Skip to main content

Involving the Private Sector and PPPs in Financing Public Investments: Some Opportunities and Challenges

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Fiscal Underpinnings for Sustainable Development in China

Abstract

Given the paucity of public resources, it is important to consider relying on the private sector for financing public investments and infrastructure. There are considerable expectations concerning Public–Private-Partnerships (PPPs) in supplementing public resources, but also risk sharing with the public sector. However, these contracts are subject to abuse, given asymmetric information, and game-play across levels of government that lead to the risks being borne by the central government or subsequent administrations. Specialized agencies can play a useful role in supporting subnational governments with the complex contracting arrangements needed for PPPs. We see that strengthened Public Financial Management is needed, to track the build-up of liabilities at the subnational level, and also own-source revenues to ensure accountability. Uncertainty, including with climate change, may require different arrangements—and the options are addressed in a subsequent paper Ahmad, Vinella and Xiao (2017), but the risk-sharing aspects of PPPs may be relevant in many cases.

An earlier version of this paper was prepared at the request of the G24 group of countries (Ahmad et al. 2015) and this paper has been prepared with the permission of the G24.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Gatti (2014) reports that, according to a study conducted by Moody’s in 2010, infrastructure projects in the construction phase tend to default earlier, to recover more slowly, and to emerge later from bankruptcy, as compared to infrastructure projects in the operation phase.

  2. 2.

    See http://ppi.worldbank.org/index.aspx.

  3. 3.

    Infrastructure Policy Unit 2012 Global PPI Data Update at http://ppi.worldbank.org/features/August-2013/PPI%202012%20Globa%20Update%20Note%20Final.pdf.

  4. 4.

    For detailed report, see (World Bank Infrastructure Policy Unit 2012) Global PPI Data Update.

  5. 5.

    Financial closure in the PPI Project Database varies among types of private participation. For greenfield projects and concessions, financial closure is defined as the existence of a legally binding commitment of equity holders or debt financiers to provide or mobilize funding for the project. The funding must account for a significant part of the project cost, securing the construction of the facility. For management and lease contracts, a contract authorizing the commencement of management or lease service must exist. For divestitures, the equity holders must have a legally binding commitment to acquire the assets of the facility. The Database includes only projects that have reached financial closure. Source: http://ppi.worldbank.org/resources/ppi_faq.aspx.

  6. 6.

    See sector report: http://ppi.worldbank.org/features/December-2013/Energy-Note-2013.pdf.

  7. 7.

    See http://ppi.worldbank.org/features/December-2013/Telecom-Note-2013.pdf.

  8. 8.

    See: http://ppi.worldbank.org/features/December-2013/Transport-Note-2013.pdf.

  9. 9.

    See: http://ppi.worldbank.org/features/December-2013/Water-Note-2013.pdf.

  10. 10.

    See: http://ppi.worldbank.org/features/December-2013/2012-EAP-Regional-Note-Final.pdf.

  11. 11.

    See: http://ppi.worldbank.org/features/December-2013/2012-ECA-Regional-Note-Final.pdf.

  12. 12.

    See http://ppi.worldbank.org/features/December-2013/2012-LAC-Regional-Note-Final.pdf.

  13. 13.

    See http://ppi.worldbank.org/features/December-2013/2012-MNA-Regional-Note-Final.pdf.

  14. 14.

    See http://ppi.worldbank.org/features/December-2013/2012-MNA-Regional-Note-Final.pdf.

  15. 15.

    See http://ppi.worldbank.org/features/December-2013/2012-SAR-Regional-Note-Final.pdf.

  16. 16.

    Please consult regional report: http://ppi.worldbank.org/features/December-2013/2012-AFR-Regional-Note-Final.pdf.

  17. 17.

    Municipalities, however, are subjected to strict control by provinces, but there are no national standards, which make it difficult to report to the GFS Yearbook on general government operations.

  18. 18.

    A rich discussion on this subject is proposed in Iossa and Antellini Russo (2008), who refer widely to the Italian PPP experience.

  19. 19.

    We should, however, mention that, in some countries such as the UK, highway contractors receive payments directly from the budgets, or like shadow tolls from the government.

  20. 20.

    A broad overview of the financial perspectives for the European energy infrastructure is found in Tagliapietra (2013).

  21. 21.

    Translation from Italian by the authors.

  22. 22.

    Private observation by the firm of the operating costs is, perhaps, the most common root of adverse selection issues in delegation problems. However, this is not a feature of all types of projects. A word of caution is, thus, needed. For instance, according to Engel, Fischer and Galetovic (1997, 2001), private information on costs is not an issue in highways franchise contracts. The authors argue that, once the infrastructure is built, the costs of operating and maintaining highways are known to be close to zero and, hence, there is little room for firms to cheat. This is instructive. It means that, although some problems are very widespread and can thus be legitimately accounted for in a general discussion, a more appropriate approach to PPP issues should pay attention to the different characteristics that the various sectors and activities display. This leads us to the sectoral analysis developed in this paper.

  23. 23.

    To be more precise, effort provision by the firm is desirable as long as the expected additional benefit that it induces, as compared to a situation in which no effort is exerted, exceeds the cost that providing effort entails for the firm. When effort has a probabilistic impact, the possibility of an additional benefit follows from the fact that the operating conditions are more likely to become favourable.

  24. 24.

    For a general presentation of ex-ante contracting with adverse selection, see Laffont and Martimort (2001). With specific regards to PPP projects, see Danau and Vinella (2014).

  25. 25.

    Risk neutrality of the firm is not an irrelevant aspect. When the firm is risk averse, it is necessary to insure it against the possibility of facing unfavourable operating conditions and, hence, a low return from the activity. In that case, a trade-off arises between provision of incentives and provision of insurance. The power of incentives that the government can provide to the firm is weakened. Note, however, that not only the attitude to risk of the firm but also that of the government is relevant. With ex-ante contracting, a risk-averse government may want to rely on a sell-out contract, under which the firm makes a payment up-front in order to have the right to produce. Thus, the government obtains a fixed payoff, regardless of the state of nature. This insurance may be interesting for small local governments, for which the project represents a significant share of the budget. Outside investors may be better diversified and, hence, they may be prone to insure small governments that privatize crucial infrastructures and services for insurance reasons (see Martimort 2006).

  26. 26.

    In this case, the contract is bound to be efficient ex post.

  27. 27.

    For examples in Latin America and the Caribbean regions, see Guasch (2004) and Guasch et al. (2006), (2008).

  28. 28.

    Allain-Dupré (2011) reports that, in OECD countries, sub-national governments are in charge of nearly half of total capital expenditures. The reason is that regions and municipalities are considered to “better spend,” i.e., to identify the most appropriate paths for promoting the territorial development and competitiveness (Charbit 2011). It is thus clear that sub-national governments play a core role in public investment. Although the general strategies are designed at the national level, the implementation and completion of investment projects and the subsequent management of the activity depend crucially on the regional and local levels. For instance, even in federal countries like Germany, local governments provide utilities and manage local infrastructure, and have a claim to state funding, up to a level that is sufficient for a correct functioning (Fink and Stratmann 2011).

  29. 29.

    For further examples, see, for instance, the Reference Guide on PPPs published by the World Bank in 2012.

  30. 30.

    See IASB (2011), IPSAS 32. This standard is also likely to affect the guidelines of Eurostat that are not so tightly defined.

  31. 31.

    In Italy, under the 2002 Stability Law, ISpa was created with the task of involving the private sector in the construction and management of important infrastructures, requiring significant long-run investments. However, being an off-budget agency, ISpa serves an important budgetary purpose as well. It can issue state-guaranteed bonds to raise capital for the new infrastructure projects, while allowing the government to comply with the European Stability and Growth Pact. See, for instance, Maskin and Tirole (2008) on the practice, often adopted by governments, to push debt finance off their own books to quasi-public agencies not consolidated in the national budgets.

References

  • Ahmad, E. (2014). Public finance underpinnings for infrastructure financing in developing countries. Paper for the G24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ahmad, E. (2017). Political economy of tax reforms for the SDGs. Paper for the G24.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ahmad, E., & Wang, Z. (2013). China: Emerging issues in public finance, Asian Development Bank (processed).

    Google Scholar 

  • Allain-DuprĂ©, D. (2011). Multi-level governance of public investment: Lessons from the crisis. OECD Regional Development (Working Papers, 2011/05). OECD Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ambrosanio, M., & Bordignon, M. (2006). Positive and normative thoeries of revenue assignments federations. In E. Ahmad and G. Brosio (2006), Handbook of Fiscal Federalism. Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Armstrong, M., & Sappington, D. (2006). Regulation, competition and liberalization. Journal of Economic Literature, 44, 325–366.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asian Development Bank. (2008). Public–Private partnership handbook.

    Google Scholar 

  • Asian Development Bank. (2013). New directions for Public–Private partnerships in People’s Republic of China.

    Google Scholar 

  • Banerjee, S. G., Oetzel, J. M., & Ranganathan, R. (2006). Private provision of infrastructure in emerging markets: Do institutions matter? Development Policy Review, 24(2), 175–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergantino, A. S., Billette de Villemeur, E., & Vinella, A. (2011). Partial regulation in vertically differentiated industries. Journal of Public Economic Theory, 13(2), 255–287.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhattacharya, A., Romani, M., & Stern, N. (2012). Infrastructure for development: Meeting the challenge, Policy Paper, June 2012.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brench, A., Beckers, T., Heinrich, M., & von Hirschhausen, C. (2005). Public-Private partnerships in New EU member countries of Central and Eastern Europe, European Investment Bank, 10(2).

    Google Scholar 

  • Charbit, C. (2011). Governance of public policies in decentralized contexts: The multi-level approach, OECD Regional Development (Working Papers, 2011/04). OECD Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Danau, D., & Vinella, A. (2014). Public-private contracting under limited commitment. Journal of Public Economic Theory, forthcoming.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dasgupta, P., Hammond, P., & Maskin, E. (1979). The implementation of social choice rules: Some general results on incentive compatibility. Review of Economic Studies, 46, 185–216.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ehrhardt, E. & Irwin, T. (2004). Avoiding customer and taxpayer bailouts in private infrastructure projects: Policy toward leverage, risk allocation, and bankruptcy, World Bank Policy Research (Working Paper 3274).

    Google Scholar 

  • Estache, A., & Wren-Lewis, L. (2008). Toward a theory of regulation for developing countries: Following Jean-Jacques Laffont’s lead. Journal of Economic Literature, 47(3), 729–770.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • European Commission. (2011). A growth package for integrated European infrastructures, COM(2011)676.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Commission. (2006). EC White Paper European Commission (2004), Resource Book on PPP Case Studies, Directorate General Regional Policy.

    Google Scholar 

  • European Investment Bank. (2004). The EIB’s role in Public-Private Partnerships (PPPs).

    Google Scholar 

  • Fink, A., & Stratmann, T. (2011). Institutionalized bailouts and fiscal policy: Consequences of soft budget constraints. KYKLOS, 64(3), 366–395.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gagnepain, P., Ivaldi, M., & Martimort, D. (2013). The cost of contract renegotiation: Evidence from the local public sector, American Economic Review, 103(6): 2352–2383.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gatti, S. (2014). Private finance for infrastructure investments. Analysis and implications for a future Multilateral Development Bank, Report prepared for the GGGI and the G24 engagement with the BRICS.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibbard, A. (1973). Manipulation of voting schemes: A general result. Econometrica, 41(4), 587–601.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, J., & Laffont, J. J. (1977). On the revelation of preferences for public goods. Journal of Public Economics, 8(1), 79–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Grout, P. (1997). The economics of the private finance initiative. Oxford Review of Economic Policy, 13, 53–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guasch, J. L. (2004). Granting and renegotiating infrastructure concessions: Doing it right, WBI development studies, the World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Guasch, J. L., Laffont, J. J., & Straub, S. (2006). Renegotiation of concession contracts: A theoretical approach. Review of Industrial Organization, 29, 55–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guasch, J. L., Laffont, J. J., & Straub, S. (2008). Renegotiation of concession contracts in Latin America, evidence from the water and transport sectors. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 26(2), 421–442.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • House of Lords. (2010). Private finance projects and off-balance sheet debt, First Report of Session 2009–10, Volume I: Report, HL Paper 63-I.

    Google Scholar 

  • House of Lords. (2010). Private Finance Projects and off-balance sheet debt, First Report of Session 2009–10, Volume II: Evidence, HL Paper 63-II.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iossa, E., & Antellini Russo, F. (2008). PotenzialitĂ  e criticitĂ  del Partenariato Pubblico Privato in Italia. Rivista di Politica Economica, 98(3), 125–158.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iossa, E., & Martimort, D. (2009). The theory of incentives applied to the transport sector. In A. de Palma, R. Lindsey, E. Quinet, & R. Vickerman (Eds.), A handbook of transport economics. Edward Elgar Publishing.

    Google Scholar 

  • Iossa, E., & Martimort, D. (2008). The simple microeconomics of public-private partnerships. CEIS Research Paper Series, 6(12), number 139.

    Google Scholar 

  • IMF. Government finance statistics manual. (2001). http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/gfs/manual/index.htm. (revised in 2014).

  • Irwin, T. (2007). Government guarantees. Allocating and valuing risk in privately financed infrastructure projects. The World Bank.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laffont, J. J., & Martimort, D. (2001). The theory of incentives: The principal-agent model. Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martimort, D. (2006). An agency perspective on the costs and benefits of privatization. Journal of Regulatory Economics, 30, 5–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Martimort, D., & Straub, S. (2008). Infrastructure privatization and changes in corruption patterns: The roots of public discontent. Journal of Development Economics, 90, 69–84.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maskin, E., & Tirole, J. (2008). Public–private partnerships and government spending limits. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 26, 412–420.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, R. B. (1979). Incentive compatibility and the bargaining problem. Econometrica, 47(1), 61–73.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • National Audit Office, The failure of Metronet, HC 512, 2008.09.

    Google Scholar 

  • National Audit Report. (2011). Audit Findings on China’s Local Government Debts, http://www.cnao.gov.cn/main/articleshow_ArtID_1154.htm.

  • National Audit Office. (2013). Audit Results of Governmental Debt of 36 Local Governments, http://www.cnao.gov.cn/main/articleshow_ArtID_1323.htm.

  • OECD. (2012). From lessons to principles for the use of Public-Private Partnerships, public governance and territorial development public management committee.

    Google Scholar 

  • Saussier, S. (2006). Public-Private Partnerships and prices: Evidence from water distribution in France, Review of Industrial Organization, 29, Special Issue.

    Google Scholar 

  • Schwartz, J. Z., Ruiz-Nunez, F., & Chelsky, J. (2014). Closing the infrastructure finance gap: Addressing risk. The World Bank Group.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tagliapietra, S. (2013). Financing the European energy infrastructure of the future, Review of environment, energy and economics, Oct. 03, 2013—Energy.

    Google Scholar 

  • The World Bank. (2012). Public–Private Partnerships. Reference Guide, Version 1.0.

    Google Scholar 

  • World Bank Infrastructure Policy Unit 2012 Global PPI Data Update.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Ehtisham Ahmad .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer Nature Singapore Pte Ltd.

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Ahmad, E., Bhattacharya, A., Vinella, A., Xiao, K. (2018). Involving the Private Sector and PPPs in Financing Public Investments: Some Opportunities and Challenges. In: Ahmad, E., Niu, M., Xiao, K. (eds) Fiscal Underpinnings for Sustainable Development in China. Springer, Singapore. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-6286-5_6

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-981-10-6286-5_6

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Singapore

  • Print ISBN: 978-981-10-6285-8

  • Online ISBN: 978-981-10-6286-5

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics