Skip to main content
Log in

Detecting multiple breaks in long memory the case of U.S. inflation

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Multiple structural change tests by Bai and Perron (Econometrica 66:47–78, 1998) are applied to the regression by Demetrescu et al. (Econ Theory 24:176–215, 2008) in order to detect breaks in the order of fractional integration. With this instrument we tackle time-varying inflation persistence as an important issue for monetary policy. We determine not only the location and significance of breaks in persistence, but also the number of breaks. Only one significant break in U.S. inflation persistence (measured by the long-memory parameter) is found to have taken place in 1973, while a second break in 1980 is not significant.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10
Fig. 11
Fig. 12
Fig. 13
Fig. 14

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. For a review on changing inflation persistence in EMU member states see Tillmann (2012) and Meller and Nautz (2012).

  2. Such a feature is sometimes called “mean-reversion” although Phillips and Xiao (1999) argue that this is a misnomer given the nonstationarity.

  3. The model in (6) introduces a nonlinearity in \(\Delta ^d y_t\) which is not present under the null in (1). Baillie and Kapetanios (2007) and Baillie and Kapetanios (2008) found evidence in favour of nonlinearity in addition to long memory in many economic and financial time series. Contrary to (6), however, they instead assume a smooth transition autoregression or a similar nonlinear \(I(0)\) model for \(\Delta ^d y_t\). An investigation of their tests under breaks in memory is beyond the scope of the present paper.

  4. The critical values are available from an unpublished appendix to Bai and Perron (2003b) posted on the homepage of Pierre Perron.

  5. Tables containing corresponding information as reported in Table 1 are available for all variations to the simulation set-up reported in this subsection.

  6. Seasonality is accounted for by twelve monthly dummies (\(dum_{seas}\)), the break in mean is accounted for by a mean dummy (\(dum_\mu \)) taking on the value one before and the value 0 after \([\tau _0 \,T]\). The variable \(y_t\) is the residual of the regression of \(p_t\) on \(dum_\mu \) and \(dum_{seas}\).

  7. As an alternative to the sequential procedure we also allow for two mean shifts simultaneously and obtain similar break points and \(p\) values.

  8. Bai and Perron (1998) also investigate a double maximum test, not considered in this paper. The number of break points is found by taking the maximum over all \(sup F(m)\) test statistics, where \(m={1,2,...,5}\). This maximum value is then compared to critical values in order to determine the significance. This suggests that in our analysis there is only one break point.

  9. As becomes evident in Fig. 5, the power of the test increases with the difference in the order of integration before and after the break. Another factor is the total number of observations in the whole sample, see Fig. 6. If the difference in the order of integration is at least 0.3 and the sample size is 500, the test has a rejection rate of more than 80 % if there are at least 150 observations left before and after the break.

  10. This interpretation is inferred directly from Proposition 3 in Demetrescu et al. (2008) and the derivations of this paper.

  11. The order of integration was estimated to be 0.22 for \(B=T^{0.70}\) with a 90 % confidence interval \([0.01, 0.43]\). However, the estimation depends heavily on single observations.

  12. The events are not described in order to indicate causality but rather in order to integrate the break date into its historical background.

References

  • Andrews DWK (1993) Tests for parameter instability and structural change with unknown change point. Econometrica 61:821–56

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bai J, Perron P (1998) Estimating and testing linear models with multiple structural changes. Econometrica 66:47–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bai J, Perron P (2003a) Computation and analysis of multiple structural change models. J Appl Econ 18:1–22

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bai J, Perron P (2003b) Critical values for multiple structural change tests. Econ J 6:72–78

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baillie RT, Chung C-F, Tieslau MA (1996) Analysing inflation by the fractionally integrated ARFIMA–GARCH model. J Appl Econ 11:23–40

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baillie RT, Kapetanios G (2007) Testing for neglected nonlinearity in long-memory. J Bus Econ Stat 25:447–461

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baillie RT, Kapetanios G (2008) Nonlinear models for strongly dependent processes with financial applications. J Econ 147:60–71

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beran J, Terrin N (1996) Testing for a change of the long-memory parameter. Biometrika 83:233–233

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beran J, Terrin N (1999) Correction: testing for a change of the long-memory parameter. Biometrika 86:627–638

