Skip to main content

Compensating Wage Differentials Across Russian Regions

  • Chapter
Geographical Labor Market Imbalances

Part of the book series: AIEL Series in Labour Economics ((AIEL))

Abstract

In this chapter, we provide evidence on compensating differentials in the labor market from the largest transition economy, Russia. Using the NOBUS micro-data and a methodology based on the estimation of the wage equation augmented by aggregate regional characteristics, we show that wage differentials across Russian regions have a compensative nature. Russian workers receive wage compensations for living in regions with a higher price level and worse nonpecuniary characteristics, such as a relatively low life expectancy, a high level of air pollution, poor medical services, a colder climate, and a higher unemployment level. These compensations are not associated with the existing government system of compensating wage coefficients. After adjusting for regional amenities and disamenities, regional wages become positively correlated with interregional migration flows. According to our estimates, wage compensations along with differences in employment composition are able to account for about three-fourths of the observed variation in wages across Russian regions.

JEL Classification J3, J6, P2, R2

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 84.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Although since 2007 the minimum wage level in Russia substantially increased, the Kaitz index (which is the ratio of minimum wage to the average wage) is still low compared with the OECD countries (Muravyev and Oshchepkov 2012) and most of the CEE countries.

  2. 2.

    The internal migration in Russia, in spite of being low by international standards, can be explained by differences in living costs, regional amenities and disamenities, and opportunities on regional labor markets, see e.g., Andrienko and Guriev (2004) and Gerber (2006).

  3. 3.

    As the magnitude of differentiation depends on the country’s particular administrative division, we used several variants of divisions. All results are presented in Table 4.1.

  4. 4.

    Standard decompositions of the total wage inequality show that the effect of the regional factor on the wage inequality is the largest in comparison with other factors such as human capital characteristics, industries and occupations (e.g., Lukiyanova 2008; Oshchepkov 2009). At the same time, the impact of the regional factor on the total wage inequality in Russia is much higher than that in OECD countries (see Oshchepkov 2007).

  5. 5.

    This result contrasts to conclusions of Combes et al. (2008) for France that spatial wage differences in France are mainly explained by differences in employment composition. However, this may be easily explained by much greater spatial variation in amenities and disamenities in Russia than in France.

  6. 6.

    At the background of rich literature on the CEE countries, papers focusing on Russia are rare. The only study known to us is that of Bornhorst and Commander (2006). They examined regional unemployment in five transition countries: Chezh Republic, Hungary, Poland, Romania, and Russia. Most of the results show that correlations between regional wages, unemployment rates, and migration flows in Russia clearly differ from those in the other four countries (see, e.g., Figs. 3 and 4 in Bornhorst and Commander 2006).

  7. 7.

    The wage curve assumes the opposite relation between individual wages and unemployment.

  8. 8.

    Possible deviations from the perfect competition conditions in the Russian context are discussed in Oshchepkov (2009).

  9. 9.

    The concentration of highly productive employees may also explain why firms operate in regions with a relatively high wage level. In this chapter, we control for the regional employment composition, and therefore this possibility is accounted for.

  10. 10.

    A possible explanation for this fact is that such employees face a smaller depreciation of accumulated human capital. At the same time, younger employees are on average less constrained by family and social ties.

  11. 11.

    In estimating Eq. (4.1), one should take into account possible regional clusterization of errors which leads to the underestimation of standard errors of coefficients at the regional characteristics (e.g., Moulton 1990).

  12. 12.

    Productive regional amenities are amenities that allow firms to decrease costs, see Roback (1982) and Beeson and Eberts (1989).

  13. 13.

    A similar methodology was used earlier by Krueger and Summers (1988).

  14. 14.

    It should be noted that it is impossible to adjust interregional wage differentials for regional characteristics with the use of regional dummy variables because of the problem of total multicollinearity. Papers that used regional dummies adjusted only for the regional employment structure (see, for example, Haisken-DeNew and Schwarze 1997; Azzoni and Servo 2002; Garcia and Molina 2002; Viera et al. 2005).

  15. 15.

    These data were used in a number of studies on Russia; see Gustafsson and Nivorozhkina (2011) and Staneva et al. (2010) among recent examples. More information on NOBUS is available on the site of World Bank (see http://go.worldbank.org/VWPUL3S9F0).

  16. 16.

    For more details see Table 4.3 in Oshchepkov (2007).

  17. 17.

    We do not need control for different tax and transfer systems in regions (as, e.g., Johnson 1983), because the personal income tax rate in Russia is equal to 13 % in all regions and social security payments are rather low comparing to wage levels.

  18. 18.

    Only three regions, the Republics of Dagestan and Ingushetiya and the Stavropol Region, border Chechnya.

  19. 19.

    Peculiarities of the system of labor compensation in the Northern territories are described in the article No. 50 of the Russian Labor Code. The magnitude of regional coefficients and the order of their implementation are set by the Russian government. A current list of areas and the magnitude of corresponding wage coefficients are presented in the joint information letter by the Pension Department of the Ministry of Labor (dated by 09.06.2003, No. 1199–1116), the Department of Incomes and Welfare of Population of the Ministry of Labor (dated by 19.05.2003, No. 670–679), and Russian Pension Fund (dated by 09.06.2003, No. 25–23/5995).

  20. 20.

    A higher wage level in a region may push up regional prices in the short run. However, in our theoretical framework, we consider the long-run period, when an interregional wage structure is close to the state of equilibrium. In the long run, relatively high prices in a region will attract producers (sellers) to the market. They will increase their supply of goods up until the benefit (that is the difference between prices in two regions) is less than transportation costs. Therefore, an interregional structure of prices for tradable goods in long run is determined by transportation costs and does not depend on regional wages.

  21. 21.

    These services are public conveyances, communication, and public utilities. For more information about the composition of the price index see in “Ceni v Rossii” (“Prices in Russia”), Rosstat (2004).

  22. 22.

    We should note that the price index for a common set of goods and services is a Laysperes price index. However, the optimal consumption structure may differ across regions, and so differences in regional price levels may either overestimate or underestimate the differences in the levels of utility that were brought about by these price differentials. In our study we do not control for this possibility.

  23. 23.

    In earlier versions of our paper we included regional housing prices to the regressions along with the price index. There are two reasons why we excluded housing prices from this version. Firstly, housing is a very specific good comparing with other goods and services included in the fixed set. The prices for housing are much higher than for “standard” goods, and people purchase houses much more rarely than such good as, for example, food and clothes. Although people may also rent housing, these expenditures are also higher than expenditures on “standard” goods and services, and only about 2.7 % individuals from the regression sample rented housing. Secondly, unfortunately we did not manage to find an appropriate instrument for housing prices, which would be correlated with them, but not correlated with regional incomes.

  24. 24.

    A similar method to solve the problem of endogeneity in the wage regression framework was used by Moretti (2004). He instrumented the percentage of college educated workers in the labor force of a city by the presence of land-grant colleges (which were founded in 1862 in the context of the federal program). For Russia, a similar method was used in Muravyev (2008). The author argued that the educational structure of cities under the central planning was determined by the federal government rather than by the market and instrumented the 1994 share of people with higher education with the respective share in 1989.

  25. 25.

    According to Rosstat, during the period from 2000 to 2005, the net migration coefficient was the highest in Moscow and the Moscow region (if data on the Republic of Ingushetia are not considered). In 2002, Moscow and the Moscow region had a positive exchange of migrants with 47 regions; the Tumenskaya Region had the next largest positive migration balance, with seven regions.

  26. 26.

    Rosstat, “Demographic yearbook”, 2001–2007 issues.

  27. 27.

    See, for example, Gimpelson and Lukiyanova (2009).

  28. 28.

    This may be due to different agglomeration effects: input–output linkages, thicker markets with better employer–employee matching and higher specialization of workers, knowledge accumulation, or the localization of HC externalities, etc. (Fujita and Tisse 2002).

  29. 29.

    The intra-class correlation coefficient estimated for residuals received from Specification 1 is positive and significant. This indicates that standard errors of coefficients for regional characteristics in Specification 1 are underestimated.

  30. 30.

    Following recommendations presented in the Chap. 8 of Baum (2006), we employed a series of tests for the relevance of the instruments and the Durbin–Wu–Hausman test of the endogeneity of our infrastructure variables. We note that, unfortunately, these tests are not technically executable in the survey regression framework; therefore, we employed them estimating Specification 3 by simple OLS. The results of the tests are presented in Tables 4.5 and 4.6. The tests fully support the relevance of our instruments and the endogeneity of the infrastructure variables.

    Table 4.5 Tests for the relevance of the instruments
    Table 4.6 Tests for endogeneity of the infrastructure variables
  31. 31.

    We cannot exclude also the possibility that with the use of some other (unknown to us) instruments, the infrastructure variables in our regression will be significant. However, one can expect that the coefficient of a variable reflecting medical services will remain negative, because it is biased upward due to the “welfare effect.”

  32. 32.

    See Andrienko and Guriev (2004) and Gerber (2006).

  33. 33.

    We note that all regional characteristics are significant at the 10 % level, and they are jointly significant at the 5 % level. As an additional robustness check, we reestimated specification 9 excluding from the sample two Russian capitals—Moscow and Saint Petersburg— which are two regions that are outliers on most of the regional characteristics used. Though this reduced the size of coefficients at medical staff and life expectancy, all the coefficients remained significant at the 10 % level.

  34. 34.

    We note that high life expectancy in Russia’s southern regions might be a consequence of a high proportion of people with specific religious, cultural and ethnic traditions. Therefore, it could be difficult to receive this amenity by moving to these regions. However, firstly, living in a neighborhood where people live longer might be a self-dependent amenity for migrants (for instance, from the point of view of gaining experience). Secondly, high life expectancy is not possible without favorable natural and environmental conditions.

  35. 35.

    The positive relationship between wages and regional unemployment level may be also interpreted in a dynamic perspective. For instance, recent studies suggest that high unemployment regions have a higher rate of reallocation (e.g., Pastore 2012). If we assume that in regions with more intense worker reallocation and industrial restructuring wages are higher than in other regions, then we receive a positive correlation between regional wages and unemployment. However, we are not aware of studies which examine the relationship between restructuring and unemployment in Russia.

  36. 36.

    The estimated coefficient of the regional price index became lower, but it still does not significantly differ from one (the p-value of the F(1,78)-statistics of the corresponding F-test is equal to 0.379). Changes in other coefficients are not significant either.

  37. 37.

    Among the elements of the employment composition, the industrial mix plays the most important role contributing about 8 % of IWD (for more details see Oshchepkov 2009).

  38. 38.

    Within the framework used in our paper, we implicitly treat employment composition as fixed. However, at each moment differences in the employment composition across regions are subject to the ongoing and uneven process of industrial restructuring. Therefore, in several years the impact of employment composition may rise (or fall). In order to investigate our results in such a dynamic perspective, we need regionally representative panel micro-data, which are not available.

  39. 39.

    Although we control the size of settlement in our regressions, Moscow (as well as St. Petersburg) may demand a special treatment, because they differ from other cities in the top category (one million people or more).

  40. 40.

    It may be also the case that relatively highly paid workers underrepresented more in the Moscow subsample of the database used than in the subsamples for other regions.

  41. 41.

    Adjusted and unadjusted wage premiums tend to be relatively stable in time. Therefore, wage premiums estimated for 2003 may influence migration decisions in other years. We present correlations between adjusted and unadjusted wage premiums for the period 2000–2005.

  42. 42.

    Fidrmuc (2004) and Kwon and Spilimbergo (2005).

References

  • Andrienko, Y., & Guriev, S. (2004). Determinants of interregional labor mobility in Russia. Evidence from panel data. Economics of Transition, 12, 1–27.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Azzoni, C., & Servo, L. (2002). Education cost of living and regional wage inequality in Brazil. Papers in Regional Science, 81, 157–175.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baum, C. (2006). An introduction to modern econometrics using Stata. College Station, TX: Stata Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Beeson, P. (1991). Amenities and regional differences in returns to worker characteristics. Journal of Urban Economics, 30, 224–241.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Beeson, P., & Eberts, R. (1989). Identifying productivity and amenity effects in interurban and wage differentials. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 71, 443–452.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bentivogli, C., & Pagano, P. (1999). Regional disparities and labour mobility: The Euro-11 versus the USA. Labour, 13, 737–760.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berger, M., Blomquist, G., & Sabirianova, P. K. (2008). Compensating differentials in emerging labor and housing market: Estimates of quality of life in Russian cities. Journal of Urban Economics, 63, 25–55.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bignebat, C. (2005). Why are wage so high in Siberia? Report on the joint CEFIR-BOFIT Conference, Moscow, April.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchard, O., & Katz, L. (1992). Regional evolutions. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 1992, 1–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower, D. (2001). Unemployment, well-being, and wage curves in eastern and central Europe. Journal of Japanese and International Economics, 15, 364–402.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower, D., & Oswald, A. (1994). The wage curve. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Blanchflower, D., Oswald, A., & Sanfey, P. (1996). Wages, profits and rent-sharing. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111(1), 227–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blomquist, G. C., Berger, M. C., & Hoehn, J. P. (1988). New estimates of quality of life in urban areas. American Economic Review, 78, 89–107.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bornhorst, F., & Commander, S. (2006). Regional unemployment and its persistence in transition countries. Econmics of Transition, 14, 269–288.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Braakman, N. (2009). Is there a compensating wage differential for high crime levels? First evidence from Europe. Journal of Urban Economics, 66, 218–231.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Combes, P.-P., Duranton, G., & Gobillon, L. (2008). Spatial wage disparities. Sorting matters! Journal of Urban Economics, 63, 723–742.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Costa, D. L., & Kahn, M. E. (2003). The rising price of nonmarket goods. American Economic Review, 93, 227–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dickie, M., & Gerking, S. (1987). Interregional wage differentials: An equilibrium perspective. Journal of Regional Science, 27, 571–585.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dumond, J., Hirsch, B., & Macpherson, D. (1999). Wage differentials across labor markets and workers: Does cost of living matter? Economic Inquiry, 37, 577–598.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferragina, A.-M., & Pastore, F. (2008). Mind the gap: Unemployment in the new EU regions. Journal of Economic Surveys, 22, 77–113.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fidrmuc, J. (2004). Migration and regional adjustment to asymmetric shocks in transition economies. Journal of Comparative Economics, 32, 230–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fujita, M., & Tisse, J.-F. (2002). Economics of agglomeration. Cambridge, MA: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Furdato, A. (1996, August 26–30). Interregional wage differentials in the European Union: A cross-section analysis for Italy, Germany, Spain and the United Kingdom. In 36th European Congress. European Regional Science Association, ETII Zurich, Switzerland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Garcia, I., & Molina, J. (2002). Inter-regional wage differentials in Spain. Applied Economic Letters, 9, 209–215.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerber, T. (2006). Regional economic performance and net migration rates in Russia, 1993–2002. International Migration Review, 40, 661–697.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gimpelson, V., & Kapelyushnikov, R. (2011). Labor market adjustment: Is Russia different? (IZA Discussion Paper No. 5588).

    Google Scholar 

  • Gimpelson, V., & Lukiyanova, A. (2009). Are public sector workers underpaid in Russia? Estimating the public-private wage gap (IZA Discussion Paper No. 3941).

    Google Scholar 

  • Goldfarb, R., & Yezer, A. (1976). Evaluating alternative theories of intercity and interregional wage differentials. Journal of Regional Science, 16, 345–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood, M., Hunt, G., Rickman, D., & Treyz, G. (1991a). Migration, regional equilibrium, and the estimation of compensating differentials. The American Economic Review, 81, 1382–1390.

    Google Scholar 

  • Greenwood, M., Mueser, P., Plane, D., & Shlottman, A. (1991b). New directions in migration research. The Annals of Regional Science, 25, 237–270.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gustafson, B., Shi, L., & Nivorojkina, L. (2011). Why household incomes are more unequally distributed in China than in Russia? Cambridge Journal of Economics, 35, 897–920. doi:10.1093/cje/beq052.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haisken-DeNew, J., & Schwarze, J. (1997). Regionale Lohndisparitaeten in Deutschland 1984–1994. Eine Analyse mit regionalisierten Daten des Sozio-ökonomischen Panels. Informationen zur Raumentwicklung, 1–2, 51–61.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hall, R., Gordon, A., & Holt, C. (1972). Turnover in the labor force. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, 3, 709–764.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harris, J., & Todaro, M. (1970). Migration, unemployment and development: A two sector analysis. American Economic Review, 60, 126–142.

    Google Scholar 

  • Heleniak, T. (1999). Migration from the Russian north during the transition period (World Bank Social Protection Discussion Paper Series, No. 9925).

    Google Scholar 

  • Iara, A., & Traistaru, I. (2004). How flexible are wages in EU accession countries? Labour Economics, 11, 431–450.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Johnson, G. (1983). Intermetropolitan wage differentials in the United States. In J. Triplett (Ed.), The measurement of labor costs (pp. 309–332). Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kapelushnikov, R., & Vishnevskaya, N. (2003). Fenomen Rossiiskoi bezrabotici: dinamika, struktura, specifika (Unemployment in Russia: Dynamics, structure and specifics). Moscow: Moscow Scientific Foundation (in Russian).

    Google Scholar 

  • Karachurina, L. (2007). Demograficheskie factori migracionnoi aktivnosti naselenia Rossii: sovremennaya situacia i perespektivi [Demographic factors of migration in Russia: Current situation and perspectives]. Demoscop Weekly, 285–286 (in Russian).

    Google Scholar 

  • Knapp, T., & Graves, P. (1989). On the role of amenities in models of migration and regional developments. Journal of Regional Science, 29, 71–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krueger, A., & Summers, L. (1988). Efficiency wages and the inter-industry wage structure. Econometrica, 56, 259–293.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kwon, G., & Spilimbergo, A. (2005). Russia’s regions: Income volatility, labour mobility and fiscal policy (IMF Working Paper No. 05/185).

    Google Scholar 

  • Lukiyanova, A. (2008). Structure and distribution of earnings in Russia, 1994–2003. The Journal of Comparative Economic Studies, 4, 9–40.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lukiyanova, A. (2011). Wage inequality in Russian economic transition (1991–2008): Stylized facts and explanations. Journal of New Economic Association, 12, 124–147 (in Russian).

    Google Scholar 

  • Manning, A. (2003). The real thin theory: Monopsony in modern labour markets. Labour Economics, 10(2), 105–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Marston, S. (1985). Two views on geographic distribution of unemployment. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 100, 57–79.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mincer, J. (1978). Family migration decisions. The Journal of Political Economy, 86, 749–773.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitra, P., & Yemtsov, R. (2006). Increasing inequality in transition economies: Is there more to come? (World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 4007).

    Google Scholar 

  • Mkrtchian, N. (2003). Iz Rossii v Rossiu: otkuda i kuda edut vnutrennie migranti? [From Russia to Russia: Where do internal migrants go?]. Mir Rossii, 2, 151–164 (in Russian).

    Google Scholar 

  • Mkrtchian, N. (2005). Migracia v Rossii: zapadni dreif [Migration in Russia: The western drift]. Demoscop Weekly, 185–186 (in Russian).

    Google Scholar 

  • Moretti, E. (2004). Estimating the social return to higher education: Evidence from longitudinal and repeated cross-sectional data. Journal of Econometrics, 121, 175–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moulton, B. (1990). An illustration of a pitfall in estimating the effects of aggregate variables in micro units’. The Review of Economic and Statistics, 72, 334–338.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muravyev, A. (2008). Human capital externalities: Evidence from the transition economy of Russia. Economics of Transition, 16, 415–443.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muravyev, A., & Oshchepkov, A. (2012). Minimum wages and labor market outcomes: Evidence from the emerging economy of Russia (Higher School Of Economics Research Paper No. WP BRP 29/EC/2013).

    Google Scholar 

  • Nickell, S. (1999). Product markets and labour markets. Labour Economics, 6(1), 1–20.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oshchepkov, A. (2007). Are interregional wage differentials in Russia compensative? (DIW Discussion Paper No. 750).

    Google Scholar 

  • Oshchepkov, A. (2009). Interregional wage differentials in Russia. Ph.D. Thesis, Higher School of Economics (in Russian).

    Google Scholar 

  • Pastore, F. (2012). Primum vivere…industrial change, job destruction and the geographical distribution of unemployment. IZA Journal of European Labor Studies, 1(7), 1–15.

    Google Scholar 

  • Reza, A. (1978). Geographical differences in earnings and unemployment rates. The Review of Economics and Statistics, 60, 201–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roback, J. (1982). Wages, rents and the quality of life. Journal of Political Economy, 90, 1257–1278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Roback, J. (1988). Wages, rents, and amenities: Differences among workers and regions. Economic Inquiry, 26, 23–41.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rosen, S. (1974). Hedonic prices and implicit markets: Production differentiation in pure competition. The Journal of Political Economy, 82, 34–55.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosen, S. (1986). The theory of equalizing differences. In O. Ashenfelter & R. Layard (Eds.), Handbook of labor economics (Vol. 1, pp. 641–692). Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosstat. (2001–2007). Demographic yearbook. Moscow: Rosstat (in Russian).

    Google Scholar 

  • Rosstat. (2004). Prices in Russia. Moscow: Rosstat (in Russian).

    Google Scholar 

  • Ryasantcev, S. (2005). Vnutrerossiiskaya trudovaya migracia naselenia: tendecii i socialno-economicheskie posledstvia [Internal labour migration in Russia: Tendencies and socio-economic consequences]. Voprosi Ekonomiki, 7, 37–50 (in Russian).

    Google Scholar 

  • Shilov, A., & Moeller, J. (2009). The wage curve in Russia, 1995–2005. Economics Letters, 102, 90–92.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Staneva, A., Arabsheibani, R., & Murphy, P. (2010). Returns to education in four transition countries: Quantile regression approach (IZA Discussion Paper No. 5210).

    Google Scholar 

  • Topel, R. (1986). Local labor markets. The Journal of Political Economy, 94, S111–S143.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Viera, J., Couto, J., &, Tiago, M. (2005). Inter-regional wage dispersion in Portugal (IZA Discussion Paper No. 1664).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

I am grateful to Tilman Brück, Irina Denisova, Vladimir Gimpelson, Rostislav Kapelushnikov, Hartmut Lehmann, Anna Lukiyanova, Alexander Muravyev, Sergei Roschin, and two anonymous referees for valuable comments and suggestions. The support from the Study Foundation of the Berlin House of Representatives and the Basic Research Program of the National Research University Higher School of Economics is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Aleksey Oshchepkov .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer-Verlag Berlin Heidelberg

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Oshchepkov, A. (2015). Compensating Wage Differentials Across Russian Regions. In: Mussida, C., Pastore, F. (eds) Geographical Labor Market Imbalances. AIEL Series in Labour Economics. Springer, Berlin, Heidelberg. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-642-55203-8_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics