Skip to main content

Advertisement

Log in

Inequality in current and lifetime income

  • Published:
Social Choice and Welfare Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

To gauge inequality in living standards, the distribution of lifetime income is likely to be more relevant than the distribution of current income. Yet, empirical studies of income inequality are typically based on observations of income for one or a few years. In this paper, we exploit a unique data set with nearly career-long income histories to assess the role of so-called life-cycle bias in empirical analysis of income inequality that uses current income variables as proxies for lifetime income. We find evidence of substantial life-cycle bias in estimates of inequality based on current income. One implication is that cross-sectional estimates of income inequality are likely to be sensitive to the age composition of the sample. A decomposition of the life-cycle bias into income mobility and heterogeneous profiles reveal the importance of two explanations that have been put forth to explain the disagreement between current and lifetime inequality.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. There are, however, a few studies that use income data over a longer period. A notable example is Björklund (1993), who uses long panel data on income from Sweden to compare the distributions of annual and long-term income. He finds that the inequality in long-run income is around 35–40 % lower than in the cross-sections of annual income. Burkhauser and Poupore (1997) report reductions in income inequality indices of about 15–20 % when the accounting period was extended from 1 to 6 years. Using income data for a whole decade, both Gittleman and Joyce (1999) and Aaberge et al. (2002) find that cross-sectional inequality indices overstate inequality in long-run income by 25–30 %. The focus of these studies is how income mobility reduces inequality in long-run income, and they do not study the issue of life-cycle bias in studies of inequality that use current income as a proxy for lifetime income.

  2. The empirical analysis of Haider and Solon has been replicated and extended for Sweden (Böhlmark and Lindquist 2006), Germany (Brenner 2010), and Norway (Nilsen et al. 2012). See also the discussion in Nybom and Stuhler (2014).

  3. Because of the small scale of the U.S. panel surveys, much of the early research relied on simple models that impose economically implausible restrictions (see the discussions in Baker and Solon 2003). Using rich administrative data, Haider (2001), Baker and Solon (2003), Moffitt and Gottschalk (2012), and Blundell et al. (2014) go beyond earlier models by allowing for key aspects in the evolution of labour income over time and across the life-cycle.

  4. Although the formal retirement age is 67 years, many individuals retire around age 65.

  5. The annual real interest rates on borrowing and savings are computed from Norwegian official statistics on interest rates on loans and deposits in commercial banks over the period 1967–2006.

  6. For a given \(u,\, N(u)\) is the ratio of the mean income of the poorest 100u per cent of the population and the overall mean. By inserting for the Lorenz curve in N(u) it follows straightforwardly that the scaled conditional mean curve is a representation of inequality that is equivalent to the Lorenz curve.

  7. Since \(C_1\), G, and \(C_3\) have a common theoretical foundation and complement each other with regard to sensitivity to changes in the lower and upper part of the income distribution, Aaberge (2007) calls them Gini’s Nuclear Family.

  8. For studies of intergenerational income mobility taking this approach to correct for life-cycle bias, see the review of Black and Devereux (2011).

  9. In comparison, Haider and Solon (2006) find that \(\lambda _{t }\) comes close to 1 when individuals are in their early 40s (and mid 30s), whereas Böhlmark and Lindquist (2006) report that \(\lambda _{t}\) is approximately 1 when individuals are aged 46–53 (and around age 33). It should be noted, however, that these two studies measure income in logs rather than levels. When measuring income in logs, our estimate of \(\lambda _{t}\) is equal to 1 around age 40.

References

  • Aaberge R (2000) Characterizations of Lorenz curves and income distributions. Soc Choice Welf 17:639–653

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aaberge R (2007) Gini’s nuclear family. J Econ Inequal 5:305–322

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aaberge R, Björklund A, Palme M, Pedersen P, Smith N, Wennemo T (2002) Income inequality and income mobility in the Scandinavian countries compared to the United States. Rev Income Wealth 48:443–469

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aaberge R, Mogstad M (2011) Robust inequality comparisons. J Econ Inequal 9:353–371

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Atkinson A, Rainwater L, Smeeding T (1995) Income distribution in OECD countries: evidence from the Luxembourg Income Study. OECD, Report

  • Baker M, Solon G (2003) Earnings dynamics and inequality among Canadian men, 1976–1992: evidence from longitudinal income tax records. J Labor Econ 21:267–288

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Pistaferri L, Preston I (2008) Consumption inequality and partial insurance. Am Econ Rev 98:1887–1921

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blundell R, Graber M, Mogstad M (2014) Labor income dynamics and the insurance from taxes, transfers, and the family. J Public Econ [Epub ahead of print]

  • Bhuller M, Mogstad M, Salvanes K (2014) Life cycle earnings, education premiums and internal rate of returns, NBER Working Paper, 20250

  • Björklund A (1993) A comparison between actual distributions of annual and lifetime income: Sweden 1951–1989. Rev Income Wealth 39:377–386

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Black S, Devereux P (2011) Recent developments in intergenerational mobility. In: Ashenfelter O, Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economics. Elsevier, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Brenner J (2010) Life-cycle variations in the association between current and lifetime earnings: evidence for German natives and guest workers. Labour Econ 17:392–406

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Burkhauser RV, Poupore JG (1997) A cross-national comparison of permanent inequality in the United States and Germany. Rev Econ Stat 79:10–17

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Böhlmark A, Lindquist MJ (2006) Life-cycle variations in the association between current and lifetime income: replication and extension for Sweden. J Labor Econ 24:879–900

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M (1957) A theory of the consumption function. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Gittleman M, Joyce M (1999) Have family income mobility patterns changed? Demography 36:299–314

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haider S (2001) Earnings instability and earnings inequality of males in the United States: 1967–1991. J Labor Econ 19:799–836

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haider S, Solon G (2006) Life-cycle variation in the association between current and lifetime earnings. Am Econ Rev 96:1308–1320

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Jenkins SP, Van Kerm P (2006) Trends in income inequality. Pro-poor income growth and income mobility. Oxf Econ Pap 58:531–548

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nybom, M, and J. Stuhler (2014) Heterogeneous income profiles and life-cycle bias in intergenerational mobility estimation, Working Paper

  • Meghir C, Pistaferri L (2011) Earnings, consumption and lifecycle choices. In: Ashenfelter O, Card D (eds) Handbook of labor economics. Elsevier, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Mincer J (1958) Investment in human capital and personal income distribution. J Polit Econ 66:281–302

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moffitt R, Gottschalk P (2012) Trends in the transitory variance of male earnings: methods and evidence. J Human Resour 47:204–236

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nilsen Ø, Vaage K, Aakvik A, Jacobsen K (2012) Intergenerational earnings mobility revisited: estimates based on lifetime earnings. Scand J Econ 114:1–23

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shorrocks A (1978) Income inequality and income mobility. J Econ Theory 19:376–393

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wiles P (1974) Distribution of income, East and West. North Holland Publishing Company, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Willis RJ, Rosen S (1979) Education and self-selection. J Polit Econ 87:7–36

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We thank two anonymous referees, the editor and Anders Björklund for helpful comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Rolf Aaberge.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Aaberge, R., Mogstad, M. Inequality in current and lifetime income. Soc Choice Welf 44, 217–230 (2015). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-014-0838-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00355-014-0838-3

Keywords

Navigation