springer, Cham, Switzerland, pp 9–49

  • Cantner U, Krüger JJ, Söllner R (2012) Product quality, product price, and share dynamics in the German compact car market. Ind Corp Chang 21 (5):1085–1115. https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/dts002

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cantner U, Savin I, Vannuccini S (2019) Replicator dynamics in value chains: explaining some puzzles of market selection. Ind Corp Chang 28 (3):589–611. https://doi.org/10.1093/icc/dty060

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coutts K, Norman N (2013) Post-keynesian approaches to industrial pricing. In: Harcourt G, Kriesler P (eds) The Oxford Handbook of Post-Keynesian Economics, Volume 1: Theory and Origins. Oxford University Press, Oxford

  • Cynamon BZ, Fazzari SM (2015) Rising inequality and stagnation in the US economy. European Journal of Economics and Economic Policies 12 (2):170–182. https://doi.org/10.4337/ejeep.2015.02.03

    Google Scholar 

  • Dosi G, Fagiolo G, Roventini A (2010) Schumpeter meeting Keynes: A policy-friendly model of endogenous growth and business cycles. J Econ Dyn Control 34(9):1748–1767. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jedc.2010.06.018

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi G, Nelson RR (2013) The evolution of technologies: an assessment of the state-of-the-art. Eurasian Bus Rev 3(1):3–46. https://doi.org/10.14208/BF03353816

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dosi G, Nelson RR (2018) Technological advance as an evolutionary process. In: Nelson RR, Dosi G, Helfat CE, Pyka A, Saviotti PP, Lee K, Dopfer K, Malerba F, Winter SG (eds) Modern evolutionary economics: an overview. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108661928. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 35–84

  • Duménil G, Lévy D (1992) The historical dynamics of technology and distribution: The US economy since the Civil War. Rev Radical Politic Econ 24(2):34–44

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duménil G., Lévy D. (2010) The classical-Marxian evolutionary theory of technological change: application to historical tendencies. In: Setterfield M (ed) Handbook of alternative theories of economic growth. Cheltenham, U.K. ; Northampton, Mass., USA: Edward Elgar, pp 243–273

  • Dutt AK (2013) Endogenous technological change in Classical-Marxian models of growth and distribution. In: Taylor L, Rezai A, Michl T (eds) Social fairness and economics: economic essays in the spirit of Duncan foley. Abingdon Oxon; New York, NY, Routledge, pp 243–264

  • Feenstra RC, Inklaar R, Timmer MP (2015) The next generation of the Penn World Table. Am Econ Rev 105(10):3150–82. https://doi.org/10.1257/aer.20130954

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Felipe J, Fisher FM (2003) Aggregation in production functions: what applied economists should know, vol 54. https://doi.org/10.1111/1467-999X.00166

  • Felipe J, McCombie JSL (2013) The aggregate production function and the measurement of technical change: ‘Not even wrong’. Cheltenham UK: Edward Elgar

  • Foley DK (2003) Endogenous technical change with externalities in a classical growth model. J Econ Behav Organ 52(2):167–189. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-2681(03)00020-9

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Foley DK, Michl TR, Tavani D (2019) Growth and distribution. In: Growth and Distribution (2nd ed.). Cambridge, MA, US: Harvard University Press

  • Frenken K (2001) Modelling the organisation of innovative activity using the NK-model. Aalborg, Denmark. Nelson-and-Winter Conference

  • Geels FW, Schot J (2007) Typology of sociotechnical transition pathways. Res Policy 36(3):399–417. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2007.01.003

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goodwin RM (1967) A growth cycle. In: Feinstein C (ed) Socialism, Cpaitalism, and Economic Growth: Essays Presented to Maurice Dobb. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, UK, pp 54–58

  • Graham JR, Harvey CR (2001) The theory and practice of corporate finance: Evidence from the field. J Financ Econ 60(2–3):187–243. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0304-405X(01)00044-7

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helfat CE (2018) The behavior and capabilities of firms. In: Nelson R.R., Dosi G., Helfat C.E., Pyka A., Saviotti P.P., Lee K., Dopfer K., Malerba F., Winter S.G. (eds) Modern evolutionary economics: an overview. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108661928. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 85–103

  • Hicks J (1932) The theory of wages. MacMillan and Company Limited, London

    Google Scholar 

  • IPCC (2022) Climate Change 2022: Impacts, adaptation, and vulnerability contribution of working group II to the sixth assessment report of the intergovernmental panel on climate change. Technical report, IPCC

  • Julius AJ (2005) Steady-state growth and distribution with an endogenous direction of technical change. Metroeconomica 56(1):101–125. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-999X.2005.00209.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kauffman S, Levin S (1987) Towards a general theory of adaptive walks on rugged landscapes. J Theoret Biol 128(1):11–45. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0022-5193(87)80029-2

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kauffman S, Lobo J, Macready WG (2000) Optimal search on a technology landscape. J Econ Behav Organ 43(2):141–166. https://doi.org/10.1016/S0167-2681(00)00114-1

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kemp-Benedict E (2018) Dematerialization, decoupling, and productivity change. Ecolog Econ 150:204–216. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2018.04.020

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kemp-Benedict E (2019) Cost share-induced technological change and Kaldor’s stylized facts. Metroeconomica 70(1):2–23. https://doi.org/10.1111/meca.12223

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kemp-Benedict E (2020) Convergence of actual, warranted, and natural growth rates in a Kaleckian–Harrodian-classical model. Metroeconomica 71 (4):851–881. https://doi.org/10.1111/meca.12305

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kennedy C (1964) Induced bias in innovation and the theory of distribution. Econ J 74(295):541–547. https://doi.org/10.2307/2228295

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • King JE (2012) The microfoundations delusion: Metaphor and dogma in the history of macroeconomics cheltenham. Edward Elgar Pub, UK

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Kurz HD (2010) Technical progress, capital accumulation and income distribution in Classical economics: Adam Smith, David Ricardo and Karl Marx. European J History Econ Thought 17(5):1183–1222. https://doi.org/10.1080/09672567.2010.522242

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lavoie M (2001) Pricing. In: Holt RPF, Pressman S (eds) Contemporary Political Economy series. London ; New York: Routledge

  • Lavoie M (2014) Post-Keynesian Economics: New foundations. Edward Elgar Publishing Limited, Cheltenham UK

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Lee FS (1994) From post-Keynesian to historical price theory, part I: Facts, theory and empirically grounded pricing model. Rev Political Econ 6 (3):303–336. https://doi.org/10.1080/09538259400000041

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lee FS (1999) Post Keynesian Price Theory. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

  • Levinthal DA (1997) Adaptation on rugged landscapes. Manag Sci 43(7):934–950

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Metcalfe JS, Foster J (2010) Evolutionary growth theory. In: Setterfield M. (ed) Handbook of Alternative Theories of Economic Growth. UK: Edward Elgar Publishing. Google-Books-ID: dOIko3VeuCMC, Cheltenham, pp 64–94

  • Murmann JP, Frenken K (2006) Toward a systematic framework for research on dominant designs, technological innovations, and industrial change. Res Policy 35(7):925–952. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2006.04.011

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson RR (2018) Economics from an evolutionary perspective. In: Nelson RR, Dosi G, Helfat CE, Pyka A, Saviotti PP, Lee K, Dopfer K, Malerba F, Winter SG (eds) Modern evolutionary economics: an overview. https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108661928. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp 1–34

  • Nelson RR, Winter SG (1982) An evolutionary theory of economic change. Mass: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Okishio N (1961) Technical changes and the rate of profit. Kobe University Econ Rev 7:86–99

    Google Scholar 

  • Okishio N (2001) Competition and production prices. Cambridge J Econ 25(4):493–501. https://doi.org/10.1093/cje/25.4.493

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perez C (2010) Technological revolutions and techno-economic paradigms. Cambridge J Econ 34(1):185–202. https://doi.org/10.1093/cje/bep051

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rada C, Taylor L (2006) Empty sources of growth accounting, and empirical replacements à la Kaldor and Goodwin with some beef. Struct Chang Econ Dyn 17(4):486–500. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.strueco.2006.08.007

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rowthorn RE (1977) Conflict, inflation and money. Cambridge J Econ 1(3):215–239

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson PA (1965) A theory of induced innovation along Kennedy-Weisäcker lines. Rev Econ Stat 47(4):343–356. https://doi.org/10.2307/1927763

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saviotti PP, Pyka A (2004) Economic development by the creation of new sectors. J Evol Econ 14(1):1–35. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-003-0179-3

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Scazzieri R (1990) Reverse capital deepening. In: Eatwell J, Milgate M, Newman P (eds) Capital Theory. The New Palgrave, pp 228–231. New York, NY, US and London, UK: The Macmillan Press Limited

  • SEI IISD, ODI (2021) The Production Gap Report 2021. Technical report, Stockholm Environment Insitute, Stockholm, Sweden

  • Shaikh A (2016) Capitalism: competition, conflict, crises. Oxford University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Shiozawa Y, Morioka M, Taniguchi K (2019) Microfoundations of evolutionary economics. Evolutionary economics and social complexity science; Vol 15. Tokyo, Japan, Springer

  • Tavani D, Zamparelli L (2017) Endogenous technical change in alternative theories of growth and distribution. Working Paper 1/2017, Dipartimento di Scienze Sociali ed Economiche, Sapienza. Università di Roma, Italy

    Google Scholar 

  • Tavani D, Zamparelli L (2021) Labor-augmenting technical change and the wage share: New microeconomic foundations. Struct Change Econ Dyn 56:27–34. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.strueco.2020.09.004

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor L, Omer O (2020) Macroeconomic inequality from Reagan to Trump: market power, wage repression, asset price inflation, and industrial decline Studies in new economic thinking. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge New York Melbpurne New Delhi Singapore

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Teulings C, Baldwin R (eds) (2014) Secular stagnation: facts, causes and cures. UK: Centre for Economic Policy Research, London

  • Valente M (2014) An NK-like model for complexity. J Evol Econ 24(1):107–134. https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-013-0334-4

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weitzman ML (1996) Hybridizing growth theory. Am Econ Rev 86(2):207–212

    Google Scholar 

  • Weitzman ML (1998) Recombinant growth. Q J Econ 113 (2):331–360. https://doi.org/10.1162/003355398555595

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Winter SG (2014) The future of evolutionary economics: can we break out of the beachhead?. J Institutional Econ 10 (4):613–644. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1744137414000277

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (2011) The changing wealth of nations: measuring sustainable development in the new millennium. Washington, D.C.: World Bank

  • Zamparelli L (2015) Induced innovation, endogenous technical change and income distribution in a labor-constrained model of classical growth. Metroeconomica 66(2):243–262. https://doi.org/10.1111/meca.12068

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The work presented in this paper benefited from the support of the AFD 2050 Facility. The author is grateful to Antoine Godin and Devrim Yilmaz and to two anonymous reviewers for critical comments on the paper.

Funding

Funding was provided by the Agence Française de Développement under the AFD 2050 Facility

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Contributions

There is a sole author, who carried out all of the work.

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Eric Kemp-Benedict.

Ethics declarations

Ethics approval

Not applicable

Conflict of interests

The author declares no conflict of interest

Consent for publication

Not applicable

Consent to participate

Not applicable

Additional information

Publisher’s note

Springer Nature remains neutral with regard to jurisdictional claims in published maps and institutional affiliations.

Rights and permissions

Springer Nature or its licensor holds exclusive rights to this article under a publishing agreement with the author(s) or other rightsholder(s); author self-archiving of the accepted manuscript version of this article is solely governed by the terms of such publishing agreement and applicable law.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Kemp-Benedict, E. A classical-evolutionary model of technological change. J Evol Econ 32, 1303–1343 (2022). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-022-00792-5

Download citation

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00191-022-00792-5

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation