Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Testing the permanent-income hypothesis: new evidence from West-German states (Länder)

  • original paper
  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper investigates whether time-series data from 11 West-German states (Länder) provide evidence in accord with the implication of the permanent-income hypothesis (PIH) for the stochastic relationship between consumption and income innovations. The empirical results do not support this hypothesis, in the sense that the response of consumption to income innovations is found to be much weaker than is predicted by the PIH. Moreover, for each individual state as well as for Germany as a whole, the response was found to be asymmetric, being stronger for negative than positive income innovations. This evidence of asymmetry is consistent with a model in which consumers are liquidity constrained.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Most of the consumption studies, which use West-German national-level data, typically focus on testing the sensitivity of consumption to predictable changes in income. See, for example, Campbell and Mankiw (1989) and Blundell, Browne and Tarditi (1995). In addition, Reimers (1997) examines the relationship between consumption, income and wealth using the seasonal cointegration technique.

  2. The Appendix discusses the more general cases of time-varying interest rates and risk aversion without certainty equivalence. Time-varying interest rates complicate the mathematics but change nothing important. Absence of certainty equivalence in general prevents an analytical solution for consumption. In specific cases where a solution for C is possible, again nothing important is changed. Thus the simplifying assumptions of a constant interest rate and quadratic utility seem to be reasonable approximations.

  3. Two possibilities are the influx of foreign (notably Turkish) workers and the unification of East and West Germany. Turkish workers' households have different characteristics with regard to the kinds of taste shifting variables identified as important to consumption behavior by other researchers, such as Attanasio and Browning (1995). Their immigration into Germany then could introduce biases in our measures. However, we lack adequate data to address this issue. As for the unification of Germany, our data are restricted to German states of the former West Germany. Only if there were major migrations from East German states to West German states might there be a problem with our estimates. Again, we lack the necessary data to check such a possibility.

  4. The likelihood ratio test statistic is defined as LR=−2[L(c)−L(u)], where L(c) is the log-likelihood value of the constrained model and L(u) is the log-likelihood value of the unconstrained model.

  5. Data prior to 1970 are not available at the state level. For West Berlin, data are available only until 1994.

  6. The results are available upon request from the authors.

  7. We thank the anonymous referee for pointing this out to us.

  8. These results are consistent with Weissenberger (1986), who also rejects the PIH using national-level aggregate German data. Under the maintained assumption that income is stationary around a deterministic trend, he reports that consumption is excessively sensitive to income innovations.

  9. Note however that these authors are concerned with the asymmetric response of consumption to predictable changes in income rather than to innovations in income.

  10. From Eq. 12, the change in permanent income is estimated as \(\widehat{{\theta _{{it}} }} = \chi _{i} \widehat{{\varepsilon _{{it}} }}\)

References

  • Altonji J, Siow A (1987) Testing the response of consumption to income changes with (noisy) panel data. Quarterly Journal of Economics 102:293–328

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Attanasio O, Browning M (1995) Consumption over the life cycle and over the business cycle. American Economic Review 85:1118–1137

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke B (1985) Adjustment costs, durables, and aggregate consumption. Journal of Monetary Economics 15:41–68

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bilson J (1980) The rational expectations approach to the consumption function: a multi-country study. European Economic Review 13:273–299

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard O, Fischer S (1989) Lectures on macroeconomics. MIT: Cambridge, MA

  • Blundell A, Browne F, Tarditi A (1995) Financial liberalization and the permanent income hypothesis. Manchester School 63:125–144

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell J, Mankiw NG (1989) Consumption, income and interest rates: reinterpreting the time aeries evidence. In Blanchard, O. J, Fischer, S (ed.) NBER Macroeconomic Annual, MIT, pp. 185–216

  • Campbell J, Deaton A (1989) Why is consumption so smooth? Review of Economic Studies 56:357–374

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deaton A (1992) Understanding consumption. Clarendon, Oxford

  • Dawson J, DeJuan J, Seater J, Stephenson EF (2001) Economic information versus quality variation in cross-country data. Canadian Journal of Economics 34:988–1009

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • DeJuan J, Seater J, Wirjanto TS (2004) A direct test of the permanent income hypothesis with an application to the US states. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 36:1091–1103

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flavin M (1981) The adjustment of consumption to changing expectations about future income. Journal of Political Economy 89:974–1009

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Flavin M (1993) The excess smoothness of consumption: identification and interpretation. Review of Economic Studies 60:651–666

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M (1957) A theory of the consumption function. Princeton University Press, Princeton

  • Gali J (1991) Budget constraints and time series evidence on consumption. American Economic Review 81:1238–1253

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall A (1994) Testing for a unit root in time series with pretest data-based model selection. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 12:461–470

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Hansen L, Sargent T (1981) A note on Wiener–Kolmogorov prediction formulas for rational expectations models. Economics Letters 9:255–260

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Kotlikoff L, Pakes A (1984) Looking for the news in the noise—additional stochastic implications of optimal consumption choice, National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper 1492

  • MacKinnon JG (1991) Critical values for cointegration tests. In Engle RF, Granger CWJ (eds.), Long-Run Economic Relationships: Readings in Cointegration, Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp

  • Meghir C (2004) A retrospective on Friedman’s theory of permanent income. Economic Journal 114:293–306

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ng S, Perron P (1995) Unit root tests in ARMA models with data dependent methods for the selection of the truncation parameter. Journal of the American Statistical Association 90:268–281

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Quah D (1990) Permanent and transitory movements in labor income: an explanation for “Excess Smoothness” in consumption. Journal of Political Economy 98:449–475

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reimers H (1997) Seasonal cointegration analysis of German consumption function. Empirical Economics 22:205–231

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Said S, Dickey D (1984) Testing for unit roots in autoregressive moving average models of unknown order. Biometrika 71:599–607

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Shea J (1995) Myopia, liquidity constraints, and aggregate consumption: a simple test. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 27:798–805

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weissenberger E (1986) Consumption innovations and income innovations: evidence from UK and Germany. The Review of Economics and Statistics 78:1–8

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • West KD (1988) The insensitivity of consumption to news about income. Journal of Monetary Economics 21:17–34

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank an anonymous referee and the editor of the journal for a number of valuable comments. We also thank Dieter Bergen for the data. The remaining errors are our own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Tony S. Wirjanto.

Appendix

Appendix

Time-varying interest rates

With deterministic time-varying interest rates, the difference equation for W is

$$W_{{i,t + 1}} = {\left( {1 + r_{t} } \right)}W_{{it}} + Y_{{it}} - C_{{it}} $$

The value of W at any time after t is

$$\begin{array}{*{20}c} {W_{{i,t + 1}} }{ = W_{{it}} {\prod\limits_{k = 0}^{i - 1} {{\left( {1 + r_{{t + k}} } \right)} + {\sum\limits_{j = 0}^{i - 1} {E{\left[ {{\left( {Y_{{i,t + j}} - C_{{i,t + j}} } \right)}} \right]}{\prod\limits_{m = j}^{i - 1} {{\left( {1 + r_{{t + 1 + m}} } \right)}} }} }} }} \\ {}{ = {\prod\limits_{k = 0}^{i - 1} {{\left( {1 + r_{{t + k}} } \right)}{\left\{ {W_{{it}} + {\sum\limits_{j = 0}^{i - 1} {{\left[ {E{\left[ {{\left( {Y_{{i,t + j}} - C_{{i,t + j}} } \right)}} \right]}{\prod\limits_{k = 0}^j {{\left( {1 + r_{{t + 1k}} } \right)}^{{ - 1}} } }} \right]}} }} \right\}}} }} \\ \end{array} $$

Discounting both sides gives

$$W_{{i,t + i}} {\prod\limits_{k = 0}^{i - 1} {{\left( {1 + r_{{t + k}} } \right)}^{{ - 1}} } } = W_{{it}} + {\sum\limits_{j = 0}^{i - 1} {{\left[ {E{\left[ {{\left( {Y_{{i,t + j}} - C_{{i,t + j}} } \right)}} \right]}{\prod\limits_{k = 0}^j {{\left( {1 + r_{{t + k}} } \right)}^{{ - 1}} } }} \right]}} }$$

The No-Ponzi condition is that the left side go to zero as i goes to infinity, which implies that

$${\sum\limits_{j = 0}^{i - 1} {{\left[ {E{\left( {C_{{i,t + j}} } \right)}{\prod\limits_{k = 0}^j {{\left( {1 + r_{{t + k}} } \right)}^{{ - 1}} } }} \right]} = W_{{i,t}} + {\sum\limits_{j = 0}^{i - 1} {{\left[ {E{\left( {Y_{{i,t + j}} } \right)}{\prod\limits_{k = 0}^j {{\left( {1 + r_{{t + k}} } \right)}^{{ - 1}} } }} \right]}} }} } = A_{t} $$

where A is total household assets. The general first-order condition is

$$\frac{{{\left( {1 + \rho } \right)}^{{ - 1}} E_{t} {\left[ {U\prime {\left( {C_{{t + j + 1}} } \right)}} \right]}}}{{E_{t} {\left[ {U\prime {\left( {C_{{t + j}} } \right)}} \right]}}} = {\left( {1 + r_{{t + j}} } \right)}^{{ - 1}} $$

For the quadratic utility function

$$U{\left( {C_{t} } \right)} = aC_{t} - bC^{2}_{t} $$

the first-order condition is

$$\frac{{{\left( {1 + \rho } \right)}^{{ - 1}} E_{t} {\left[ {a - 2bC_{{t + j + 1}} } \right]}}}{{E_{t} {\left[ {a - 2bC_{{t + j}} } \right]}}} = {\left( {1 + r_{{t + j}} } \right)}^{{ - 1}} $$

In period t, the value of C t (i.e., for j=0) is known, so we can solve for E[C t+1 ] in terms of C t :

$$E{\left[ {C_{{t + 1}} } \right]} = \frac{a}{{2b}}\frac{{\rho - r_{t} }}{{1 + r_{t} }} + \frac{{1 + \rho }}{{1 + r_{t} }}C_{t} $$

We then can iterate forward to obtain the solution for any future C:

$$\begin{array}{*{20}c} {E{\left[ {C_{{t + i}} } \right]}}{ = \frac{a}{{2b}}{\sum\limits_{j = 0}^{i - 1} {{\left[ {{\left( {\rho - r_{{t + {\left( {i - 1} \right)} - j}} } \right)}{\left( {1 + \rho } \right)}^{j} {\prod\limits_{m = {\left( {i - 1} \right)} - j}^{i - 1} {{\left( {1 + r_{{t + m}} } \right)}^{{ - 1}} } }} \right]}} }} \\ {}{ + {\left( {1 + \rho } \right)}^{i} {\prod\limits_{k = 0}^{i - 1} {{\left( {1 + r_{{t + k}} } \right)}^{{ - 1}} C_{t} } }} \\ \end{array} $$

We next substitute this solution into the budget constraint:

$$A_{t} = {\sum\limits_{I = 0}^m {{\left\{ {{\left( {\frac{a}{{2b}}{\sum\limits_{j = 0}^{i - 1} {{\left[ {{\left( {\rho - r_{{t + {\left( {i - 1} \right)} - j}} } \right)}{\left( {1 + \rho } \right)}^{j} {\prod\limits_{m = {\left( {i - 1} \right)} - j}^{i - 1} {{\left( {1 + r_{{t + m}} } \right)}^{{ - 1}} } }} \right]} + {\left( {1 + \rho } \right)}^{i} {\prod\limits_{k = 0}^{i - 1} {{\left( {1 + r_{{t + k}} } \right)}^{{ - 1}} C_{t} } }} }} \right)}{\prod\limits_{k = 0}^i {{\left( {1 + r_{{t + k}} } \right)}^{{ - 1}} } }} \right\}}} }$$

which can be expressed as

$$A_{t} = \alpha _{t} + \beta _{t} C_{t} $$

where

$$\begin{array}{*{20}c} {\alpha _{t} }{ = {\sum\limits_{i = 0}^m {\left\{ {{\left[ {\frac{a}{{2b}}{\sum\limits_{j = 0}^{i - 1} {{\left( {\rho - r_{{t + {\left( {i - 1} \right)} - j}} } \right)}{\left( {1 + \rho } \right)}^{j} {\prod\limits_{m = {\left( {i - 1} \right)} - j}^{i - 1} {{\left( {1 + r_{{t + m}} } \right)}^{{ - 1}} } }} }} \right]}} \right.} }} \\ {}{\left. {{\prod\limits_{k = 0}^i {{\left( {1 + r_{{t + k}} } \right)}^{{ - 1}} } }} \right\}} \\ \end{array} $$
$$\beta _{t} = {\sum\limits_{i = 0}^m {{\left\{ {{\left[ {{\left( {1 + \rho } \right)}^{i} {\prod\limits_{k = 0}^{i - 1} {{\left( {1 + r_{{t + k}} } \right)}^{{ - 1}} } }} \right]}{\prod\limits_{k = 0}^i {{\left( {1 + r_{{t + k}} } \right)}^{{ - 1}} } }} \right\}}} }$$

Finally, we solve for the optimal value of C t

$$C_{t} = \beta ^{{ - 1}}_{t} A_{t} - \beta ^{{ - 1}}_{t} \alpha _{t} $$

From this expression, we can obtain the response of C t to a change in any future income:

$$\Delta C_{t} = {\left[ {\beta ^{{ - 1}}_{t} {\prod\limits_{k = 0}^{i - 1} {{\left( {1 + r_{{t + k}} } \right)}^{{ - 1}} } }} \right]}\Delta Y_{{t + i}} = \gamma _{{t,i}} \Delta Y_{{t + i}} $$

Notice that, when r t+k =ρ for all k, then γ t,i reduces to the usual (1+r)−(t+1). Because ρ is an attraction for the interest rate, we expect to see r fluctuate closely around ρ in any time series sample of reasonable length with an average value of approximately ρ. Thus in any such sample, we expect γ t,i to be close to (1+r)−(t+1). If Y follows an ARIMA process, then the response of C t to an innovation in Y involves a weighted sum of the γ t,i , where the weights depend on the AR and MA coefficients. Because the γ t,i are time-varying, the weighted sum also will be time-varying, but because the γ t,i are close to (1+r)−(t+1), we expect the weighted sum of the γ t,i to be close to the expression given in Eq. (15) in the main text. For this reason, assuming that the interest rate equals ρ for all time periods is a reasonable simplification that does not alter the results in this paper in any important way.

Absence of certainty equivalence

The general household choice problem without certainty equivalence (i.e., quadratic utility) and uncertainty in labor income is typically not solvable analytically. We can obtain analytical solutions in special cases. For example, suppose that there is uncertainty only in interest rates. Labor income either has no uncertainty or any uncertainty in it can be diversified away through life insurance, unemployment insurance, and other such schemes. We then can obtain analytic solutions for C t for many forms of the utility function, such as members of the HARA class. For example, logarithmic utility yields the result (see Blanchard and Fischer, 1989)

$$C_{t} = \frac{\rho }{{1 + \rho }}W_{t} $$

The problem here is how to define permanent income. Permanent income is the annuity value of lifetime wealth, but it is unclear how to compute that value with a random interest rate. One solution is to use the risk-free interest rate, R. That rate may vary over time (deterministically) but should equal the time preference rate Δ on average. We can use the average value of R to define permanent income as

$$Y^{P}_{t} = \frac{{\overline{R} }}{{1 + \overline{R} }}W_{t} = \frac{\rho }{{1 + \rho }}W_{t} $$

We then immediately have

$$C_{t} = W^{P}_{t} $$

implying that

$$\Delta C_{t} = \Delta Y^{P}_{t} $$

which is the same result as that obtained in the main text with quadratic utility and constant interest rates. Admittedly, this case requires several strong restrictions, but it does show that our assumptions in the main text are at least defensible.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

DeJuan, J.P., Seater, J.J. & Wirjanto, T.S. Testing the permanent-income hypothesis: new evidence from West-German states (Länder). Empirical Economics 31, 613–629 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-005-0035-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-005-0035-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation