Skip to main content

Introducing Severance Payment Systems in Japan: A Proposal for Vacancy Decontrol

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Severance Payment and Labor Mobility

Part of the book series: Economics, Law, and Institutions in Asia Pacific ((ELIAP))

  • 202 Accesses

Abstract

In Japan, the court requires job restoration rather than a severance payment from a firm after it decides that a dismissal has been abusive. This results in a high settlement cost for termination.

This chapter recommends a simultaneous adoption of two proposals for introducing severance payments to reduce settlement costs in Japan. The first applies to existing contracts and proposes to specify levels of severance payments that would replace the current job restoration requirement after the court determines that a case is abusive.

The second applies to new employees either for a recently vacated position or a new position and proposes vacancy decontrol, which allows firms to set the levels of severance payments freely. Within this category, this paper proposes government-assisted vacancy decontrol, a transitional measure, where the government sets a minimum level of statutory severance payment, which is equal to 6 months of wages for a worker who has worked for 20 years, following the Taiwan precedent. After the need for the transitional measure is dissolved, complete vacancy decontrol should be introduced, abolishing the statutory severance payment. We propose that even at this stage, the government should publicly set a default level of the severance payment, which a firm should observe unless an explicit agreement or contract stipulates otherwise. The government should immediately introduce some form of vacancy decontrol for senior workers who have already retired from a regular job.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 99.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 129.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    See Sect. 4 of Yashiro (2018).

  2. 2.

    In Japan, the so-called Shakuchi-shakka Law (Act on Land and Building Lease) played a similar role to the US rent controls, in that the owner could not refuse the renewal of a contract with a low rent. In 2000, a new Fixed Term Lease Law was legislated, and the tenant and owner can now choose which law applies. This yielded a form of vacancy decontrol.

  3. 3.

    In the US , “at-will” employment is constrained by statutory, public policy, and other exceptions. See National Conference of State Legislature (2008). For example, firing based on discrimination is deemed illegal. Within the bound, freedom of contract is honored. It is expected that a similar situation will prevail for the new contracts under the vacancy decontrol in Japan.

  4. 4.

    “In the United States, the ‘employment at will’ doctrine implies that either party can break the employment relationship with no liability, provided there was no express contract for a definite term governing the employment relationship and as long as the employer has not entered into a collective bargain.” (Cahuc et al. 2014, p. 882). This implies that when there is an “express contract,” the employer cannot break the employment contract . See Autor et al. (2006) for a precise description of the employment-at-will doctrine and its exceptions.

  5. 5.

    Bellinger (1989).

  6. 6.

    It is true that the workers in small firms can make use of the joint labor union system. But the cost in terms of both time and money in taking advantage of this union is substantial for their income. Workers in large firms can better withstand the litigation cost .

  7. 7.

    Hatta (1996; 2009 pp. 494–496). This was originally pointed out by Yoshida (1994, p. 162). See also Noguchi (2010, p. 114) and Jo (2006).

  8. 8.

    Consider a steady growth economy, where employment is steadily growing at the rate g. Assume for simplicity that the firm pays back the loan from the workers by a lump sum exit payment at the time of retirement. Hence, the workers get lower wage rate than under the merit-based wage system when they are in their twenties and thirties, then earn the merit-based wage until retirement , and finally receives the exit payment that redeem the loan they gave when they are young. If the firm pays the exit payment as the sum of the wage payment and interest payment at the rate of g, the revenue from the savings in wage and the expense in the exit payment will exactly match. The firm will gain if the implicit interest rate is less than g.

  9. 9.

    See the Appendix I for a more detailed discussion of the Ponzi scheme .

  10. 10.

    Nakamura (1998).

  11. 11.

    This implies that the longer the employment at a firm, the more advantageous it becomes in terms of exit payments , and that starting one’s career at a company immediately after graduating from high school or college is a strategy for maximizing any future exit payment .

  12. 12.

    In recent years, however, wage curve has started to slightly come down after age of 50. Also, the ratio of the exit payment to the lifetime wage income has been coming down. These phenomena seem to reflect erosion of the pre-conditions of the Ponzi scheme in recent years.

  13. 13.

    See Yashiro (2018, Sect. 5).

  14. 14.

    Moreover, in the IT age, information on employment can be disseminated far more easily than it used to be. After all, house- and car-sharing services have been working well in many countries, assisted by the availability of widespread reputation information through IT.

  15. 15.

    This proposal has been made by Ouchi (2013, pp.175–178).

  16. 16.

    As the system of lifetime employment seniority became mandatory in practice, a wide range of Japanese firms was obliged to develop firm-specific skills . As a result, lifetime employment became even more difficult to resolve.

  17. 17.

    See Sect. 5 of Yashiro (2018) and Ouchi (2018).

  18. 18.

    Public unemployment insurance could cause another moral hazard to the employer to dismiss excessively because the employer does not face the financial cost of the unemployment insurance benefit payment it entails. This moral hazard can be prevented by designing the unemployment insurance premium appropriately.

  19. 19.

    According Li (2018), Professor Huang (1991) pointed out that severance pay provided “…certain protection until they (dismissed workers) have found a new job.” This theory seems to accord with our claim that the severance payment under Taiwan’s Old Pension Scheme served as a substitute for unemployment insurance .

  20. 20.

    According to Li (2018), Professor Liu (1986a, b, c, d, e, f) justified the severance payment as a differed wage. A differed wage implies raising the wage as workers become older, at the cost of reducing wages when workers are young. This could be done without government intervention if both employers and employees agree with such an arrangement. For the government to force employers and employee to have this arrangement, there must be a reason. From the economics point of view, however, using a statutory severance payment as a substitute for the public pension may be justified.

  21. 21.

    See footnote 19.

  22. 22.

    See Chang (2018, Sects. 1, 2 and 3, Footnote 28, and Appendix 3).

  23. 23.

    The argument in defense of agreement-based statutory severance payment in the line of Posner (2003) is that if statutory severance payment is imposed externally for the purpose of job protection, wages would be lowered to compensate for the higher job security, and the wage decrease would be worth less to the workers than the employment security if they did not choose a positive level of the severance payment themselves. Thus, such an external imposition of statutory severance payment will harm workers.

  24. 24.

    See Hatta (2006), for example.

  25. 25.

    This is not the best solution as in this case, there is no reason to reform the economy.

  26. 26.

    Some argue that a statutory severance payment that makes dismissal difficult is useful for motivating workers to undertake firm-specific human capital investment . However, a firm could spontaneously choose to assure job security because that is also to the benefit of the firm.

  27. 27.

    Some scholars argue the system’s main merit of protecting worker investment in firm-specific skills outweighs its cost. However, each firm should be free to conclude private contracts reflecting the differing degrees of employment security . There is no reason to impose a very high termination cost by statute.

  28. 28.

    Ohtake and Tsuru (2016, p. 4). Generally, the amount of monetary compensation is smaller for nonregular workers, being 3.4 months plus 0.2 months for every year of service, or 5.4 months’ salary in the equivalent case. However, there could be bias in the estimated coefficient for years of service in that the monthly salary by itself becomes higher with longer years of service.

  29. 29.

    Kawata and Kawaguchi (2018, p. 261).

  30. 30.

    See Section III of the present Part.

  31. 31.

    However, the level of exit payment for workers who have resigned is only seven months of wages.

  32. 32.

    National Conference of State Legislature (2008).

  33. 33.

    Holzschu (2016).

  34. 34.

    Posner (2003).

  35. 35.

    Such pension plans are portable with defined contributions; therefore, they will not be affected by whether the person is dismissed or resigns spontaneously and serve as a third-tier pension system on top of the Employees’ Pension System, which is the second tier of the pension system in Japan.

  36. 36.

    Yamamoto (2018).

  37. 37.

    Fukui (2006) argues that the literature has excessively focused on the severance payment as a replacement for the existing JRR . We propose vacancy decontrol in the present Chapter to rectify this situation.

  38. 38.

    Cabinet Office (2017).

  39. 39.

    Research and Statistics Department in Bank of Japan (2004).

  40. 40.

    A difference between the two systems is that Taiwan’s labor pension is managed through Individual Retirement Accounts using a fully funded method (defined contribution base), while Japanese Employee’s Pension System is managed through a modified pay-as-you-go method.

References

  • Autor, D. H., Donohue, J. J., & Schwab, S. J. (2006). The costs of wrongful-discharge Laws. The Review of Economics and Statistics, MIT Press 88(2), 211–231. https://doi.org/10.1162/rest.88.2.211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bellinger, M. A. (1989). “Lifetime employment in the United States: Can it work?,” Perspectives on Business and Economics, Paper 3. http://preserve.lehigh.edu/perspectives-v07/3

  • Cabinet Office. [2017]. Systems of National Accounts, gross domestic product classified by economic activities (major industry group), at constant prices (at market prices in the calendar year 1990). Government of Japan. http://www5.cao.go.jp/j-j/wp/wp-je17/index_pdf.html

  • Cahuc, P., Carcillo, S., & Zylberberg, A. (2014). Labor economics (2nd ed.). Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chang, C.-H. (2018). Severance payment system in Taiwan: A historical perspective. In T. Hatta & S. Ouchi (Eds.), Severance payment and labor mobility: A comparative study of Taiwan and Japan. Singapore: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fukui, H. (2006). Dismissal regulation widened income gap (Japanese title:「解雇規制が助長する格差社会」). In Fukui and Ohtake (2006).

    Google Scholar 

  • Hatta, T. (1996). Remark. In Hatta, T. et. al. (Eds.), Investing in human services (Japanese title: 『福祉は投資である』). Nippon Hyoron Sha Publishers, Japan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hatta, T. (2006). The principle of efficiency improvement and principle of protecting the vested interests (Japanese title:「効率化原則と既得権保護原則」). In: Fukui and Ohtake (2006).

    Google Scholar 

  • Hatta, T. (2009). Microeconomics II. Japan: Toyo Keizai.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holzschu, M. (2016). Just cause vs. employment-at-will. https://www.businessknowhow.com/manage/justcausevsfreewill.htm. Accessed 2018-6-8.

  • Huang, Y.-C. (1991). Perspective on labor law 215. Institute for Labor Research, National Chengchi University.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hyde, A. (2003). Working in Silicon Valley: Economic and legal analysis of a high-velocity labor market. Armonk: M.E. Sharpe.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jo, S. (2006). Why Do the Youngs Resign their Job in 3 Years? (Japanese title:『若者はなぜ3年で辞めるのか?』). Kobunsha, Japan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kawata, K., & Kawaguchi, D. (2018). “Estimation for Monetary Compensation based on the Full Compensation Rule” (Section 7.). In S. Ouchi & D. Kawaguchi (Eds.), Reconsidering unfair dismissal in Japan: Design of monetary compensation system (pp. 253–283). Japan: Yuhikaku.

    Google Scholar 

  • Li, Y.-C. (2018). Law Review and Comparison of Dismissal Regulations. In T. Hatta & S. Ouchi (Eds.), Severance payment and labor mobility: A comparative study of Taiwan and Japan. Singapore: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu, C.-P. (1986a). On labor pension claims (1). Lawyer Newsletter, 79, 25–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu, C.-P. (1986b). On labor pension claims (2). Lawyer Newsletter, 80, 8–10.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu, C.-P. (1986c). On labor pension claims (3). Lawyer Newsletter, 81, 11–14.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu, C.-P. (1986d). On labor pension claims (4). Lawyer Newsletter, 82, 12–14.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu, C.-P. (1986e). On labor pension claims (5). Lawyer Newsletter, 83, 5–9.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liu, C.-P. (1986f). On labor pension claims (last). Lawyer Newsletter, 84, 5–8.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nakamura, T. (1998). A history of Showa Japan, 1926–1989 (E. Whenmouth, Trans.). Tokyo: University of Tokyo Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • National Conference of State Legislature. (2008). At-will employment – Overview. http://www.ncsl.org/research/labor-and-employment/at-will-employment-overview.aspx. accessed 2018-6-8.

  • Noguchi, Y. (2010). The year 1940 system (enlarged edition) (Japanese title: 『1940年体制』増補版). Toyo Keizai Inc., Japan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ohtake, F., & Tsuru, K. (2016, June 6). A statistical analysis on monetary compensations for dismissal (in Japanese). Paper presented to the study group of settling individual disputes in the Ministry of Health Labor and Welfare.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ouchi, S. (2013). Dismissal reform (Japanese title:『解雇改革』). Chuokeizai-Sha, Japan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ouchi, S. (2018). “Why should the monetary compensation system be introduced in Japanese dismissal regulation?” In: Hatta, Tatsuo and Ouchi, Shinya. (Eds.) [2018]. Severance payment and labor mobility: A comparative study of Taiwan and Japan. Springer, Singapore.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parsons, D. O., & Shuaizhang, F. (2006, July). Insuring displaced workers: Human capital losses and severance pay design (IZA Discussion Paper, No. 2238). IZA Institute of Labor Economics, Germany.

    Google Scholar 

  • Posner, R. A. (2003). Economic analysis of law. New York: Aspen Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Research and Statistics Department in Bank of Japan. (2004). Financial and economic statistics monthly, 14–1 Principal interest rates (1946–2004). www.stat.go.jp/data/chouki/zuhyou/14-01.xls

  • Shiu, H., & Chien, I. (2017). A brief introduction to employment termination and severance pay systems in Taiwan – A reference model for japan’s reform of labor mobility. In T. Hatta & S. Ouchi (Eds.), Severance payment and labor mobility: A comparative study of Taiwan and Japan. Singapore: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yamamoto, Y. (2018). “German Law.” (Section 4–2). In S. Ouchi & D. Kawaguchi (Eds.), Reconsidering unfair dismissal in Japan: Design of monetary compensation system (pp. 130–142). Tokyo: Yuhikaku.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yashiro, N. (2018). Dismissal compensation and labor mobility in Japan. In T. Hatta & S. Ouchi (Eds.), Severance payment and labor mobility: A comparative study of Taiwan and Japan. Singapore: Springer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yoshida, K. (1994). The guilt of Japanese style bank management (Japanese title: 『日本型銀行経営の罪』). Japan: Toyo Keizai Inc.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendices

1.1 Appendix I: Ponzi Scheme

1.1.1 The Expanding Economy

Consider an economy where people work for only two “years.” In each year, the young and the old generations work concurrently in this economy. In the following, the model year is simply the year, without quotation marks. The calendar year is as written. One year is approximately 20 calendar years in the real economy.

1.1.2 The Expanding Firm Model

Consider a growing firm in this economy, which satisfies the following assumptions.

  1. (1)

    This firm employs workers for their lifetime. Thus, the firm employs young workers and retains them in the next year.

  2. (2)

    Every year, this firm’s employment of young workers expands at a constant annual growth rate of g.

  3. (3)

    In the first year, the firm has 1 old worker.

In the first year, therefore, the firm employs 1 + g young workers, making total employment size 2 + g, as shown in Table 6.2. In the second year, the number of employees of both the older and young generations grow by a factor of 1 + g and the total number of the employees in this firm is (1 + g)(2 + g), also shown in Table 6.2.

Table 6.2 Labor force

Therefore, in year t, the employment size of the young is (1 + g)t and that of the old is (1 + g)t − 1. The total employment this year is (1 + g)t − 1(2 + g).

  1. (4)

    In this firm, the productivity of the young and the old are identical in any given year.

  2. (5)

    Productivity does not increase over time, and we assume that the productivity of all workers in any year is 1 throughout the period .

1.1.3 The Merit-Based Wage System

This firm can adopt a merit-based wage system , where the wage rate is equal to its productivity, which is 1. Hence, the total wage payment in each year is the total employment in that year multiplied by one. Table 6.3, which is identical to Table 6.2, shows the wage payments to the young and old generations each year. This table shows that the wage payment of this firm in year t is (1 + g)t − 1(2 + g).

Table 6.3 Merit-based wage payment

1.1.4 The Seniority-Based Wage System

Alternatively, the firm can adopt a seniority-based wage system . In this setting, young workers receive zero wage, receiving the wage payment 2 + r in their old age, where r is the market rate of interest. Note that the remuneration for their work in old age is equal to 1 while the present value then of their remuneration while young is 1 + r. Thus, they add to 2 + r, which they receive in their old age, as is shown in Table 6.4.

In the second year, the young generation again receives nothing. But the old generation receives remuneration for their work in the current year, which is 1 + g, plus the present value of their remuneration in the previous year, which is (1 + g)(1 + r). Thus, the combined wage of this generation in year 2 is (1 + g)(2 + r), as is shown in the second column of Table 6.4.

Likewise, the older generation in year t receives remuneration for that year, which is (1 + g)t − 1, and the present value of their work in the previous year, which is (1 + g)t − 1(1 − r). The total wage payment in year t is (1 + g)t − 1(2 + r). Table 6.3 provides the details .

1.1.5 The Ponzi Scheme

Thus, the wage payments in year t under the two systems are as follows.

  • Merit-based wage system : (1 + g)t − 1(2 + g)

  • Seniority-based wage system : (1 + g)t − 1(2 + r)

When g is greater than r, the total wage payment by this firm is smaller under the seniority-based wage payment than under the merit-based wage payment system. The employer clearly gains by adopting a seniority-based wage payment system. However, note that under either system, a given cohort receives exactly the same present value of wages. Thus, employers can gain by adopting a seniority-based wage payment scheme over a merit-based payment scheme without damaging the interests of workers.

This implies that the firm would still be better off than under the merit-based system, even if it paid the present value of the wage of the previous year evaluated at a higher discount factor than the rate of interest. If the firm made this choice, both employers and employees would gain through the seniority-based wage scheme.

1.1.6 Productivity Improvement

So far, we have assumed that the productivity does not increase, and the wage rate remains constant. Now assume that the employment growth rate g is 0 in the Expanding Firm Model , and that assumption (5) is replaced by the following.

  1. (6)

    Productivity increases at a constant rate α so that each new generation is equipped with new productivity, but each generation retains in old age the level of technology it acquired in its young age.

Replacing g in Table 6.3 with α provides the output levels of each generation employed by this firm and the total output for each year. By reinterpreting Tables 6.3 and 6.4 as representing the merit-based and seniority-based wage systems respectively, where productivity increases at a rate α, we again find that the firm can gain by employing the seniority-based wage scheme.

Table 6.4 Seniority-based wage payment

Furthermore, assume that the productivity increase given by α and the employment growth given by γ occur simultaneously, and we denote the sum of γ + α as g. Tables 6.3 and 6.4 then provide the combined wage payments in each case. If we expect both productivity and employment levels to grow at some constant rate, then g in Tables 6.3 and 6.4 is the growth rate of the total wage payments in the firm where we expect both the employment level and the wage rate to increase.

In this situation, the gap between g and r can be substantial. For instance, during the period 1956–73 in Japan, the average growth rate per calendar year of secondary industry was 12.1%, while the average interest rate per calendar year on savings was 2.3%. The average annual gap is then 9.8%. Assume that one year in this model is 20 calendar years (as between age 30 and 50). Hence the 12.1% growth rate in a calendar year will approximately equal 242% growth rate in a model year, yielding g = 2.42.Footnote 38 On the other hand, the 2.3% interest rate on savings for the calendar year will translate to 45.6% interest rate in the model year, yielding r = 0.46.Footnote 39 If firms discount the payment of premiums at a factor between g = 2.42 and r = 0.46, both employers and employees would significantly gain from this scheme. Thus, the firm is motivated to spontaneously adopt the combination of lifetime employment and a seniority-based wage system when it believes that g > r will prevail in the forecastable future.