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Breitung J, Hassler U (2002) Inference on the cointegration rank in fractionally integrated processes. J Econ 110:167–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Busetti F, Taylor AMR (2004) Tests of stationarity against a change in persistence. J Econ 123:33–66

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cogley T, Sargent TJ (2001) Evolving post-world war II U.S. inflation dynamics. NBER Macroecon Ann 16:331–373

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cogley T, Sargent TJ (2005) Drift and volatilities: monetary policies and outcomes in the post WWII U.S. Rev Econ Dyn 8:262–302

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demetrescu M, Hassler U, Kuzin V (2011) Pitfalls of post-model-selection testing: experimental quantification. Empir Econ 40:359–372

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Demetrescu M, Kuzin V, Hassler U (2008) Long memory testing in the time domain. Econ Theory 24: 176–215

    Google Scholar 

  • Gadea MD, Mayoral L (2006) The persistence of inflation in OECD countries: a fractionally integrated approach. Int J Central Banking 2:51–104

    Google Scholar 

  • Geweke J, Porter-Hudak S (1983) The estimation and application of long memory time series models. J Time Ser Anal 4:221–238

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gil-Alana LA (2008) Fractional integration and structural breaks at unknown periods of time. J Time Ser Anal 29:163–185

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hassler U, Breitung J (2006) A residual-based lm-type test against fractional cointegration. Econometric Theory 22:1091–1111

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hassler U, Kokoszka P (2010) Impulse responses of fractionally integrated processes with long memory. Econ Theory 26:1855–1861

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hassler U, Rodrigues PMM, Rubia A (2009) Testing for general fractional integration in the time domain. Econ Theory 25:1793–1828

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hassler U, Scheithauer J (2011) Detecting changes from short to long memory. Stat Pap 52:847–870

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hassler U, Wolters J (1995) Long memory in inflation rates: international evidence. J Bus Econ Stat 13: 37–45

    Google Scholar 

  • Hidalgo J, Robinson PM (1996) Testing for structural change in a long-memory environment. J Econ 70:159–174

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hsu C-C (2005) Long memory or structural changes: an empirical examination on inflation rates. Econ Lett 88:289–294

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kew H, Harris D (2009) Heteroskedasticity-robust testing for a fractional unit root. Econ Theory 25: 1734–1753

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim J-Y (2000) Detection of change in persistence of a linear time series. J Econ 95:97–116

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kumar MS, Okimoto T (2007) Dynamics of persistence in international inflation rates. J Money, Credit Banking 39:1457–1479

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lavielle M, Ludeña C (2000) The multiple change-points problem for the spectral distribution. Bernoulli 6:845–869

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Leeb H, Pötscher BM (2005) Model selection and inference: facts and fiction. Econ Theory 21:21–59

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lobato IN, Savin NE (1998) Real and spurious long-memory properties of stock-market data. J Bus Econ Stat 16:261–268

    Google Scholar 

  • Martins LF, Rodrigues PMM (2012) Testing for persistence change in fractionally integrated models: an application to world inflation rates. Comput Stat Data Anal doi:10.1016/j.csda.2012.07.021

  • Meller B, Nautz D (2012) Inflation persistence in the euro area before and after the European Monetary Union. Econ Model 29:1170–1176

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meltzer AH (2006) From inflation to more inflation, disinflation, and low inflation. Am Econ Rev 96:185–188

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Phillips PCB, Xiao Z (1999) A primer on unit root testing. J Econ Surv 12:423–470

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pivetta F, Reis R (2007) The persistence of inflation in the United States. J Econ Dyn Control 31:1326–1358

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ray BK, Tsay RS (2002) Bayesian methods for change-point detection in long-range dependent processes. J Time Ser Anal 23:687–705

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson PM (1991) Testing for strong serial correlation and dynamic conditional heteroskedasticity in multiple regression. J Econ 47:67–84

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson PM (1994) Efficient tests of nonstationary hypotheses. J Am Stat Assoc 89:1420–1437

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson PM (1995) Gaussian semiparametric estimation of long range dependence. Ann Stat 23:1630–1661

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Robinson PM (2005) The distance between rival nonstationary fractional processes. J Econ 128:283–399

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schwert GW (1989) Tests for unit roots: a Monte Carlo investigation. J Bus Econ Stat 7:147–159

    Google Scholar 

  • Shimotsu K, Phillips PCB (2005) Exact local whittle estimation of fractional integration. Ann Stat 33:1890–1933

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sibbertsen P (2004) Long memory versus structural breaks: an overview. Stat Pap 45:465–515

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sibbertsen P, Kruse R (2009) Testing for a break in persistence under long-range dependencies. J Time Ser Anal 30:263–285

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stock JH (2001) Evolving post-world war II U.S. inflation dynamics: comment. NBER Macroecon Ann 16:379–387

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stock JH, Watson MW (2007) Why has U.S. inflation become harder to forecast? J Money, Credit Banking 39:3–33

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tanaka K (1999) The nonstationary fractional unit root. Econ Theory 15:549–583

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tillmann P (2012) Has inflation persistence changed under EMU? Ger Econ Rev 13:86–102

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yamaguchi K (2011) Estimating a change point in the long memory parameter. J Time Ser Anal 32:304–314

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

In particular we thank Dieter Nautz for his valuable comments. We are grateful to two anonymous referees who helped to improve the paper. Financial support by the German Research Foundation (Deutsche Forschungsgemeinschaft, DFG) through HA-3306/2-1 and by the Frankfurt Graduate Program in Finance and Monetary Economics is gratefully acknowledged. The paper represents the authors’ personal opinions and does not necessarily reflect the views of the Deutsche Bundesbank or its staff.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Barbara Meller.

Additional information

Earlier versions of this paper were presented at the 15th International Conference on Computing in Economics and Finance (July 2009, Sydney) and the European Society Econometric Meeting (August 2009, Barcelona).

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 Proof of Proposition 1

Under Gaussianity and Assumption 2 the pseudo-log-likelihood function becomes

$$\begin{aligned} \mathcal L (\theta _1, \ldots , \theta _m ; \, d,\sigma ^2)=-\frac{T}{2} \log (2\pi \sigma ^2)-\frac{1}{2\sigma ^2}\sum _{t=1}^{T}\varepsilon _t^2, \end{aligned}$$

with \(\varepsilon _t = \Delta ^{d+\theta _{j-1}} y_t\) for \(t=T_{j-1}+1, \ldots , T_j \) using (3) and (4), or \(\varepsilon _t = \Delta ^{d+\theta _{j}} y_t\) for \(t=T_{j}+1,\ldots ,T_{j+1}\), such that (\(j=1,\ldots ,m\))

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \varepsilon _t}{\partial \theta _j}= \left\{ \begin{array}{cl} \left( \log (1-L)\right) (1-L)^{d+\theta _j}y_t, &{} t=T_{j}+1,\ldots ,T_{j+1} \\ 0 &{} \text{ else } \end{array} \right. . \end{aligned}$$

With \(\log (1-L)=-\sum _{j=1}^{\infty }j^{-1}L^{j}\) we obtain for the score vector evaluated under the null (where \(\Delta ^d y_t = \varepsilon _t\))

$$\begin{aligned} S= \left( \left. \frac{\partial \mathcal L }{\partial \theta _j} \right| _{\theta _j=0} \right) _{j=1,\ldots ,m} \!=\! \left( \frac{1}{\sigma ^2} \sum _{t=T_j+1}^{T_{j+1}} \varepsilon _t\varepsilon _{t-1}^{**}\right) _{j=1,\ldots ,m} \quad \text{ with } \varepsilon _{t-1}^{**}\!=\!\sum _{j=1}^{\infty }j^{-1}\varepsilon _{t-j}, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\{\varepsilon _{t-1}^{**}\}\) is a stationary process with variance

$$\begin{aligned} \sigma _{**}^2 = \text{ Var } \left( \varepsilon _{t-1}^{**}\right) = \sigma ^2 \sum _{j=1}^\infty j^{-2} = \sigma ^2 \frac{\pi ^2}{6}. \end{aligned}$$

To construct the LM statistic we compute the Fisher information as the outer product of gradients,

$$\begin{aligned} \mathcal I = \text{ E } \left( S \, S^\prime \right) = \frac{\sigma _{**}^2}{ \sigma ^2} \, \text{ diag } \left( T_2-T_1, \ldots , T_{m+1}- T_m \right) . \end{aligned}$$

Hence, we obtain

$$\begin{aligned} S^\prime \mathcal I ^{-1} S = \frac{1}{\sigma _{**}^2 \sigma ^2} \ \sum _{j=1}^m \ \frac{\left( \sum \limits _{t = T_j +1}^{T_{j+1}} \varepsilon _t \varepsilon _{t-1}^{**} \right) ^2}{T_{j+1} - T_j}. \end{aligned}$$

Since the LM statistic is evaluated under \(H_0\), we replace \(\varepsilon _t\) with \(\Delta ^d y_t\). Given the starting value assumption in Assumption 2, this coincides with \(x_t\) defined in (7). Consequently, \(\varepsilon _{t-1}^{**}\) equals \(x_{t-1}^*\) from (9 ), and the LM statistic becomes \(LM\) from (8) as required. \(\square \)

1.2 Proof of Proposition 2

Write the regression equation (13) in obvious matrix notation, \( y = X \, \widehat{\beta }+ \widehat{\varepsilon }\), with

$$\begin{aligned} y^\prime&= (x_2,\ldots ,x_T), \\ \widehat{\beta }^\prime&= (\widehat{\phi }, \, \widehat{\psi }_1,\ldots ,\widehat{\psi }_m), \end{aligned}$$

and \(X\) containing \((x_1^*,\ldots ,x_{T-1}^*)^\prime \) as the first column, while the other columns contain zeros and segments of \((x_{T_j}^*,\ldots ,x_{T_{j+1}-1}^*)^\prime \). Under Assumption 2, we have \(x_{t}=\varepsilon _{t} \sim iid (0,\sigma ^{2})\). The required limiting distributions can be obtained as set out by Robinson (1991) or Tanaka (1999), see also Hassler and Breitung (2006, Lemma A):

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{X^\prime X}{T} \ \overset{p}{\rightarrow } \ \sigma ^{2} \, \frac{\pi ^{2}}{6} \, \Lambda ^0 \end{aligned}$$

where \(\overset{p}{\rightarrow }\) stands for convergence in probability, and

$$\begin{aligned} \Lambda ^0 \!=\! \left( \begin{array}{ll} 1 &{}\quad (\lambda ^0)^\prime \\ \lambda ^0 &{}\quad \text{ diag } (\lambda _2^0-\lambda _1^0,\ldots ,\lambda _{m+1}^0-\lambda _m^0) \end{array} \right) , \quad (\lambda ^0)^\prime \!=\! (\lambda _2^0\!-\!\lambda _1^0,\ldots ,\lambda _{m+1}^0\!-\!\lambda _m^0), \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{X^\prime y}{\sqrt{T}} \ \overset{d}{\rightarrow } \ \mathcal N _{m+1} \left( \left( \begin{array}{ll} 0 &{} \\ \vdots &{} \\ 0 &{} \end{array} \right) , \ \sigma ^{4} \frac{\pi ^{2}}{6} \, \Lambda ^0 \right) . \end{aligned}$$

Consequently, \(\sqrt{T} \, \widehat{\beta }\) follows a limiting normal distribution with \(\Sigma = \frac{6}{\pi ^{2}} \left( \Lambda ^0\right) ^{-1}\). Define the \(m \times (m+1)\) matrix \(R\) with \(R \, \widehat{\beta }=( \widehat{\psi }_1,\ldots ,\widehat{\psi }_m)^\prime \). The \(F\) statistic becomes

$$\begin{aligned} F(\lambda _1^0,\ldots ,\lambda _m^0) = \frac{T-m-1}{m} \, \frac{ \widehat{\beta }^\prime R^\prime \left( R \, (X^\prime X)^{-1} R^\prime \right) ^{-1} R \, \widehat{\beta }}{\widehat{\varepsilon }^\prime \varepsilon }, \end{aligned}$$

and its limiting distribution follows the usual way. \(\square \)

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Hassler, U., Meller, B. Detecting multiple breaks in long memory the case of U.S. inflation. Empir Econ 46, 653–680 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-013-0691-8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-013-0691-8

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation