Skip to main content
Log in

Expropriation of foreign direct investments: Empirical evidence and implications for the debt crisis

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Conclusions

The message from the empirical tests is the following. First, we were not able to support the public-interest hypothesis stating that selective expropriations are driven by a national-welfare calculus with costs and benefits directly related to the technological characteristics of foreign firms. Instead, the hypothesis that governments decide on expropriations with regard to their political self-interest seems to be more appropriate. This is true if we look at more widespread expropriations that are unspecific in terms of technological standards (industries). The main factor that drives politically motivated expropriations is the poor overall economic performance of a country, which reinforces earlier findings (e.g., Picht, 1988: 351).

Additional regressions were run for selective expropriations that included political-economy variables. The results were as discouraging as the results for the “pure” public-interest calculus. The only explanation of why overall national welfare considerations as expressed by selective rather than unspecific expropriations are not reflected at all in the empirical results we can think of is that either government illusion about its potential or ignorance prevailed. This does not seem to be totally unrealistic (Tullock, 1986: 9–11) in a world where authoritarian governments are dominant with its extreme form being the dictatorship.Footnote 1 In fact, a look at the list of countries covered by this analysis does not leave any doubts in this respect.

Second, these findings suggest also that LDC governments may face difficulties if they try to attract more FDI to compensate for limits encountered with respect to new bank loans. The same reasons that lead creditors to restrict new lending, i.e., poor economic performance (e.g., Nunnenkamp and Picht, 1989; Picht, 1988: 349) may also induce foreign investors to hesitate with new investments. Apparently, firm-specific measures of self-protection (Ehrlich and Becker, 1972) as the use of technologies that increase the cost of expropriation for the host country do not have much impact in realistic settings.

Third, LDC governments must build up a reputation that they do not succumb to the political pressures against foreign investors and lenders in case of sluggish economic performance. Otherwise the access to foreign sources of finance, in particular to loans and foreign direct investments, will be restricted just in times of emerging economic difficulties, i.e., when additional foreign financing is most urgently needed. Thus, arrangements that serve as “institutional collaterals” need to be found that specifically address the government's incentive to expropriate and willfully default when the economic performance is poor. Yet it is much more difficult to imagine how such arrangements may look like if the presumption is that one is dealing, more often than not, with non-democratic, ultimately politically unaccountable regimes. The same difficulty, of course, arises with respect to sovereign borrowing, for which FDI might substitute, where patterns of self-enforcing contracts come to bear (Picht, 1990).

It is interesting to add, fourth, that external shocks, which may eventually lead to real income losses in the future, initially seem to reduce the likelihood of an expropriation. It is perhaps here were expropriation risks differ systematically from default risks, since some empirical evidence is available that suggests that the risk of willful default increases with external strains (e.g., Nunnenkamp and Picht, 1989; Picht, 1988: 349). The difference might be that the change in the expropriation risk follows with some lag to the initial shock. In other words, the variable measuring the external shock might be taken as a leading indicator with respect to the exposure to expropriation risk.

Finally, from all that has been said it may be obvious that the present euphoria with respect to debt-for-equity swaps in LDC financing as a way of converting existing ‘old’ debt into FDIs should be looked at with caution from the sovereign-risk perspective. This aspect has largely been ignored until present.Footnote 2 The reason, of course, is that the international debt crisis was predominantly viewed as either a liquidity or a solvency problem, and not as a matter of government opportunism towards foreign creditors and investors alike.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. “The dictator ... has not to worry about the policy outcomes of his decisions, but about their effect on other high officials and on other powers in his government. ... He may in various ways sacrifice the welfare of the state for his own continuance in office” (Tullock 1987: 116, own emphasis).

  2. For a recent survey see, for instance, Roberts and Remolona (1987).

References

  • Altman, E.J., Avery, R.B., Eisenbeis, R.A. and Sinkey, J.F. (1981). Application of classification techniques in business, banking and finance. Contemporary Studies in Economics and Financial Analysis 3. Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Balassa, B. (1981). The newly-industrializing developing countries after the oil-crisis. Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv 117: 142–194.

    Google Scholar 

  • Basche, J.R. (1979). Nationalization: The experience of US companies in the 1970s. The Conference Board Information Bulletin 62 (August): 1–18.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burton, F.N. and Inoue, H. (1984). Expropriation of foreign-owned firms in developing countries. Journal of World Trade Law 18: 396–414.

    Google Scholar 

  • Burton, F.N. and Inoue, H. (n.d.). Nationalization of foreign owned properties in developing countries: 1960–1977. Department of Management Sciences, University of Manchester, Institute of Sciences and Technology, England; and Nikko Research Center, Tokyo.

  • Casson, M. (1987). Multinational firms. In R. Clarke and T. McGuiness (Eds.), The economics of the firm, 133–164. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Caves, R.E. (1982). Multinational enterprise and economic analysis. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Davies, W. (1981). Beyond the earthquake allegory: Managing political risk vulnerability. Management International Review 21: 5–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eaton, J. and Gersovitz, M. (1983). Country risk: Economic aspects. In R.J. Herring (Ed.), Managing international risk, 75–108. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eaton, J. and Gersovitz, M. (1984). A theory of expropriation and deviations from perfect capital mobility. The Economic Journal 94: 16–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ehrlich, I. and Becker, G.S. (1972). Market insurance, self-insurance, and self-protection. Journal of Political Economy 80: 623–648.

    Google Scholar 

  • IMF, Direction of Trade Statistics. (DTS). Washington, various issues.

  • IMF, International Financial Statistics. (IFS). Washington, various issues.

  • IFM, Balance of Payments Statistics. (BPS). Washington, various issues.

  • Jodice, D.A. (1980). Sources of change in Third World regimes for foreign direct investment, 1968–1976. International Organization 34: 177–206.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jones, R. (1984). Empirical models of political risk in US oil production operations in Venezuela. The Journal of International Business Studies 15: 81–95.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kobrin, S.J. (1978). When does political instability result in increased investment risk? The Columbia Journal of World Business 13: 113–122.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kobrin, S.J. (1980). Foreign enterprise and forced divestment in LDCs. International Organization 34: 65–88.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lächler, U. (1985). Debt versus equity in development finance. Kiel Working Paper 248 (December).

  • Lloyd, B. (1974). The identification and assessment of political risk in the international environment. Long Range Planning 7: 24–31.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nunnenkamp, P. and Picht, H. (1989). Willful default by developing countries in the 1980s: A cross country analysis of major determinants. Review of World Economics 125(4), forthcoming.

  • OECD (1976). Preliminary estimate of the stock of direct private investment of D.A.C. members in developing countries, end 1975. Paris.

  • Picht, H. (1988). The political economy of debt repudiation and expropriation in LDCs. In D. Laussel, W. Marrois, and A. Soubeyran (Eds.), Monetary theory and policy, 329–383. Berlin, Heidelberg, New York: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Picht, H. (1990). “Sovereign credit and contingency rules on insolvency.” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics, forthcoming.

  • Roberts, D.L. and Remolana, E.M. (1987). Debt swaps: A technique in developing country finance. In Group of Thirty (Ed.), Finance for developing countries, 15–40, New York.

  • Rubin, B. (1987). Modern dictators: Third World coup makers, strongmen, and populist tyrants. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sachs, J.D. (1983). Theoretical issue in international borrowing. NBER Working Paper 1189, Cambridge, MA (August).

  • Stoever, W.A. (1982). Endowments, priorities, and policies: An analytical scheme for the formation of developing country policy toward foreign investment. The Columbia Journal of World Business 17: 3–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Truitt, J.F. (1984). Expropriation of private foreign investment. International business research series 3. Graduate School of Business, Bloomington.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1986). Industrial organization and rent-seeking in dictatorship. Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 142: 4–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1987). Autocracy. Dordrecht: Kluwer.

    Google Scholar 

  • UNCTAD (1987). Handbook of international trade and development statistics, 1986 supplement. New York.

  • World Bank. World debt tables, various issues.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Picht, H., Stüven, V. Expropriation of foreign direct investments: Empirical evidence and implications for the debt crisis. Public Choice 69, 19–38 (1991). https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00123852

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00123852

Keywords

Navigation