Importantly, the seniority wage system is effectively a Ponzi scheme and the reason the firm can gain from this system. Under this system, the firm owes a debt to the young generation each year. Thus, the firm is indebted to the next generation each year. This means that the firm is eventually indebted to generations in the infinite future. The firm can then make a profit because it never has to return the debt to the generations in the infinite future. This profitability, however, relies on the presumption that g > r will continue.

However, the Ponzi scheme breaks down when the expectation of everlasting expansion is not actualized. That is exactly what has been happening in Japan over the past 20 years.

1.2 Appendix II: Non-firm-Specific Human Capital

If a person accumulates general (non-firm-specific) human capital and if the skills improve accordingly, his wage rate will increase in a competitive economy under the merit-based system, where the wage rate is equal to the productivity of each worker. Thus, just because the wage level increases as the worker ages, does not mean that the wage structure is determined under a seniority-based wage system , which is where the wage rate becomes higher than the productivity as the worker’s work duration becomes longer.

However, a worker who wishes to invest in such skills must accept very low wage levels when young. Given capital market imperfections, however, each worker may not be able to borrow from the bank to get by on a low wage during the investment period. Hence, it would benefit a worker if the firm makes an implicit contract with the worker to pay a wage rate higher than the productivity when young, in return for a commitment to remain in the firm. Therefore, in this case, the firm lends money and retrieves the return later, which is the opposite of the Ponzi scheme . Let us call this the case of investment in the general human capital with an educational loan (GEL).

Suppose that the GEL , not the Ponzi scheme , is the only reason for the commitment to long-term employment. Then the wage rate would be below productivity after the worker completes the acquisition of general skills. Hence, the wage structure under this scheme is not a seniority-based wage as defined earlier; the wage rate would be less than productivity after the worker completes the acquisition of general skills. To prevent workers from resigning before returning their debt, created during investment in human capital , there is an incentive for firms to have a written agreement that secures a certain period of employment under this scheme.

However, in practice, most firms in Japan already employ a lifetime employment system based on the Ponzi scheme , and GEL is only an additional cause for any long-term commitment. Under the Ponzi scheme, wages will increase, and there is a handsome exit payment for long-time workers. Therefore, there is no incentive for workers to quit for reason of GEL . Based on these grounds, there is no need for a written contract guaranteeing long-term employment. Alternatively, for the case of general human capital , workers will not forgo much by losing their job because their skills are marketable and firms wish to retain these workers as long as possible. However, this willingness weakens when there is a crisis, and the very existence of the business is threatened.

1.3 Appendix III: Employee’s Public Pension and Dismissal Premiums

In both Taiwan and Japan, an employee’s public pension does not contribute to the dismissal premium. In Taiwan , all employees are eligible for the “labor pension” benefit at age 60 years, regardless of their length of service and the lack of employment continuity under the New Pension Scheme established in 2005. Thus, the level of pension benefit after retirement is unaffected by whether there has been a change in employer during the employee’s career resulting from resignation or dismissal.

Just as Taiwan has a statutory portable labor pension , Japan has a statutory portable pension called the Employee’s Pension System. They are similar in the following two respects.

  1. 1.

    Pension rights are equal regardless of resignation or dismissal.

  2. 2.

    Payments are in the form of the annuity starting at a statutorily determined age, although Taiwan provides an option of a lump-sum payment in addition to the annuity.Footnote 40

Therefore, in both Taiwan and Japan , the employee pension does not contribute to the dismissal premium .

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Hatta, T. (2018). Introducing Severance Payment Systems in Japan: A Proposal for Vacancy Decontrol. In: Hatta, T., Ouchi, S. (eds) Severance Payment and Labor Mobility. Economics, Law, and Institutions in Asia Pacific. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-13-2149-8_6

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-13-2149-8_6

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-13-2148-1

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-13-2149-8

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics