Skip to main content

It Takes Two to Tango. Patents and Markets in the Periphery and the Centre. Prebisch Dancing with Hilty

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Kreation Innovation Märkte - Creation Innovation Markets

Abstract

Since 1995, the TRIPs Agreement has provided an international framework for domestic patent law. Reto Hilty and the Max Planck Institute for Innovation and Competition have led an effort among patent scholars to map patent ‘flexibilities’ included in the TRIPs Agreement. These flexibilities allow developing countries to adapt their national patent law to their developmental needs.

Said legal scholars have argued in favour of regulatory sovereignty and room for manoeuvre under TRIPs but they have seldom stated for what purpose this policy space should be preserved. In this contribution, we draw on the work of Raul Prebisch to explore one possible, productive way of using the flexibility of the TRIPs Agreement.

Prebisch was a twentieth century Argentinian structuralist economist and a leading specialist of economic development in Latin America. Over the past 15 years, Prebisch’s work has received renewed attention. Prebisch’s structural analysis deviates from the dominant schools of neoclassical economics, institutional economic analysis in legal scholarship and free trade ideology in international economic law. Nevertheless, Prebisch's writings remain relevant to patent theory.

We derive a patent policy from Prebisch’s economic writings and subsequently argue that Prebisch’s patent vision can be implemented under today’s TRIPs Agreement as interpreted by Reto Hilty.

The authors research the socio-political context of IP legislation in Argentina to pay tribute to the multifaceted and international scholarship of Reto Hilty and his recent interest in Latin America, particularly in Argentina. As neither of the authors masters the Spanish language, they had to resort to available English sources. Many thanks to Latin American colleagues, amongst whom Prof. Guillermo Vidaurreta and Pedro Henrique Batista, for their valuable information. Any mistakes or misinterpretations, remain the authors’.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 189.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 249.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Yglesias (2012).

  2. 2.

    Spruk (2019), p. 5. Also see the references cited there.

  3. 3.

    Lewis (1992); Edwards et al. (2009).

  4. 4.

    Dosman (2008).

  5. 5.

    Lin (2012), p. 5; Simon (2019), pp. 339–345.

  6. 6.

    Also named after the German-British UN-employed development economist Hans Singer, who came to similar conclusions independently from Prebisch.

  7. 7.

    Harvey et al. (2010); Arezki et al. (2014).

  8. 8.

    In the 1930s, Prebisch had served as the Director-General of the Argentinian Central Bank under the conservative military government of General Uriburu. In 1943, he was forced to leave his position by a new military government, linked to Juan Peron. Prebisch became a fierce criticus of the populist President Peron but did not object to working with the military government that succeeded him, writing the Prebisch Plan for economic development in 1955. All in all, Prebisch was seen as a conservative voice on the Argentinian domestic political scene. See Dosman (2008).

  9. 9.

    Sikkink (1988).

  10. 10.

    Prebisch (1976); Prebisch (1981); Prebisch (1984).

  11. 11.

    Lin (2012).

  12. 12.

    Dosman (2008).

  13. 13.

    E.g., Margulis (2017).

  14. 14.

    E.g., Fajardo (2022).

  15. 15.

    Annex 1C of the Marrakesh Agreement Establishing the World Trade Organization, signed in Marrakesh, Morocco on 15 April 1994. Hilty also took an interest in bilateral and regional free trade agreements (FTAs) with IP provisions, see Grosse Ruse-Khan et al. (2013).

  16. 16.

    Lamping et al. (2014).

  17. 17.

    Ibid. See also Hilty (2015); Hilty (2011b).

  18. 18.

    The First Industrial Revolution had started in England from the 1780s onwards but the rate of innovation slowed down towards the 1820s to 1840s. The First Industrial Revolution was powered by coal and steam engines and made strides in industries ranging from iron to textiles. See Hobsbawm (1996).

  19. 19.

    Mokyr (1999).

  20. 20.

    See Abbenhuis and Morrell (2019). Since the end of the Cold War, we are in the middle of the ‘Second Globalisation’.

  21. 21.

    Pinilla and Rayes (2019).

  22. 22.

    Pinilla and Rayes (2019); Spruk (2019), p. 2.

  23. 23.

    Spruk (2019), p. 2. Argentina’s exports represented around 0.8% of the world trade during the early 1850s and reached levels of almost 4% in the 1920s. See Fig. 1 Pinilla and Rayes (2019), p. 445. According to economic scholars, only Canada and Japan increased their share at a faster rate than Argentina.

  24. 24.

    Cardenas (2003) as discussed in Pinilla and Rayes (2019), p. 445.

  25. 25.

    Pinilla and Rayes (2019), pp. 448–449, 459. For more on ‘import substitution’, see Sect. 3.

  26. 26.

    This paragraph is based on Spruk (2019) and the sources cited there; see also Lewis (1992); Edwards et al. (2009).

  27. 27.

    For the term ‘corporatism’, see Schmitter (1974).

  28. 28.

    On import substitution, see further, Sect. 3.1.

  29. 29.

    Ley N° 111 de 11 de octubre de 1864 sobre las Patentes de Invención. The present contribution is based on the English translation: Law No. 111 of October 11, 1864 on Patents (available at https://wipolex-res.wipo.int. Accessed March 9, 2023). Two partial patent acts were enacted in Argentina before the APA 1864 (For details, see Vidaurreta (2007), p. 91). The patent act of 1864 was in force until the Patent Act No. 24.481 which was adopted in 1995: Ley N° 24.481 de 20 de septiembre de 1995, de Patentes de Invención y Modelos de Utilidad; Law No. 24.481 of September 20, 1995 on Patents for Inventions and Utility Models.

  30. 30.

    Spruk (2019), p. 2.

  31. 31.

    For some comparative notes, see, Ladas (1930), pp. 23–24. Also see Dreyfuss and Pila (2018), pp. 3–22; Kurz (2000).

  32. 32.

    See https://www.constituteproject.org/constitution/Argentina_1994?lang=en#s41. Accessed May 2, 2023.

  33. 33.

    Paris Convention for the Protection of Industrial Property (open for signature March 20, 1883, entered into force July 7, 1884, last amended September 28, 1979) 828 UNTS 305 (hereafter Paris Convention).

  34. 34.

    Vidaurreta (2007), p. 153.

  35. 35.

    The APA 1864 shows quite some resemblance with the French Patent Act of 1791. A detailed, comparative analysis of both acts will not be reported upon here.

  36. 36.

    Also see article 3 and article 46 in fine APA 1864 in this regard.

  37. 37.

    See Simon (2019), pp. 339–345. We wrote the paragraphs on Prebisch’s theory mainly on the basis of the following primary sources, in the order of importance: Prebisch (1962); Prebisch (1959); Prebisch (1964); Prebisch (1954); Prebisch (1976).

  38. 38.

    See Sect. 1.

  39. 39.

    For ‘growth with redistribution’, see Chenery et al. (1979).

  40. 40.

    Cf. Lewis (1954).

  41. 41.

    Pioneered by David Ricardo. See Ricardo (1817).

  42. 42.

    Lin and Chang (2009).

  43. 43.

    Pinilla and Rayes (2019); Bulmer-Thomas (2003), pp. 46–81. Also see Sect. 2.

  44. 44.

    Bulmer-Thomas (2003), pp. 82–116.

  45. 45.

    The contemporary school of New Structural Economics tends to look more favourable upon arguments based on comparative advantage than Prebisch did. See Lin (2012).

  46. 46.

    Prebisch (1962).

  47. 47.

    Cf. ‘Middle Income Trap’, see Gill and Kharas (2015).

  48. 48.

    Prebisch (1962).

  49. 49.

    Prebisch (1954); Dosman (2008), pp. 327–328.

  50. 50.

    Prebisch (1962), p. 18.

  51. 51.

    For both points, see Waterbury (1999).

  52. 52.

    Dosman (2008), pp. 327–328, 453.

  53. 53.

    Baer (1972).

  54. 54.

    Love (1980).

  55. 55.

    Amin (1974); Frank (1970).

  56. 56.

    See, e.g., Prebisch (1959).

  57. 57.

    Sherwood (1998), p. 79; Gruben (1992), p. 20.

  58. 58.

    Prebisch (1959), p. 252.

  59. 59.

    Prebisch (1962), p. 16.

  60. 60.

    Ho (2012), p. 889.

  61. 61.

    Ho (2012), p. 889.

  62. 62.

    UNCTAD (1975).

  63. 63.

    Bulmer-Thomas (2003), pp. 46–81.

  64. 64.

    Similar to ‘European patents’ under the European Patent Convention 1973.

  65. 65.

    Similar to ‘European patents with unitary effect’ (Unified patents). See Desaunettes-Barbero et al. (2023); Plomer (2015).

  66. 66.

    Our terminology.

  67. 67.

    Although Argentina wanted to join the Convention as early as 1966. See Law No. 17.011 of November 10, 1966, on Approval of the Paris Convention for the Protection of Industrial Property.

  68. 68.

    Dreyfuss and Pila (2018), pp. 432–441.

  69. 69.

    From 1930 to 1935, Prebisch was first Under-Secretary of Finance and Agriculture and later adviser to the Ministers of Finance and of Agriculture. In other words, he never worked for the Ministry of the Interior and, therefore, was never directly in charge of the Patent Office. See Simon (2019), p. 339.

  70. 70.

    Notably the arrangements for follow-on innovation (see Articles 27–32) and non-working (Article 47) which will not be further elaborated upon here.

  71. 71.

    Winham (2005), pp. 3–25.

  72. 72.

    Hilty (2017); Hilty and Slowinski (2014). For more on this legitimation theory, see Drahos (1996); Van Overwalle and van Zimmeren (2009). Also see Burk and Lemley (2009); Lemley (2015); Machlup (1959); Merges (2011).

  73. 73.

    Hilty developed the idea that patents are not a booster for innovation per se but an instrument of competition and innovation policy in many of his writings. The following paragraphs are based on Hilty (2017); Hilty (2012); Hilty (2011a); Hilty (2011b); Hilty and Slowinski (2014). In the same sense, Ullrich (2009), pp. 399, 442; Ullrich (2015), p. 333. Also see, Van Overwalle and Léonard (2024) Van Overwalle (2022).

  74. 74.

    Hilty has written extensively on the need for compulsory licenses to address dysfunctional behavior of IP owners, see Hilty (2017); Hilty (2015); Hilty (2012); Hilty, Liu (eds) (2015). Also, in his analyses of proprietary versus more open models, Hilty stressed the need for limitations, see Hilty (2012); Hilty (2011b); Hilty and Köklü (2013).

  75. 75.

    Hilty (2012), p. 5, with reference to Lehmann: “Competition restraints in order to boost Competition”.

  76. 76.

    Hilty (2011a, b).

  77. 77.

    Hilty never, as far as we are aware, admitted to any influence on his work by the school of NIE, but the influences are clear to us.

  78. 78.

    North (1991), p. 97.

  79. 79.

    North (1991), pp. 97–112; North (1990).

  80. 80.

    Faundez (2016).

  81. 81.

    Coase (1937); Coase (2000).

  82. 82.

    Hilty (2012).

  83. 83.

    See Gervais (2003).

  84. 84.

    Lamping et al. (2014).

  85. 85.

    Patent Declaration (2014), p. 1.

  86. 86.

    Patent Declaration (2014), p. 3.

  87. 87.

    Patent Declaration (2014), p. 3.

  88. 88.

    Patent Declaration (2014), p. 3.

  89. 89.

    Patent Declaration (2014), p. 4.

  90. 90.

    Patent Declaration (2014), p. 4.

  91. 91.

    Patent Declaration (2014), p. 8.

  92. 92.

    Patent Declaration (2014), p. 9.

  93. 93.

    Patent Declaration (2014), p. 10.

  94. 94.

    Patent Declaration (2014), p. 5.

  95. 95.

    Patent Declaration (2014), p. 7. On purpose-bound protection, see Lamping (2010).

  96. 96.

    Patent Declaration (2014), p. 7.

  97. 97.

    Patent Declaration (2014), p. 9.

  98. 98.

    See above.

  99. 99.

    Lin (2012).

References

  • Abbenhuis M, Morrell G (2019) The first age of industrial globalization: an international history 1815–1918. Bloomsbury Publishing, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Amin S (1974) Accumulation on a world scale. Monthly Review Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Arezki R, Hadri K, Loungani P, Rao Y (2014) Testing the Prebisch–Singer hypothesis since 1650: evidence from panel techniques that allow for multiple breaks. J Int Money Finance 42:208–223

    Google Scholar 

  • Baer W (1972) Import substitution and industrialization in Latin America: experiences and interpretations. Latin Am Res Rev 7:95–122

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bulmer-Thomas V (2003) The economic history of Latin America since independence. Cambridge University Press, S 46–81, Cambridge (UK)

    Google Scholar 

  • Burk DL, Lemley MA (2009) The patent crisis and how the courts can solve it. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago/London

    Google Scholar 

  • Cardenas E, Ocampo JA, Thorp R (2003) Introducción. In: Ocampo JA, Thorp R (Hrsg) Cárdenas E. La era de las exportaciones latinoamericanas. De fines del siglo XIX a principios del XX. Fondo de Cultura Económica, Mexico

    Google Scholar 

  • Chenery H, Ahluwalia MS, Duloy JH et al (1979) Redistribution with growth, policies to improve income distribution in developing countries in the context of economic growth. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase RH (1937) The nature of the firm. Economica 4:386–405

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase RH (2000) The problem of social cost. In: Gopalakrishnan C (Hrsg) Classic papers in natural resource economics. Palgrave Macmillan UK, London, S 87–137

    Google Scholar 

  • Declaration On Patent Protection. Regulatory Sovereignty Under TRIPS (2014) Lamping M, Hilty RM, Burk DL, Correa CM, Drahos P, Gopalakrishnan NS, Große Ruse-Khan H, Kur A, Van Overwalle G, Reichman J, Ullrich H. 45 IIC, 679–698. Also available at http://www.ip.mpg.de/en/pub/news/patentdeclaration.cfm. Accessed 27 Apr 2023

  • Desaunettes-Barbero L, de Visscher F, Strowel A, Cassiers V (2023) The unitary patent package & Unified Patent Court. Problems, possible improvements and alternatives. LediPublishing, Milano

    Google Scholar 

  • Dosman EJ (2008) The life and times of Raúl Prebisch, 1901–1986. McGill-Queen’s Press, Montreal

    Google Scholar 

  • Drahos (1996), A Philosophy of Intellectual Property, Dartmouth Publishing Group

    Google Scholar 

  • Dreyfuss R, Pila J (2018) The Oxford handbook of intellectual property law. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Edwards S, Esquivel G, Márquez G (2009) The decline of Latin American economies: growth, institutions, and crises. University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Fajardo M (2022) The world that Latin America created: the United Nations Economic Commission for Latin America in the development era. Harvard University Press, Cambridge (US)

    Google Scholar 

  • Faundez J (2016) Douglass North’s theory of institutions: lessons for law and development. Hague J Rule Law 8:373–419

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank AG (1970) Latin America and underdevelopment. New York University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Gervais D (2003) The TRIPs Agreement. Drafting history and analysis. Sweet & Maxwell, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Gill IS, Kharas H (2015) The middle-income trap turns ten. The World Bank, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Grosse Ruse-Khan H, Drexl J, Hilty RM et al (2013) Principles for intellectual property provisions in bilateral and regional agreements. IIC 44:878–883

    Google Scholar 

  • Gruben WC (1992) Trade Policy and Intellectual Property Protection: The North-South Dispute. Economic Review - Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas 19

    Google Scholar 

  • Harvey DI, Kellard NM, Madsen JB, Wohar ME (2010) The Prebisch-Singer hypothesis: four centuries of evidence. Rev Econ Stat 92:367–377

    Google Scholar 

  • Helfer LR (2004) Regime shifting: the TRIPs agreement and new dynamics of international intellectual property lawmaking. Yale J Int L 29:1–85

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilty RM (2011a) La Constitution économique européenne et la propriété intellectuelle. Revue Internationale de Droit Économique:481–510 (abbreviated as Hilty RM 2011a)

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilty RM (2011b) Open approaches. In: Kommunikation – Festschrift für Rolf H. Weber zum 60. Geburtstag. Stämpfli Verlag, Bern, S 83–108 (abbreviated as Hilty RM 2011b)

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilty RM (2012) Individual, multiple and collective ownership: what impact on competition? In: Rosén J (Hrsg) Individualism and collectiveness in intellectual property law, ATRIP intellectual property series. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, S 3–44

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilty RM (2015) Legal remedies against abuse, misuse and other forms of inappropriate conduct of IP right holders. In: Hilty RM, Liu KC (Hrsg) Compulsory licensing. Springer, Heidelberg, S 377–395

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilty RM (2017) Intellectual property and private ordering. In: Dreyfuss R, Pila J (Hrsg) The Oxford handbook of intellectual property law. Oxford University Press, Oxford, S 898–930

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilty RM & Köklü K (2013) Access and use: open vs. proprietary worlds. Max Planck Institute for Innovation and Competition Research Paper, No. 14-07, S 9

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilty R, Liu K-C (Hrsg) (2015) Compulsory licensing. Practical experiences and ways forward. Springer, Berlin/Heidelberg, S 458

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilty RM, Slowinski PR (2014) Patenting coffee – IP protection and its impact on innovation in the coffee-capsule market. In: Varieties of European economic law and regulation, Studies in European Economic Law and Regulation, 3. Springer, Berlin, S 489–503

    Google Scholar 

  • Hobsbawm E (1996) The age of revolution: 1789–1848. Vintage, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Ho PS (2012) Revisiting Prebisch and Singer: beyond the declining terms of trade thesis and on to technological capability development. Cambridge Journal of Economics 36:869–893. https://doi.org/10.1093/cje/bes011

  • Kurz P (2000) Weltgeschichte des Erfindungsschutzes. Erfinder und Patente im Spiegal der Zeiten. Carl Heymanns Verlag, Köln/Berlin/Bonn/München, S 641

    Google Scholar 

  • Ladas SP (1930) The international protection of industrial property. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Lamping M (2010) Monsanto case note—purpose-bound patent protection for genes. Eur J Risk Regul 1:445–450

    Google Scholar 

  • Lamping M, Hilty R M, Burk DL, Correa CM, Drahos P, Gopalakrishnan NS, Große Ruse-Khan H, Kur A, Van Overwalle G, Reichman J, Ullrich H (2014) Declaration on patent protection. Regulatory sovereignty under TRIPS, 45 IIC, 679–698. Also available at http://www.ip.mpg.de/en/pub/news/patentdeclaration.cfm. Accessed 27 Apr 2023

  • Lemley M (2015) Faith-based intellectual property. 62 UCLA Law Review, University of California, Los Angeles. School of Law, S 1328–1346

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis WA (1954) Economic development with unlimited supplies of labour. Manch Sch 22:139–191

    Google Scholar 

  • Lewis PH (1992) The crisis of Argentine capitalism, New edition. The University of North Carolina Press, Chapel Hill

    Google Scholar 

  • Lin JY (2012) New structural economics: a framework for rethinking development. World Bank, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Lin J, Chang H-J (2009) Should industrial policy in developing countries conform to comparative advantage or defy it? A debate between Justin Lin and Ha-Joon Chang. Dev Policy Rev 27:483–502

    Google Scholar 

  • Love JL (1980) Raúl Prebisch and the origins of the doctrine of unequal exchange. Latin Am Res Rev 15(45–72):63–64

    Google Scholar 

  • Machlup F (1959) Review of the patent system. Study for the United States Senate, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • Margulis ME (2017) The global political economy of Raúl Prebisch. Taylor & Francis, Abingdon

    Google Scholar 

  • Merges RP (2011) Justifying intellectual property. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Google Scholar 

  • Mokyr J (1999) The second industrial revolution, 1870–1914. In: Castronovo V (Hrsg) Storia dell’economia Mondiale. Laterza Publishing, Rome, S 219–245

    Google Scholar 

  • North DC (1990) Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • North DC (1991) Institutions. J Econ Perspect 5:97–112

    Google Scholar 

  • Pinilla V, Rayes A (2019) How Argentina became a super-exporter of agricultural and food products during the First Globalisation (1880–1929). Cliometrica, 443–469

    Google Scholar 

  • Plomer A (2015) A unitary patent for a (sis)united Europe: the long shadow of history. IIC 46:508–533

    Google Scholar 

  • Prebisch R (1954) International co-operation in a Latin American development policy. In: United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Prebisch R (1959) Commercial policy in the underdeveloped countries. 49 Am Econ Rev:251

    Google Scholar 

  • Prebisch R (1962) The economic development of Latin America and its principal problems. Economic Bulletin for Latin America

    Google Scholar 

  • Prebisch R (1964) Towards a new trade policy for development. In: United Nations Conference on Trade and Development. New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Prebisch R (1976) A critique of peripheral capitalism. Cepal Review

    Google Scholar 

  • Prebisch R (1981) Capitalismo periferico: crisis y transformacion. Fondo de Cultura Economica, Mexico City

    Google Scholar 

  • Prebisch R (1984) Five stages in my thinking on development. In: Meier GM, Seers D (Hrsg) Pioneers in development. Oxford University Press, Oxford, S 175–191

    Google Scholar 

  • Ricardo D (1817) On the principles of political economy and taxation. John Murray, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmitter PC (1974) Still the century of corporatism? Rev Polit 36:85–131

    Google Scholar 

  • Sherwood RM (1998) Intellectual Property for Latin America: How Soon Will It Work. NAFTA: Law & Bus Rev Am 4:77

    Google Scholar 

  • Sikkink K (1988) The influence of Raul Prebisch on economic policy-making in Argentina, 1950–1962. Latin Am Res Rev 23:91–114

    Google Scholar 

  • Simon D (2019) Key thinkers on development. Routledge, London, S 339–345

    Google Scholar 

  • Spruk R (2019) The rise and fall of Argentina. Latin Am Econ Rev 28:16

    Google Scholar 

  • Ullrich H (2009) Propriété intellectuelle, concurrence et régulation – Limites de protection et limites de controle. 4 RIDE, S. 399, 442

    Google Scholar 

  • Ullrich H (2015) Mandatory licensing under patent law and competition law: different concerns, complementary roles. In: Hilty RM, Liu K-C (Hrsg) Compulsory licensing. Springer, Berlin, S 333

    Google Scholar 

  • UNCTAD (1975) The role of the patent system in the transfer of technology to developing countries: United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Overwalle G (2022) Regulation theory and intellectual property law. In: Godt C, Van Overwalle G, Guibault L, Beyleveld D (Hrsg) Boundaries to information property. Intersentia, Cambridge, S 33–56

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Overwalle G, Léonard A (2024) The public interest in compulsory licensing: examining the complementarity between IP and competition law. In: Godt C, Lamping M (Hrsg) A critical mind in the triangle of internal market law, intellectual property and competition law –Liber Discipulorum for Hanns Ullrich. Springer, Berlin. (forthcoming)

    Google Scholar 

  • Van Overwalle G, van Zimmeren E (2009) Functions and limits of patent law. In: Claes E, Devroe W, Keirsbilck B (Hrsg) Facing the limits of the law. Springer, Berlin/Heidelberg, S 415–442

    Google Scholar 

  • Vidaurreta GE (2007) Historia del Sistema Argentino de Patentes de Invención [1580–1863]: Propiedad Intelectual en la Constitución Nacional. Antecedentes, Fuentes e Interpretación. Facultad de Derecho de la Universidad de Buenos Aires y Editorial La Ley S.A, Buenos Aires, S 153

    Google Scholar 

  • Waterbury J (1999) The long gestation and brief triumph of import-substituting industrialization. World Dev 27:323–341

    Google Scholar 

  • Winham GR (2005) An interpretative history of the Uruguay Round negotiation. In: Macrory PFJ, Appleton AE, Plummer MG (Hrsg) The World Trade Organization: legal, economic and political analysis. Springer US, Boston, S 3–25

    Google Scholar 

  • Yglesias M (2012) The four types of economies and the global imbalances. Slate Magazine, 17 Apr 2012. https://slate.com/business/2012/04/the-four-types-of-economies-and-theglobal-imbalances.html

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Geertrui Van Overwalle .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2024 Der/die Autor(en), exklusiv lizenziert an Springer-Verlag GmbH, DE, ein Teil von Springer Nature

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Van Overwalle, G., Van Dycke, L. (2024). It Takes Two to Tango. Patents and Markets in the Periphery and the Centre. Prebisch Dancing with Hilty. In: Thouvenin, F., Peukert, A., Jaeger, T., Geiger, C. (eds) Kreation Innovation Märkte - Creation Innovation Markets. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-68599-0_52

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-662-68599-0_52

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-662-68598-3

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-662-68599-0

  • eBook Packages: Social Science and Law (German Language)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics