Skip to main content

Reciprocity Approaches: The Possibility of Human Cooperation

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
The Cordial Economy - Ethics, Recognition and Reciprocity

Part of the book series: Ethical Economy ((SEEP,volume 55))

  • 221 Accesses

Abstract

Finding an explanation for human cooperation in highly competitive contexts has become one of the main challenges for economics. Many field studies and laboratory experiments with strategy games have shown that human beings are predisposed to cooperate with their peers in a competitive context like the economic one, and that this is a conduct which most agents consider to be desirable. For many economists, behind this diversion of the theoretical model based on the self-interested rationality of homo oeconomicus lies the human capacity to reciprocate. This allows agents to establish interpersonal relationships to meet common objectives. The objective of this chapter will be to analyse the main reciprocity approaches proposed from sociobiology , evolutionary economics and humanistic economics from the ethical-critical viewpoint as a plausible explanation for cooperation in different areas of activity, particularly economics.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 79.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 99.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 99.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    To learn the basic aspects of this argument, see Olson (1965).

  2. 2.

    As Camilo J. Cela-Conde (1989) explained, sociobiology coined the inclusive fitness concept with the intention of attempting to offer a plausible explanation about the paradox aroused by altruism . Natural selection is assumed to have a tendency to favour individual fitnesses, so it seems paradoxical that so many people who display this non-individualistic fitness exist.

  3. 3.

    The term kin selection was coined by John Maynard Smith in Group Selection and Kin Selection (1964) to refer to the idea expressed by Hamilton .

  4. 4.

    As Dawkins argues, “(…) in the world of Darwinism, gains are not paid in money, but in descendants” (2016).

  5. 5.

    The inclusive fitness or kinship rule would be related to both the direct fitness and the indirect fitness (Curtis et al. 2008: 836).

  6. 6.

    Different studies indicate that reciprocal altruism has very little to do with uninterested disinterested attitude because the person performing the act does so expecting a future behavioural response from the other person in case of need. They therefore suggested that the most suitable name would be weak reciprocity (Bowles 2006, 444, 433) or direct reciprocity (Becchetti et al. 2010: 289).

  7. 7.

    Well-known theorists were among the participants, like Dawkins , Rapoport or Maynard Smith .

  8. 8.

    It should be borne in mind that tournament players were not human beings, but computer programmes representing the strategies developed by each theorist in the group (Dawkins 2016: 271).

  9. 9.

    As Axelrod explained, this particular characteristic defined the so-called round-robin-type tournament (2003: 30).

  10. 10.

    Friedman ’s resentful strategy proposal did not work well at all (Dawkins 2016: 274).

  11. 11.

    Although all the participants from the first tournament were asked to participate, they did not all agree to compete again; e.g. Dawkins presented a strategy in the first tournament but rejected Axelrod ’s offer to compete again (Dawkins 2016).

  12. 12.

    Maynard Smith presented an extremely merciful version of tit-for-tat but did not manage to beat Rapoport ’s original strategy (Dawkins 2016: 275).

  13. 13.

    An ESS cannot be invalidated by other mutant or rare strategies. The tit-for-tat strategy cannot be considered a ESS because it comes over as being unyielding with “nasty” strategies, but not with “nice” ones (Dawkins 2016: 280–281).

  14. 14.

    See also Bowles (2006); Bowles and Gintis (1998, 2004, 2006, 2011); Fehr and Fischbacher (2005); Gintis (2000, 2010); Henrich et al. (2001, 2004).

  15. 15.

    Zero or close to zero rates.

  16. 16.

    Axelrod argued that “(…) the reciprocity that works well in the Bipersonal Prisoner’s Dilemma simply does not work in the n-persons game version when there are more than just a few people involved” (2003: 60).

  17. 17.

    One type of dual relationship could be the mutual exchange of assets.

  18. 18.

    Ostrom’s first explorations into reciprocity are found in the article “A Behavioral Approach to the Rational Choice Theory of Collective Action ”, published in 1998.

  19. 19.

    Ostrom ’s relationality would be framed within a limited two-way rationality that considers both rational interest in personal well-being and interest in others’ well-being (which, despite being self-interested, introduces feelings and pro-social emotions as something rational). Sen , however, argues that another level of rationality exists that is not self-interested, committed to that which we consider is right and fair. Ostrom does not consider this level.

  20. 20.

    On this matter, see Henrich et al. (2001), and Fehr and Rockenbach (2003).

  21. 21.

    As previously mentioned, Adam Smith seemed to suggest one kind of transitive reciprocal behaviour  – inclusive reciprocity – which was strikingly similar to that developed by Zamagni . Smith warned about was how unfruitful it was for society to both give without expecting and to receive without acting. So, benevolence is positive, as long as it is used in the context of relationships controlled by the logic of reciprocity.

  22. 22.

    There are studies in economic and business ethics about other reciprocal behaviours in humans. For example, work is being done about the possibility of institutional-type reciprocity ; in other words, an indirect form of relationality which, based on the act of offering help to others in exchange for this help benefitting the development and enrichment of a given institution, requires that the reciprocator should pay the high costs.

Bibliography

  • Alexander, Richard. 1987. The Biology of Moral Systems. New York: Aldine.

    Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod, Robert. 1984. The evolution of cooperation. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1986. La evolución de la cooperación. Madrid: Alianza.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2003. La complejidad de la cooperación. Modelos de cooperación basados en los agentes. Buenos Aires: Fondo de Cultura Económica de Argentina.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becchetti, Leonardo, Luigino Bruni, and Stefano Zamagni. 2010. Microeconomia. Scelte, Relazione, Economia Civile. Bologna: Il Mulino.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, Samuel. 2006 [2004]. Microeconomics: Behavior, Institutions, and Evolution. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, Samuel, and Herbert Gintis. 1998. Is equality Passé? Homo reciprocans and the future of egalitarian politics. Boston Review 23 (6): 1–27.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2003. The origins of human cooperation. In The Genetic and Cultural Origins Of Cooperation, ed. P. Hammerstein, 429–444. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2004. Homo Economicus and Zoon Politikon: Behavioral Game Theory and Political Behavior, 1–16.. http://www.umass.edu/preferen/gintis/Homo%20Economicus%20and%20Zoon%20Politikon.pdf. Accessed 25 Sept 2017.

  • ———. 2006. Social preferences, homo economicus and zoon politikon. In Work of Contextual Political Analysis, ed. Robert E. Goodin and Charles Tilly, 172–186. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2011. A Cooperative Species. Human Reciprocity and Its Evolution. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bowles, Samuel, Robert Boyd, Ernst Fehr, and Herbert Gintis. 1997. Homo reciprocans: A research initiative on the origins, dimensions, and policy implications of reciprocal fairness. Advances in Complex Systems 4 (2–3): 1–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brondizio, Eduardo S., Elinor Ostrom, and Oran R. Young. 2009. Connectivity and the governance of multilevel social-ecological systems: The role of social capital. The Annual Review of Environment and Resources 34 (1–3): 253–278.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bruni, Luigino. 2006. Reciprocità. Dinamiche di cooperazione, economia e società civile. Milan: Bruno Mondadori.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2008 [2006]. El precio de la gratuidad. Madrid: Ciudad Nueva.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bruni, Luigino, and Stefano Zamagni. 2007 [2004]. Civil Economy: Efficiency, Equity, Public Happiness. New York: Peter Lang.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cárdenas, Juan-Camilo, and Elinor Ostrom. 2004. What do people bring into the game? Experiments in the field about cooperation in the commons. Agricultural Systems 82: 307–326.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carpenter, Jeffrey, Samuel Bowles, Herbert Gintis, and Sung-Ha Hwang. 2009. Strong reciprocity and team production: Theory and evidence. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 71 (2): 221–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cela-Conde, Camilo-José. 1989. Altruismo moral y altruismo biológico. Taula 12: 34–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cortina, Adela. 2007a. Ethica cordis. Isegoría. Revista de Filosofía Moral y Política 37: 113–126.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2007b. Ética de la razón cordial. Educar en la ciudadanía en el siglo XXI. Oviedo: Nobel.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2010. Justicia Cordial. Madrid: Trotta.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2011. Neuroética y Neuropolítica. Sugerencias para la Educación Moral. Madrid: Tecnos.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2013. ¿Para qué sirve realmente… la ética? Barcelona: Paidos Iberica.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2017. Aporofobia, el rechazo al pobre. Un desafío para la democracia. Barcelona: Paidós Ibérica.

    Google Scholar 

  • Curtis, Helena, N. Barnes Sue, and Adriana Schnek. 2008. Biología. Buenos Aires: Editorial Médica Panamericana.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dawkins, Richard. 1982. The Extended Phenotype: The Gene as the Unit of Selection. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2016 [1976]. The Selfish Gene. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, Ernst, and Urs Fischbacher. 2005. The economics of strong reciprocity. In Moral Sentiments and Material Interests. The Foundations of Cooperation in Economic Life, ed. Herbert Gintis, Samuel Bowles, Robert Boyd, and Ernst Fehr, 151–191. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, Ernst, and Simon Gächter. 1998. Reciprocity and economics: The economic implications of homo reciprocans. European Economic Review 42 (3): 845–859.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, Ernst, and Bettina Rockenbach. 2003. Detrimental effects of sanctions on human altruism. Nature 422 (6928): 137–140.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, Ernst, Simon Gächter, and Georg Kirchsteiger. 1997. Reciprocity as a contract enforcement device: Experimental evidence. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society 65 (4): 833–860.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, Ernst, Urs Fischbacher, and Simon Gächter. 2002. Strong reciprocity, human cooperation and the enforcement of social norms. Human Nature 13 (1): 1–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fletcher, Jeffrey A., and Martin Zwick. 2006. Unifying the theories of inclusive fitness and reciprocal altruism. The American Naturalist 168 (2): 252–262.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fong, Christina M., Samuel Bowles, and Herbert Gintis. 2005. Reciprocity and the welfare state. In Moral Sentiments and Material Interests. On the Foundations of Cooperation in Economic Life, ed. Herbert Gintis, Samuel Bowles, Robert Boyd, and Ernst Fehr, 277–302. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank, Robert H. 1988. Passions Within Reason: The Strategic Role of the Emotions. New York: W. W. Norton & Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gintis, Herbert. 2000. Game Theory Evolving: A Problem-Centered Introduction to Modeling Strategic Interaction. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2010. Behavioral ethics. In Creating consilience: Integrating the Sciences and the Humanities (New Directions in Cognitive Science), ed. Edward Slingerlan and Mark Collard, 318–333. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2016. Individuality and Entanglement: The Moral and Material Bases of Social Life. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton, William D. 1964. The genetical evolution of social behaviour, I&II. Journal of Theoretical Biology 7 (1): 1–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henrich, Josep, Robert Boyd, Samuel Bowles, Colin Camerer, Ernst Fehr, Herbert Gintis, and Richard McElreath. 2001. In search of Homo Economicus: Behavioral experiments in 15 small-scale societies. American Economic Review 91 (2): 73–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henrich, Josep, Robert Boyd, Samuel Bowles, Colin Camerer, Ernst Fehr, and Herbert Gintis. 2004. Foundation of Human Sociality: Ethnography and Experiments in Fifteen Small-Scale Societies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Leimar, Olof, and Peter Hammerstein. 2001. Evolution of cooperation through indirect reciprocity. The Royal Society 268: 745–753.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mandeville, Bernard. 1705. The Grumbling Hive, or Knaves Turn’d Honest. London: Sam Ballard.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1724 [1714]. The Fable of the Bees: Or, Private Vices, Public Benefits. 3rd ed. London: J. Tonson.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marechal, Patricia. 2009. Selección de Grupo y Altruismo: El Origen del Debate. Scientia Studia 7 (3): 447–459.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maynard Smith, John. 1964. Group selection and kin selection. Nature 201: 1145–1147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mediavilla, Daniel. 2015, November 3. Michael Tomasello: “Para mejorar la sociedad no podemos obviar lo negativo de nuestra biología”. El País. https://elpais.com/elpais/2015/10/20/ciencia/1445363532_639418.html

  • Olson, Mancur. 1965. The Logic of Collective Action: Public Goods and the Theory of Groups. Harvard: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, Elinor. 1998. A behavioral approach to the rational choice theory of collective action. American Political Science Review 92 (1): 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2000 [1990]. El Gobierno de los Comunes. La Evolución de las Instituciones de Acción Colectiva. Mexico: Fondo Cultural de Economía.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2003. Toward a behavioral theory linking trust, reciprocity, and reputation. In Trust & Reciprocity. Interdisciplinary Lessons from Experimental Research, ed. E. Ostrom y James Walker, 19–79. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, Elinor y T.K. Ahn 2003. Una Perspectiva del Capital Social desde las Ciencias Sociales: Capital Social y Acción Colectiva. Revista Mexicana de Sociología 65 (1): 155–233.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Panchanathan, Karthik, and Robert Boyd. 2001. A tale of two defectors: The importance of standing for evolution of indirect reciprocity. Journal of Theoretical Biology 224 (1): 115–126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Putnam, Robert D., Roberto Leonardi, and Raffaella Nanetti. 1993. Making Democracy Work: Civic Traditions in Modern Italy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Strawson, Peter F. 1974. Freedom and Resentment and Other Essays. London: Methuen.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sugden, Robert. 1986. The Economics of Rights, Co-operation and Welfare. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trivers, Robert L. 1971. The evolution of reciprocal altruism. Quarterly Review of Biology 46: 35–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zamagni, Stefano. 2009. Fraternity, gifts and reciprocity in Cáritas in Veritate. Revista Cultural Económica 27 (75–76): 11–29.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer International Publishing AG, part of Springer Nature

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Calvo, P. (2018). Reciprocity Approaches: The Possibility of Human Cooperation. In: The Cordial Economy - Ethics, Recognition and Reciprocity. Ethical Economy, vol 55. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-90784-0_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics