Skip to main content

Critiques of the Two-Sector Mahalanobis Model

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Mahalanobis Growth Model

Abstract

The Mahalanobis model attracted worldwide attention by academic economists, statisticians, and development practitioners in the field. In this chapter, we detail what we feel are the most important of these critiques, due to Martin Bronfenbrenner, Charles Bettelheim, Hannan Ezikiel, and J.B.S. Haldane. We discuss the implications of these criticisms for the Mahalanobis model both analytically and computationally. These critiques are based on the Mahalanobis model outlined in Chap. 2, which is a closed-economy model.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 39.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 54.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 79.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Uzawa notes that “the more I studied Mahalanobis’ work, the more I felt uneasy about this relationship between the stability of the dynamic system and factor price intensities of consumption goods and investment goods” (p. 407). See Okuno-Fujiwara and Shell (2009).

  2. 2.

    One of the critiques, due to Charles Bettelheim, is not publicly available. A hard copy is located in the Mahalanobis Museum on the ISI Calcutta campus in the archives. The basis for discussing this article therefore is solely this hard copy, as we are unable to locate a published version of this article.

  3. 3.

    Martin Bronfenbrenner (1914–1997) was a distinguished fellow of the American Economic Association. This is a highly selective award made to the most prominent scholars in the economics profession. See https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Martin_Bronfenbrenner for his contributions to the field and profession.

  4. 4.

    Bronfenbrenner does not assume the standard law of motion of capital as given by (2.10). His special assumption helped him to derive the fundamental output Eq. (2.20) using his setup and to obtain constant growth rates.

  5. 5.

    As we will discuss in the subsequent sections, the perfect shiftability of capital was also subject to criticism. See Ezekiel (1966).

  6. 6.

    More recent two-sector growth models (see Rebelo 1991) also assume that the investment good is produced linearly with capital. The dating assumption of production in Rebelo—who writes down a model based on continuous time—is however different, i.e., output in period t is a function of \(K_{t}\) and not \(K_{t-1}.\) Even if we use this alternative dating specification in the Bronfenbrenner model, we get the same result that output growth is constant.

  7. 7.

    Hannan Ezekiel was a professional economist, public speaker, teacher/trainer, writer/editor and business and economic consultant. He was a former editor of the Economic Times, a leading business daily in India. He also worked at the IMF.

  8. 8.

    See Bronfenbrenner (1996).

  9. 9.

    In fact, it can be shown that growth rates for \(\Delta {C_{t}}\) and \(\Delta {I_{t}}\) obtained here are identical to the growth rates for \(\Delta {C_{t}}\) and \(\Delta {I_{t}}\) from the Mahalanobis model.

  10. 10.

    Charles Bettelheim (1913–2006) was a French Marxian economist and historian. He was an advisor to several developing economies including India. See https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Charles_Bettelheim

  11. 11.

    Replacement requirements correspond to expenses on equipment such as repair works, furnishing, etc. to take care of wear and tear. These are essential for maintaining an asset/equipment in its normal state and are hence the value of equipment needed for replacement of the depreciated capital stock every year.

  12. 12.

    In Solow-Swan parlance, capital deepening must exceed capital widening for the change in the capital stock to be positive.

  13. 13.

    We will see shortly that \(\lambda _{i}^{*}\) is given by Eq. (4.39). Given parameter values, \(\lambda _{i}^{*}=0.54762\) is obtained under the assumption of a \(10\%\) replacement requirement with respect to total net investment, i.e., for \(mc=10.\)

  14. 14.

    We leave it to the reader to check whether at \(\lambda _{i}=\lambda _{i}^{*}\) consumption and investment grow at a constant and equal rate to output.

  15. 15.

    We leave it to the reader to verify this.

  16. 16.

    This is analogous to the critical value of \(\widehat{\lambda }_{i}=\frac{\alpha _{0}\beta _{c}}{(1-\alpha _{0})\beta _{i}+\alpha _{0}\beta _{c}}\) in the Mahalanobis model.

  17. 17.

    See Appendix 4.B.

  18. 18.

    J. B. S Haldane (1892–1964) was a British scientist whose political dissent against England made him leave England for India in 1956. He joined the Indian Statistical Institute—Calcutta in the same year, heading the biometry unit. He became a naturalized Indian citizen in 1961. See https://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/J._B._S._Haldane

  19. 19.

    The exponential series can be expanded as follows:

    $$\begin{aligned} e^{x}=1+x+\frac{x^{2}}{2!}+\frac{x^{3}}{3!}+..... \end{aligned}$$

    For very small values of x

    $$\begin{aligned} e^{x}\approx 1+x. \end{aligned}$$

    Given that \(\lambda _{i}\in \left( 0,1\right) \) and \(\beta _{i}=0.1,\) \(\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}\) is sufficiently small to eliminate higher powers, i.e., \(\left( \lambda _{i}\beta _{i}\right) ^{n},\) where \(n=2,3,4,....\)

  20. 20.

    Contour lines are plane sections of a three-dimensional graph where each line represents a function of two variables but taking a unique value. That is

    $$\begin{aligned} g\left( x,y\right) =\overline{g}. \end{aligned}$$

    Therefore, different values of x and y yield the same value of \(g\left( .\right) =\overline{g}.\)

  21. 21.

    See Appendix 4.C for derivation of Eqs. (4.43) and (4.44) and for final expressions presented in Eqs. (4.45)–(4.46).

  22. 22.

    This means, \(\beta _{i}\) and \(\beta _{c}\) can depend endogenously on consumption, via increased intake of nutrition and health expenditure, which was indicated by Haldane but not explicitly modeled. Modern macroeconomics offers a vast literature on the nutritional effects of productivity . See Arora (2001); Mayer (2001); Bloom et al. (2004), Fogel (2004); Weil (2014); Gopalakrishnan and Saha (2001) to name a few papers.

  23. 23.

    \(Y_{n0}=Y_{0}\)

References

  • Arora, S. 2001. Health, human productivity, and long-term economic growth. The Journal of Economic History 61: 699–749.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bettelheim, Charles, 1954. Investment allocation and increase in national income. In Studies Relating to Planning for National Development, Working Paper No. 10/R.U.1.6., December 24, 1954.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bloom, D.E., D. Canning, and J. Sevilla. 2004. The effect of health on economic growth: A production function approach. World Development 32: 1–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bronfenbrenner, M., 1960. A simplified Mahalanobis development model. Economic Development and Cultural Change 9(1, part 1): 45–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bronfenbrenner, M. 1966. A comment on Bronfenbrenner’s simplified Mahalanobis development model: Reply. Economic Development and Cultural Change 14 (3): 363.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ezekiel, H. 1966. A comment on Bronfenbrenner’s simplified Mahalanobis model. Economic Development and Cultural Change 14 (3): 361–362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fogel, R.W. 2004. Health, nutrition, and economic growth. Economic Development and Cultural Change 52: 643–658.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gopalakrishnan, P., and A. Saha. 2021. Tax policy and food security: A dynamic analysis. Macroeconomic Dynamics 25 (3): 795–823.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haldane, J.B.S. 1955. The maximization of national income. Sankhyā: The Indian Journal of Statistics (1933–1969) 16(1/2): 63–89.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayer, D. 2001. The long-term impact of health on economic growth in Latin America. World Development 29: 1025–1033.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mahalanobis, P.C. 1953. Some observations on the process of growth of national income. Sankhyā: The Indian Journal of Statistics (1933–1969) 12(4): 1–2.

    Google Scholar 

  • Okuno-Fujiwara, M., and K. Shell. 2009. [MD interview] an interview with Hirofumi Fujiwara. Macroeconomic Dynamics 390–420.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rebelo, S. 1991. Long-run policy analysis and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy 99 (3): 500–521.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weil, D.N. 2014. Health and economic growth. In Handbook of Economic Growth 2: 623–682.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Chetan Ghate .

4.1 Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (zip 317 KB)

4.7 Technical Appendix

4.7 Technical Appendix

4.A Mahalanobis Model v/s Bettelheim Model—Comparison of Output for a given \(\lambda _{i}\) : From Eqs. (2.20) and (4.26), suppose \(Y_{t}^{Bet}\) and \(Y_{t}^{MM}\) denote the output in the Bettelheim model and the Mahalanobis model, respectively.Footnote 23

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{t}^{Bet}=Y_{0}\left[ 1+\alpha _{0}\left( \lambda _{i}\beta _{i}+\lambda _{c}\beta _{c}\right) \left( \frac{\left( 1+\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}-\frac{\lambda _{c}}{mc}\right) ^{t}-1}{\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}-\frac{\lambda _{c}}{mc}}\right) \right] \end{aligned}$$
$$\begin{aligned} Y_{t}^{MM}=Y_{0}\left[ 1+\alpha _{0}\left( \lambda _{i}\beta _{i}+\lambda _{c}\beta _{c}\right) \left( \frac{\left( 1+\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}\right) ^{t}-1}{\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}}\right) \right] . \end{aligned}$$

For a given \(\lambda _{i}\) in an economy, let us compare the absolute value of net outputs in the two models.

If \(\frac{1}{mc}=0\), then Mahalanobis model gives the same national income as the Bettelheim model, i.e., \(Y_{t}^{MM}=Y_{t}^{Bet}\) \(\forall t.\) Also, \(Y_{t}^{MM}=Y_{t}^{Bet}\) \(\forall mc\) for \(t=1.\)

For \(t>1,\) intuitively, both numerator and denominator of \(Y_{t}^{Bet}\) are less than that of \(Y_{t}^{MM}.\) But since the numerator is raised to the power t,  the negative impact of lower numerator is higher than the positive effect of lower denominator. This makes \(Y_{t}^{Bet}<Y_{t}^{MM}.\) Suppose \(a = \alpha _0\), \(x = \lambda _i\beta _i\), and suppose,

\(Z=a\left( \frac{\left( 1+x\right) ^{t}-1}{x}\right) .\) Differentiating Z with respect to x

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{dZ}{dx}=\frac{a}{x^{2}}\left[ ((t-1)x-1)(1+x)^{t-1}+1\right] >0. \end{aligned}$$

Since, Z is increasing in x,  this implies

$$\begin{aligned} \alpha _{0}\left( \lambda _{i}\beta _{i}+\lambda _{c}\beta _{c}\right) \left( \frac{\left( 1+\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}-\frac{\lambda _{c}}{mc}\right) ^{t}-1}{\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}-\frac{\lambda _{c}}{mc}}\right) <\alpha _{0}\left( \lambda _{i}\beta _{i}+\lambda _{c}\beta _{c}\right) \left( \frac{\left( 1+\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}\right) ^{t}-1}{\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}}\right) , \end{aligned}$$

i.e., \(Y_{t}^{MM}>Y_{t}^{Bet}\) for a given \(\lambda _{i}\) in an economy for all values of mc and \(t>1.\)

Now, comparing the relative net outputs in the two models for a given \(\lambda _{i}\),

$$\begin{aligned} \left( \frac{Y_{t+1}}{Y_{t}}\right) ^{MM}=\frac{\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}+\alpha _{0}\beta \left[ \left( 1+\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}\right) ^{t+1}-1\right] }{\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}+\alpha _{0}\beta \left[ \left( 1+\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}\right) ^{t}-1\right] } \end{aligned}$$
$$\begin{aligned} \left( \frac{Y_{t+1}}{Y_{t}}\right) ^{Bet}=\frac{\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}-\frac{\lambda _{c}}{mc}+\alpha _{0}\beta \left[ \left( 1+\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}-\frac{\lambda _{c}}{mc}\right) ^{t+1}-1\right] }{\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}-\frac{\lambda _{c}}{mc}+\alpha _{0}\beta \left[ \left( 1+\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}-\frac{\lambda _{c}}{mc}\right) ^{t}-1\right] }. \end{aligned}$$

We get \(\left( \frac{Y_{t+1}}{Y_{t}}\right) ^{MM}=\left( \frac{Y_{t+1}}{Y_{t}}\right) ^{Bet}\) if \(\frac{1}{mc}=0\) and \(\left( \frac{Y_{t+1}}{Y_{t}}\right) ^{MM}>\left( \frac{Y_{t+1}}{Y_{t}}\right) ^{Bet}\) if \(\frac{1}{mc}>0\) because

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}+\alpha _{0}\beta \left[ \left( 1+\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}\right) ^{t+1}-1\right] }{\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}+\alpha _{0}\beta \left[ \left( 1+\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}\right) ^{t}-1\right] }\gtreqless \frac{\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}-\frac{\lambda _{c}}{mc}+\alpha _{0}\beta \left[ \left( 1+\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}-\frac{\lambda _{c}}{mc}\right) ^{t+1}-1\right] }{\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}-\frac{\lambda _{c}}{mc}+\alpha _{0}\beta \left[ \left( 1+\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}-\frac{\lambda _{c}}{mc}\right) ^{t}-1\right] }. \end{aligned}$$

By cross multiplication and canceling the terms, we get

$$\begin{aligned} \left( 1+\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}\right) ^{t}\left[ \begin{array}{c} \left( \lambda _{i}\beta _{i}\right) ^{2}-\frac{\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}\lambda _{c}}{mc}- \\ \alpha _{0}\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}\beta +\frac{\alpha _{0}\lambda _{c}\beta }{mc}\left( 1+\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}-\frac{\lambda _{c}}{mc}\right) ^{t}\end{array}\right] \gtreqless \left( 1+\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}-\frac{\lambda _{c}}{mc}\right) ^{t}\left[ \begin{array}{c} \left( \lambda _{i}\beta _{i}\right) ^{2}-\frac{\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}\lambda _{c}}{mc} \\ -\alpha _{0}\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}\beta +\frac{\alpha _{0}\lambda _{c}\beta }{mc}\end{array}\right] . \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, as long as \(\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}-\frac{\lambda _{c}}{mc}>0,\) \(\left( 1+\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}-\frac{\lambda _{c}}{mc}\right) ^{t}>1\) and \(\left( 1+\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}\right) ^{t}>\left( 1+\lambda _{i}\beta _{i}-\frac{\lambda _{c}}{mc}\right) ^{t},\) \(L.H.S>R.H.S.\) This implies that \(\left( \frac{Y_{t+1}}{Y_{t}}\right) ^{MM}>\left( \frac{Y_{t+1}}{Y_{t}}\right) ^{Bet}\) \(\forall t\) and \(\forall \frac{1}{mc}>0\) for a given \(\lambda _{i}\) in an economy.

4.B Mahalanobis Model versus Bettelheim Model—Comparison of Output at respective critical values: At \(\lambda _{i}=\frac{\alpha _{0}\beta _{c}}{(1-\alpha _{0})\beta _{i}+\alpha _{0}\beta _{c}}=\widehat{\lambda }_{i},\)

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{t}^{MM}=Y_{0}\left[ 1+\alpha _{0}\beta ^{MM}\left( \frac{\left( 1+\widehat{\lambda }_{i}\beta _{i}\right) ^{t}-1}{\widehat{\lambda }_{i}\beta _{i}}\right) \right] , \end{aligned}$$

where \(\beta ^{MM}=\widehat{\lambda }_{i}\beta _{i}+(1-\widehat{\lambda }_{i})\beta _{c}.\) Substituting the value of \(\widehat{\lambda }_{i},\) we get

$$\begin{aligned} \beta ^{MM}=\frac{\alpha _{0}\beta _{c}\beta _{i}}{(1-\alpha _{0})\beta _{i}+\alpha _{0}\beta _{c}}+\frac{(1-\alpha _{0})\beta _{i}\beta _{c}}{(1-\alpha _{0})\beta _{i}+\alpha _{0}\beta _{c}}=\frac{\beta _{i}\beta _{c}}{(1-\alpha _{0})\beta _{i}+\alpha _{0}\beta _{c}} \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \widehat{\lambda }_{i}\beta _{i}=\frac{\alpha _{0}\beta _{c}\beta _{i}}{(1-\alpha _{0})\beta _{i}+\alpha _{0}\beta _{c}}. \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, we get

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{t}^{MM}=Y_{0}\left( 1+\widehat{\lambda }_{i}\beta _{i}\right) ^{t}. \end{aligned}$$

At \(\lambda _{i}=\frac{\frac{1}{mc}+\alpha _{0}\beta _{c}}{\frac{1}{mc}+(1-\alpha _{0})\beta _{i}+\alpha _{0}\beta _{c}}=\lambda _{i}^{*},\)

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{t}^{Bet}=Y_{0}\left[ 1+\alpha _{0}\beta ^{Bet}\left( \frac{\left( 1+\lambda _{i}^{*}\beta _{i}-\frac{\lambda _{c}^{*}}{mc}\right) ^{t}-1}{\lambda _{i}^{*}\beta _{i}-\frac{\lambda _{c}^{*}}{mc}}\right) \right] , \end{aligned}$$

where \(\beta ^{Bet}=\lambda _{i}^{*}\beta _{i}+(1-\lambda _{i}^{*})\beta _{c}.\) Substituting the value of \(\lambda _{i}^{*},\) we get

$$\begin{aligned} \beta ^{Bet}=\frac{\frac{\beta _{i}}{mc}+\alpha _{0}\beta _{c}\beta _{i}}{\frac{1}{mc}+(1-\alpha _{0})\beta _{i}+\alpha _{0}\beta _{c}}+\frac{(1-\alpha _{0})\beta _{i}\beta _{c}}{\frac{1}{mc}+(1-\alpha _{0})\beta _{i}+\alpha _{0}\beta _{c}}=\frac{\frac{\beta _{i}}{mc}+\beta _{c}\beta _{i}}{\frac{1}{mc}+(1-\alpha _{0})\beta _{i}+\alpha _{0}\beta _{c}} \end{aligned}$$

and

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda _{i}^{*}\beta _{i}-\frac{\lambda _{c}^{*}}{mc}=\frac{\frac{\beta _{i}}{mc}+\alpha _{0}\beta _{c}\beta _{i}}{\frac{1}{mc}+(1-\alpha _{0})\beta _{i}+\alpha _{0}\beta _{c}}-\frac{\frac{(1-\alpha _{0})\beta _{i}}{mc}}{\frac{1}{mc}+(1-\alpha _{0})\beta _{i}+\alpha _{0}\beta _{c}}=\frac{\frac{\alpha _{0}\beta _{i}}{mc}+\alpha _{0}\beta _{c}\beta _{i}}{\frac{1}{mc}+(1-\alpha _{0})\beta _{i}+\alpha _{0}\beta _{c}}. \end{aligned}$$

Therefore, we get

$$\begin{aligned} Y_{t}^{Bet}=Y_{0}\left( 1+\lambda _{i}^{*}\beta _{i}-\frac{\lambda _{c}^{*}}{mc}\right) ^{t}, \end{aligned}$$

where \(\lambda _{c}^{*}=1-\lambda _{i}^{*}\ \)is the allocation of investment goods towards production of the consumer goods analogous to the critical value \(\lambda _{i}^{*}.\) Now, both numerator and denominator of \(\lambda _{i}^{*}\beta _{i}-\frac{\lambda _{c}^{*}}{mc}\) are greater than that of \(\widehat{\lambda }_{i}\beta _{i}\) but numerator is greater by a smaller amount, and hence \(\lambda _{i}^{*}\beta _{i}-\frac{\lambda _{c}^{*}}{mc}<\widehat{\lambda }_{i}\beta _{i}.\) This implies that at their respective critical values, \(Y_{t}^{MM}>Y_{t}^{Bet}\) \(\forall t \) and \(\forall mc.\)

4.C Solving Haldane’s Model: In Eq. (4.42), suppose \(bxt=y\)

$$\begin{aligned} ae^{-y}= & {} a-y[a-(a-b)x] \\ e^{-y}= & {} 1-y\left[ 1-\left( \frac{a-b}{a}\right) x\right] \\ \left( \frac{a-b}{a}\right) x= & {} 1-\left( 1-e^{-y}\right) y^{-1} \\= & {} 1-\left( 1-\left[ 1-y+\frac{y^{2}}{2!}-\frac{y^{3}}{3!}+.....\right] \right) y^{-1} \\= & {} 1-\left( y-\frac{y^{2}}{2!}+\frac{y^{3}}{3!}-\frac{y^{4}}{4!}+.....\right) y^{-1} \\= & {} 1-\left( 1-\frac{y}{2!}+\frac{y^{2}}{3!}-\frac{y^{3}}{4!}+....\right) \\= & {} \frac{y}{2!}-\frac{y^{2}}{3!}+\frac{y^{3}}{4!}-\frac{y^{4}}{5!}+.... \end{aligned}$$

Suppose \(\frac{2(a-b)}{a}x=z\). We get Eq. (4.43).

$$\begin{aligned} z=2\left( \frac{y}{2!}-\frac{y^{2}}{3!}+\frac{y^{3}}{4!}-\frac{y^{4}}{5!}+....\right) . \end{aligned}$$

Now, to invert the series so that we can represent y in terms of z such as in Eq. (4.44), we can follow the following procedure:

Re-write (4.43) as

$$\begin{aligned} z=a_{1}y+a_{2}y^{2}+a_{3}y^{3}+..... \end{aligned}$$
(4.47)

Let the following be the corresponding inverted series:

$$\begin{aligned} y=A_{1}z+A_{2}z^{2}+A_{3}z^{3}+..... \end{aligned}$$
(4.48)

Substituting (4.48) in (4.47),

$$\begin{aligned} z= & {} a_{1}(A_{1}z+A_{2}z^{2}+A_{3}z^{3}+.....)+a_{2}(A_{1}z+A_{2}z^{2}+A_{3}z^{3}+.....)^{2} \\&+a_{3}(A_{1}z+A_{2}z^{2}+A_{3}z^{3}+.....)^{3}+.... \\ z= & {} (a_{1}A_{1})z+(a_{1}A_{2}+a_{2}A_{1}^{2})z^{2}+(a_{1}A_{3}+a_{3}A_{1}^{3}+2a_{2}A_{1}A_{2})z^{3}+....... \end{aligned}$$

Comparing parameters on both sides of the equation, we get

$$\begin{aligned} a_{1}A_{1}= & {} 1\Rightarrow A_{1}=\frac{1}{a_{1}} \\ a_{1}A_{2}+a_{2}A_{1}^{2}= & {} 0\Rightarrow A_{2}=-\frac{a_{2}}{a_{1}^{3}} \\ a_{1}A_{3}+a_{3}A_{1}^{3}+2a_{2}A_{1}A_{2}= & {} 0\Rightarrow A_{3}=\frac{2a_{2}^{2}-a_{1}a_{3}}{a_{1}^{5}} \end{aligned}$$

and so on.

From (4.43), \(a_{1}=1,\) \(a_{2}=-\frac{1}{3},\) \(a_{3}=\frac{1}{12} \) and so on.

Substituting these values in the above-derived equations of \(A_{1},A_{2},A_{3},....\), we get

$$\begin{aligned} A_{1}=1,A_{2}=\frac{1}{3},A_{3}=\frac{5}{36},\text { and so on} \end{aligned}$$

Substituting these values back in Eq. (4.48), we get the inverted series in Eq. (4.44):

$$\begin{aligned} y=z+\frac{1}{3}z^{2}+\frac{5}{36}z^{3}+..... \end{aligned}$$

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2022 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Ghate, C., Gopalakrishnan, P., Grover, S. (2022). Critiques of the Two-Sector Mahalanobis Model. In: The Mahalanobis Growth Model. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-16-8980-2_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics