Skip to main content
Log in

Framework for regulation of the consumer marketplace

Zur Regulierung von Konsumgütermärkten

  • Articles
  • Published:
Journal of Consumer Policy Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Recent critiques of the costs, effectiveness, and potential inequities in consumer protection measures have drawn attention to the need for a coherent normative framework for consumer protection. This paper sketches therefore a framework for government intervention in the marketplace to protect consumers' economic interests.

After outlining the overarching objectives of consumer protection, namely the improvement of economic efficiency and equity, it documents the two main failures in consumer markets, information and high enforcement costs. Discussion is then focused on the relevance of the recent “economics of information” literature and its implications in consumer protection. Finally, there is a brief discussion of equity rationales. The article concludes by drawing out the general policy implications of the approach adopted in the paper.

Zusammenfassung

Die neuere Kritik an den Kosten, an der Wirksamkeit und an den potentiellen Ungerechtigkeiten verbraucherpolitischer Instrumente macht deutlich, daß ein systematischer normativ-theoretischer Hintergrund für die Verbraucherpolitik nötig ist. Allgemeine Hinweise auf unausgewogene Marktmacht reichen im nach-regulatorischen Stadium nicht mehr aus.

Der vorliegende Beitrag umreißt daher einen Rahmen für staatliche Intervention auf M:arkten zum Schutz des Verbraucherinteresses. Zunächst werden die Verbesserung sowohl der ökonomischen Effizienz als auch der Gleichrangigkeit als die beiden Hauptziele der Verbraucherpolitik und ihre Beziehungen untereinander angesprochen. Es folgt eine Behandlung der Interventionsbegründungen unter dem Gesichtspunkt der Effizienz mit einer Diskussion der neueren Literatur zur Informationsökonomie in ihrer Bedeutung für die Identifizierung von Informationsunzulänglichkeiten zuf Konsumgütermärkten und eine Behandlung der Interventionsbegründungen unter dem Gesichtspunkt der Gleichrangigkeit.

Als Schlußfolgerung ergibt sich, daß Interventionen in höherem Maße markt- und produkt-spezifisch sein sollten; dies muß mit der Forderung nach längerfristiger Klarheit und Vorhersagbarkeit von Regelungen und Standards in Einklang gebracht werden. Abschließend wird darauf hingewiesen, daß trotz aller rationaler Rechtfertigungen, die der Beitrag liefert, die Entscheidung zur Intervention im Kern politischer Natur ist.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Akerlof, G. (1970). The market for “lemons”: Qualitative uncertainty and the market mechanism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 84, 488–500.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barry, B. (1965). Political argument. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bator, F. (1958). The anatomy of market failure. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 72, 351–379.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baumol, W., & Blinder, A. S. (1982). Economics: Principles and policy. New York: Harcourt Brace Jovanovich.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beales, H., Craswell, R., & Salop, S. (1981). The efficient regulation of consumer information. Journal of Law and Economics, 24, 491–539.

    Google Scholar 

  • Belobaba, E. (1983). Consumer product warranty reform: Regulation in search of rationality. Ottawa: Consumer and Corporate Affairs Canada.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bourgoignie, T. (1984). The need to reformulate consumer protection policy. Journal of Consumer Policy, 7, 307–321.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breyer, S. (1982). Regulation and its reform. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cave, M. (1985). Market models and consumer protection. Journal of Consumer Policy, 8, 335–351.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cayne, D. J., & Trebilcock, M. J. (1973). Market considerations in the formulation of consumer protection policy. University of Toronto Law Journal, 23, 396–430.

    Google Scholar 

  • C. B. I. (1979). Pilot study of the additional costs to the British consumer of compliance by industry with consumer legislation. London: Economist Intelligence Unit.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1960). The problem of social cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dawson, J. (1976). Unconscionable coercion: The German version. Harvard Law Review, 89, 1041–1126.

    Google Scholar 

  • Department of Trade and Industry (U.K.) (1985). Burdens on business. London: Her Majesty's Stationery Office.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dewees, D. (1983). The regulation of quality: Products, services, workplaces, and the environment. Toronto: Butterworths.

    Google Scholar 

  • Diver, C. S. (1983). The optimal precision of administrative rules. Yale Law Journal, 93, 65–109.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Consumer Law Group (1983). Group actions in the consumer interest. Journal of Consumer Policy, 6, 325–350.

    Google Scholar 

  • Federal Trade Commission (1979). Consumer information remedies. Washington, D.C.: Federal Trade Commission.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goyens, M. (Ed.) (1985). E.C. competition policy and the consumer interest. Brussels: Cabay-Bruylant.

    Google Scholar 

  • Handler, J. F. (1978). Social movements and the legal system. New York: Academic Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, T. T., & Pickering, J. F. (1979). The consumer's interest in competition policy. I. Welfare implications. II. Policy implications. Journal of Consumer Studies and Home Economics, 3, 85–126.

    Google Scholar 

  • Komesar, N. (1981). In search of a general approach to legal analysis: A comparative institutional alternative. Michigan Law Review, 79, 1350–1392.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kronman, A. T. (1983). Paternalism and the law of contracts. Yale Law Journal, 92, 763–798.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mishan, E. J. (1982). Cost-benefit analysis (3rd ed.). London: Allen & Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • MIT (1978). Consumer durables: Warranties, service contracts, and alternatives. Cambridge, MA: Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Center for Policy Alternatives.

    Google Scholar 

  • National Consumer Council (1980). Consumers and credit. London: National Consumer Council.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, P. (1970). Information and consumer behavior. Journal of Political Economy, 78, 311–329.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nisbett, R. E., & Ross, L. (1980). Human inference: Strategies and shortcomings of social judgment. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nozick, R. (1974). Anarchy, state, and utopia. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Office of Fair Trading (1982). Opticians and competition: A report by the Director General of Fair Trading on sections 21 and 25 of the Opticians Act 1958. London: Her Majesty's Stationery Office.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pertschuk, M. (1982). Revolt against regulation: The rise and pause of the consumer movement. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pitofsky, R. (1977). Beyond Nader: Consumer protection and the regulation of advertising. Harvard Law Review, 90, 661–701.

    Google Scholar 

  • Priest, G. (1981). A theory of the consumer product warranty. Yale Law Journal, 90, 1297–1352.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rakoff, T. (1982). Contracts of adhesion: An essay in reconstruction. Harvard Law Review, 96, 1174–1284.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramsay, I. (1981). Consumer redress mechanisms for defective and poor quality products. University of Toronto Law Journal, 31, 117–152.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ramsay, I. (1984). Rationales for intervention in the consumer marketplace. London: Office of Fair Trading.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rawls, J. (1971). A theory of justice. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reich, R. B. (1979). Towards a new consumer protection. University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 128, 1–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Royal Commission on Legal Services (1979). Final report. Cmnd. 7648. London: Her Majesty's Stationery Office.

    Google Scholar 

  • Road Traffic Reports (1972). Robertson v. di Cicco, 431.

  • Scherer, F. (1980). Industrial market structure and economic performance (2nd ed.). Chicago. Rand McNally.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, G., & Wilde, L. (1979). Intervening in markets on the basis of imperfect information: A legal and economic analysis. University of Pennsylvania Law Review, 127, 630–683.

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon, H. (1975). Administrative behavior (3rd ed.). New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. (1961). The economics of information. Journal of Political Economy, 69, 213–225.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. J. (1975). The citizen and the state. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stone, C. (1976). Where the law ends: The social control of corporate behavior. New York: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stewart, R., & Sunstein, C. (1982). Public programs and private rights. Harvard Law Review, 95, 1195–1322.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stuyck, J. (1983). Product differentiation: The legal situation. Deventer: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sugden, R., & Williams, A. (1978). The principles of practical cost-benefit analysis. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Swann, D. (1979). Competition and consumer protection. Harmondsworth: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Teubner, G. (1983). Substantive and reflexive elements in modern law. Law and Society Review, 17, 239–285.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trebilcock, M. (1976). Winners and losers in the modern regulatory state: Must the consumer always lose? Osgoode Hall Law Journal, 13, 619–647.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trebilcock, M. J. (1980). The consumer interest and the regulatory process. In: A. J. Duggan & L. W. Darvall (Eds.), Consumer protection law and theory, pp. 257–269. Sydney: Law Book.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trebilcock, M. J., Hartle, D. G., Prichard, I. J. S., & Dewees, D. N. (Eds.) (1982). The choice of governing instrument. Ottawa: Economic Council of Canada.

    Google Scholar 

  • Unfair terms in contracts concluded with consumers (1984). Brussels: E.C. Supp. 1/84.

  • Veljanovski, C. G., & Whelan, C. (1983). Professional negligence and the quality of legal services: An economic perspective. Modern Law Review 46, 700–718.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weisbrod, B. A., Handler, J. F., & Komesar, N. K. (1978). Public interest law: An economic and institutional analysis. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Whitford, W. (1973). The functions of disclosure legislation in consumer transactions. Wisconsin Law Review, 400–470.

  • Williams, F. (Ed.) (1977). Why the poor pay more, London: Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williamson, O. (1984). Corporate governance. Yale Law Journal, 93, 1197–1230.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Additional information

Iain Ramsay is a Lecturer at the Faculty of Law, University of Newcastle upon Tyne, 22–24 Windsor Terrace, Newcastle upon Tyne NE1 7RU, England. This article is a summary of ideas which are developed at greater length in I. Ramsay: Rationales for intervention in the consumer marketplace, Occasional Paper, Office of Fair Trading, London. Copies of this study may be obtained from the Office of Fair Trading.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ramsay, I. Framework for regulation of the consumer marketplace. J Consum Policy 8, 353–372 (1985). https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00380247

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00380247

Keywords

Navigation