Skip to main content

Risk-Analysis Techniques for the Economic Evaluation of Investment Projects

  • Conference paper
  • First Online:
Integrated Evaluation for the Management of Contemporary Cities (SIEV 2016)

Part of the book series: Green Energy and Technology ((GREEN))

Abstract

The argument of Pope Francis’ “Laudato si’” Encyclical was developed around the concept of “integral ecology”: «Since everything is closely interrelated and today’s problems require a vision capable of taking account every aspect of the global crisis, I suggest we now consider some elements of an integral ecology, one which clearly respects its human and social dimension» (Pope Francis 2015). With regard to investment initiatives, the pursuit of not only financial but also social, cultural and environmental objectives requires a careful and accurate analysis of the various risk components associated with this concept. The objective of this paper is to strongly focus on the concept of risk and the techniques that are commonly used for risk analysis in the economic evaluation of projects. Also included are the identification of critical issues and outlining of potential successful research prospects that are linked to the entire process.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 169.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Gobbi (1919, p. 49) wrote: «An event may be economically advantageous or disadvantageous for a person depending on whether he or she is more or less equipped with means for his/her life; it is indifferent if the event has neither one nor the other effect. The word risk is sometimes used in the sense of chance that has, good or bad, economic consequences; most often in the sense of an economically unfavorable eventuality».

    Nor does this meaning contradict the distinction for business activities proposed by Mowbray and Blanchard (1961) in:

    • speculative risks”, characterized by an occurrence that can be both profit and loss and

    • pure risks” for which they projected only cases of loss.

  2. 2.

    Uncertainty indicates a “generic state” that does not support complete knowledge of the development of the facts. Resuming Spencer and Siegelman (1964, p. 9): «Uncertainty has been defined as a state of knowledge in which one or more alternatives result in a set of possible specific outcomes, but where the probabilities of the outcomes are neither known nor meaningful».

    The same explanation is given by Saraceno (1970, p. 122): «It can be seen that:

    1. (1)

      in the decisions taken in uncertainty situations, the values assigned to P do not find a good foundation in the observations of the past; such decisions are, therefore, inevitably different, from other operators to other operators;

    2. (2)

      in the decisions taken in a situation of risk, the observation of the past provides evidences on the value that has to be assigned to P; if such a presumption is founded and if the observation is made correctly, several operators can therefore assign equal values to P. In other words, the subjectivity that is relevant to the situation referred to in point 1 can effectively fall into the decisions referred to in point (2), while maintaining the risk situation;

    3. (3)

      in the decisions taken in a situation of certainty, the observation of the past induces a zero value at all probabilities except for one; the determination then results in a choice between the only alternatives contemplated in the corresponding column of the only condition that may occur».

    Panati and Golinelli (1991) use the terms deterministic certainty, probability certainty and absolute uncertainty.

    The same exegesis is also given by Zerbe and Bellas (2006, p. 256) for the purposes of the cost-benefit analysis of investment projects: «Uncertainty refers to the idea that planners do not know for certain what the state of the world will be. While they realize that different states of the world may occur, the relative probabilities of these states of the world may be unknown. Risk is a condition where probabilities are assigned to these different states of the world and active consideration is given to how good or bad the outcomes are in each state of the world».

  3. 3.

    In this sense, Pennisi and Scandizzo (2003) on p. 227 give an interesting definition of uncertainty and risk: «There is usually uncertainty when it comes to an objective condition, characterized by the possibility that future events may differ according to the different states of nature that may occur. We speak instead of risk to denote a subjective condition in which, as a consequence of uncertainty, the well-being of one or more subjects depends on the particular state of nature that will occur. It is said in this case that the subject runs a risk to indicate that his well-being can be jeopardized (but may also be exalted) by the realization of one or more particular events».

  4. 4.

    Among them, we find: Keynes (1921, 2nd ed. 1929), Keynes (1936), Borel (192434), Von Neumann and Morgenstern (1944), Samuelson (1952), Hicks (1959) and Saraceno (1970, op. cit.).

    It should be noted, however, that studies related to the criteria useful for the so-called uncertainty economy date back to Fermat and Pascal (1654), Huygens (1657), Bernoulli (1730, 1731, 1738) and Laplace (1814). For further information on the historical evolution of risk analysis and treatment, see Massè (1965).

  5. 5.

    It is worth emphasizing the different conceptual meaning often attributed to the terms “economic appraisal” and “economic analysis” of the risk. As Dezzani F. explains (1971, p. 20): «While the studies that specifically investigate the economic reflection of future events are studies on the risk’s “economic analysis”, those aiming at researches on the occurrence of future events’ “state of knowledge” are instead studies on the risk’s “economic evaluation”».

  6. 6.

    The economic-corporate literature deals with risk management in business activities since the early decades of the last century. At first, the issue was addressed in terms of insurance management, since it was almost exclusively tended to forms of axiomatic cover; Only since the 1950s was there the introduction of the term risk management, currently understood as a process to permeate the entire decision-making process. On historical-evolutionary aspects, just mentioned here, see Bernstein (2002) and Beretta (2004, in particular pages 20–33).

  7. 7.

    Equivalent is the definition that Amelotti and Valcalda (1998, pp. 253–280) given to risk management for investment projects. In particular, the authors recognize moments, temporally successive and interrelated, so understood:

    « –risk planning: it represents the development process to organize an interactive strategy to identify the risk-parameters directors, to realize the operational plans, to assess risk evolution and to plan the necessary resources;

    risk assessment: it represents the process concerning the identification and classification of risks and their analysis (lessons learned) to define its details, to isolate the cause and to quantify the effects using the tools of Project Management such as WBS, networks, cost model, performance evaluation, etc.;

    risk handling: it represents the process related to the identification, the selection and the implementation of the actions to take to limit the risk to acceptable levels according to the objectives and the constraints of the project;

    risk monitoring: it represents the process that systematically highlights and reviews the risk-handling performance» (p. 256).

  8. 8.

    As Mishan (1974, p. 295) claims, «the problem concerning how to make decisions in those situations where past experience has little or no orientation value cannot be satisfactorily solved either in logical or empirical terms, and all of the rules that have been formulated are applicable in a limited way or without a practical value».

  9. 9.

    With this tool, a mathematical law, called objective function, which corresponds to the project’s result with its representative variables, is defined. Constraints, associated with the function and expressed in the form of equations or inequalities, define the eligibility set for the values ​​of the variables. The problem to solve is therefore to optimize a function with multiple variables subjected to the predetermined constraint system.

    With regard to the purely mathematical aspects, see, among many, Hillier and Lieberman (2006). For an application to the investment programs definition, see Morano and Nesticò (2007).

  10. 10.

    A critical analysis on the topic is in Mishan (1974, op. cit.). About the game theory use to support the decisions, see Bennion (1956), Luce and Raiffa (1967).

  11. 11.

    In Anglo-Saxon countries, we often talk about bop analysis, where bop is the acronym of best, optimistic, pessimistic.

  12. 12.

    On this topic, see Chandler and Cockle (1982) and Loasby (1990). Examples of both sensitivity analysis and evaluation in various scenarios are in Brealey et al. (2006, pp. 234–240). It is worth noting that the authors found in break-even point analysis a different way of applying the sensitivity analysis: «When we submit a project to sensitivity analysis or when we consider alternative scenarios, we wonder what would happen if sales or costs were different from forecasts. Managers sometimes prefer to ask this question in different terms and ask how much sales may decrease before the project may be in loss. This exercise is known as a break even point analysis» (p. 238).

  13. 13.

    Other less-known approaches are also proposed for risk analysis. One is that of mathematical programming, already cited as a useful tool for the uncertainty treating. See Mao (1969).

    Further models are derived from financial risks’ evaluation techniques; See, for example, Basile and Erzegovesi (1989), Penati (1991) and Cherubini and Della Lunga (2001). Equally, references arise from studies on the portfolio-decisions theory, due to Markowitz H. M. (March 1952), originally intended for the selection of securities lending, and subsequently employed to generalize real-estate investments. In this matter: Markowitz (1959), Champernowne (1969), Bicksler and Samuelson (1974), Peterson (1974); and Copeland and Weston (1992).

    Interesting reading is the Arrow K. J.’s work (1951), which reviews the economic, philosophical, mathematical and statistical literature on the choice of theme of risky solutions.

    Of great value is S. Reutlinger’s text (1970).

  14. 14.

    It is pleonastic to say that the project’s features arise, at least in part, from those of the reference production sector.

  15. 15.

    Think of a project that employs “mature” technologies or, otherwise, innovative and untried technical solutions. In the latter circumstance, it may be overly simplistic to exclude future variants in some of the dimensions that draw the original structure of the intervention.

  16. 16.

    The rational basis of certain equivalent lies in the concept of risk aversion. See Dallocchio (1995, p. 339).

  17. 17.

    On the topic, see Schlaifer (1969), Allen (1983) and Ingersoll (1987).

  18. 18.

    As it is written in Pivato (1993, p. 934), CAPM’s thesis is that «in a “perfect” financial market and in equilibrium conditions, the yield of each title is equal to the sum of the interest rate and to a “premium” for systematic risk. This increase is much higher as the bond yield itself’ aptitude to fluctuate in harmony with the market is lower. The random risk component, which can be eliminated with a suitable portfolio diversification, does not have any influence on the examined rate».

    And then it is specified: «Risk is divided into two parts: the diversifiable (or non-systematic) component is eliminated by the same operators, with the formation of the optimal market portfolio; the non-diversifiable (or systematic) component is related, instead, to the greater or lesser discrepancies that may occur between the yield fluctuations of the particular bond under consideration, on the one hand, and the optimal portfolio on the other. The equation expressing the model is the following one:

    $$\mu \left( {r_{j} } \right) = i + \beta_{j} \left| {\mu \left( {r_{m} } \right) \, {-}i} \right|,$$

    where μ(r j ) is the expected yield, relative to the price, for the j-th bond; i is the interest rate for risk-free financial assets; μ(r m ) is the expected return of the optimum market portfolio; β j is a coefficient that expresses the magnitude of the expected systematic risk of the title. Precisely, it is:

    $$\beta_{j} = \, Cov \, \left( {r_{j} ,r_{m} } \right) \, /\sigma^{2} \left( {r_{m} } \right)$$

    For a clear discussion on CAPM, see Copeland and Weston (1992, op. cit.), Brealey et al. (2006, op. cit.). See also Lumby (1991), Damodaran (1996a, b), Massari (1998) and Pastorello (2001).

  19. 19.

    According to Ventriglia (2005, pp. 140 and 141), who also takes Sobrero M. under exam (1999), «higher risk premiums are assigned to riskier investment projects, which are characterized by a high degree of uncertainty relative to the magnitude and temporal distribution of the expected cash flows. This approach, however, often leads to excessive distortions, stemming from the fact that the financial flows of an investment are as much penalized by the discount rates, as they are distant from the time of the decision. The use of arbitrarily high and consistent over time risk premium, gives birth to geometric increasing discount rates, while it is almost never true that an investment is characterized by uncertainty having the same dynamics. It is true, however, that for some investments most of the uncertainty extinguishes itself, normally, in the early years of life of the project. As a result, the risk decreases over time. Ultimately, the risk adjustment according to the subjective approach often results in arbitrary increments of discount rates, which grow geometrically, reducing with the same progression the values of the most distant financial flows over time». Among the texts dealing with the theme of the risk premium, see Cornell (1999), Ibbotson et al. (2004).

  20. 20.

    On adjusting the risk discount rate according to the CAPM, see Ventriglia (2005, pp. 140–148).

  21. 21.

    The expected average yield and the yield variance’s concepts are of primary importance for the economic evaluation since, considered jointly, they enable the correct interpretation of the invested capital’s risk.

    In statistical terms, the expected average yield R formula—estimated through the NPV or IRR or other indicator more suited to interpret the analysis results—is expressed as the weighted average of the various yields R s (s = 1, …, n) that the intervention can generate when various scenarios occur, where the weighting factor P s is given by the probabilities associated with each of the n scenarios:

    \(R = \sum\limits_{s = 1}^{n} {P_{s} \cdot R_{s} }\).

    The variance σ2 is the average of the squared of yield deviations R s associated with the initiative related to the average value R:

    \(\sigma^{2} = \sum\limits_{s = 1}^{n} {P_{s} \cdot (R_{s} - R)^{2} }\).

    The square root of the variance is the standard deviation, also known as the root mean square deviation. Although variance and standard deviation give the same information about the returns dispersion around the average, the second has the advantage to return the measure of the risk in the same unit of measure in which the expected or observed values and their average are provided.

  22. 22.

    For a simple reading of the stochastic dominance concept, refer to Dallocchio (1995, op. cit., pp. 320–324). For further information: Goodwin and Wright (2004).

  23. 23.

    It is important to emphasize that the applicability of statistical criteria depends on the availability of objective data and the ability to handle them. On the subject, Dallocchio (1995, pp. 311–312) adds: «Assigning a probability distribution to a project’s outcomes therefore implies a certain degree of subjectivity from the decision maker. In order to reduce the uncertainty characterizing the formulating estimates process, there is often an analysis of the projects’ historical performance that present a risk level similar to the one of the project to evaluate».

    Further reflections can be found in Azzini (1982) and Piccolo and Vitale (1984).

References

  • Allen DE (1983) Finance: a theoretical introduction. Martin Robertson, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Amelotti L, Valcalda B (1998) Il ciclo di vita della gestione dei progetti. Dall’approccio tradizionale all’analisi dei rischi. Guerini e Associati, Milano

    Google Scholar 

  • Arrow KJ (1951) Alternative approaches to the theory of choice in risk-taking situations. In: Econometrica. J Econ Soc 19(4). The University of Chicago

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Azzini L (1982) Istituzioni di Economia d’Azienda. Giuffrè, Milano

    Google Scholar 

  • Basile I, Erzegovesi L (1989) L’analisi del rischio degli investimenti mobiliari. EGEA, Milan

    Google Scholar 

  • Bennion EG (1956) Capital budgeting and game theory. Harvard Bus Rev 34 (reprinted in: Financial decision-making, a cura di Mock E. J., 1967, International Textbook Company, Scranton, Pennsylvania)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bentivegna V (2016) Dialogue and transparency in decision-making. Valori e Valutazioni 17:25–28

    Google Scholar 

  • Beretta S (2004) Valutazione dei rischi e controllo interno. EGEA, Milano

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernoulli D (1730, 1731, 1738) Specimen theoriae novae de mensura sortis. Commentarii academiae scientiarum imperialis Petropolitanae (trans: L. Sommer, Exposition of a new theory on the management of risk, 1954, Econometrica)

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernstein P (2002) Più forti degli dei. La straordinaria storia del rischio. IlSole24Ore, Milano

    Google Scholar 

  • Bicksler JL, Samuelson PA (1974) Investment portfolio decision-making. Lexington Books, Lexington

    Google Scholar 

  • Borel E (1924–34) Traité du calcul de probabilité et ses applications

    Google Scholar 

  • Brealey RA, Myers SC, Allen F, Sandri S (2006) Principi di Finanza aziendale. McGraw-Hill, Milano

    Google Scholar 

  • Brenner M (1983) Option pricing and applications. Lexington Books, Massachusetts

    Google Scholar 

  • Buttignon F (1990) La strategia aziendale e il valore economico del capitale. CEDAM, Padova

    Google Scholar 

  • Carsberg B (1974) Analysis for investment decisions. Accountancy Age, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Champernowne DG (1969) Uncertainty and estimation in economics, vol I, II, III, Oliver & Boyd (Edinburgh) and Holden Day (San Francisco, California)

    Google Scholar 

  • Chandler J, Cockle P (1982) Techniques of scenario planning. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Cherubini U, Della Lunga G (2001) Il rischio finanziario. McGraw-Hill, Milano

    Google Scholar 

  • Chessa F (1929) La teoria economica del rischio e dell’assicurazione, vol I. CEDAM, Padova

    Google Scholar 

  • Copeland TE, Weston JF (1992) Financial theory and corporate policy. Addison-Wesley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Cornell B (1999) The equity risk premium: the long-run future of the stock market. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Culp CL (2001) The risk management process. Business strategy and tactics. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Dallocchio M (1995) Finanza d’azienda. Analisi e valutazioni per le decisioni d’impresa. EGEA, Milano

    Google Scholar 

  • Damodaran A (1996a) Investment valuation. Tools and techniques for determining the value of any asset. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Damodaran A (1996b) Manuale di valutazione finanziaria. McGraw-Hill, Milano

    Google Scholar 

  • De Finetti B (1970) Theory of probability. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Dezzani F (1971) Rischi e politiche d’impresa. Giuffrè, Milano

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit AK, Pindyck RS (1994) Investment under uncertainty. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    Google Scholar 

  • Fermat P, Pascal B (1654) Six letters on the dice game. In: Tannery, Henry (eds) The oeuvres de fermat, vol II, Paris, pp 288–314 (1894)

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher I (1922) La natura del capitale e del reddito. In: Biblioteca degli Economisti—Serie 5a, vol IV. UTET, Torino

    Google Scholar 

  • Gobbi U (1919) Trattato di Economia. Società Editrice Libraria, Milano

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodwin P, Wright G (2004) Decision analysis for management judgment. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Hardy CO (1931) Risk and risk-bearing. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Hertz DB, Thomas H (1983) Risk analysis and its applications. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Hicks JR (1959) Valore e capitale. UTET, Torino

    Google Scholar 

  • Hillier FS, Lieberman GJ (2006) Ricerca operativa. McGraw-Hill, Milano

    Google Scholar 

  • Huygens C (1657) De ratiociniis in ludo aleae, Amsterdam

    Google Scholar 

  • Ibbotson R, Goetzmann W, Kogut B (2004) The equity risk premium: research and practice. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Google Scholar 

  • Ingersoll JE Jr (1987) Theory of financial decision making. Rowman & Littlefield, Totowa

    Google Scholar 

  • Jackel P (2002) Monte Carlo methods in finance. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes JM (1921, 2a ed. 1929) A treatise on probability. MacMillan and Co., New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Keynes JM (1936) The general theory of employment, interest and money. New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight FH (1921) Risk, uncertainty and profit. The London School of Economics and Political Science, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight FH (1960) Rischio, incertezza e profitto, La Nuova Italia, Firenze (Italian translation from: Risk, uncertainty and profit, 1921)

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight FH (1971) Risk, uncertainty and profit. University Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Laplace PS (1814) Essai Philosophique sur les Probabilités. Courcier, Parigi

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Loasby BJ (1990) The use of scenarios in business planning. In: Frowen SF (ed) Unknowledge and choice in economics. MacMillan, Houndmills

    Google Scholar 

  • Luce RD, Raiffa H (1967) Games and decisions: introduction to critical survey. Wiley, New York

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Lumby S (1991) Investment appraisal and financing decisions. Chapman & Hall, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Mao JCT (1969) Quantitative analysis of financial decisions. MacMillan, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Markowitz HM (1952) Portfolio selection. J Finance 7:77

    Google Scholar 

  • Markowitz HM (1959) Portfolio selection: efficient diversification of investments. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Mason F (1992) Metodi quantitativi per le decisioni. Giappichelli, Torino

    Google Scholar 

  • Massari M (1998) Finanza aziendale: valutazione. McGraw-Hill, Milano

    Google Scholar 

  • Massè P (1965) La scelta degli investimenti. Criteri e metodi. ETAS KOMPASS, Milano (Italian translation of Luigi Bianchi and Paola Morbilli)

    Google Scholar 

  • Micalizzi A (1997) Opzioni reali. Logiche e casi di valutazione degli investimenti in contesti di incertezza. EGEA, Milano

    Google Scholar 

  • Mishan EJ (1974) Analisi costi-benefici. ETAS, Milano (Italian translation of Nanni Negro)

    Google Scholar 

  • Morano P, Nesticò A (2006) L’analisi delle serie storiche per la gestione degli aspetti incerti nella stima indiretta del reddito aziendale. Rivista dell’Agenzia del Territorio n.1/2006, Stabilimenti tipografici Carlo Colombo S.p.A., Roma

    Google Scholar 

  • Morano P, Nesticò A (2007) Un’applicazione della programmazione lineare discreta alla definizione dei programmi di investimento. Aestimum n. 50, University Press, Firenze

    Google Scholar 

  • Mowbray AH, Blanchard RH (1961) Insurance. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Orsi R (1985) Probabilità e inferenza statistica. il Mulino, Bologna

    Google Scholar 

  • Panati G, Golinelli GM (1991) Tecnica economica industriale e commerciale. Imprese, strategie e management, vol I, NIS, Roma

    Google Scholar 

  • Pastorello S (2001) Rischio e rendimento. Teoria finanziaria e applicazioni econometriche. il Mulino, Bologna

    Google Scholar 

  • Penati A (ed) (1991) Il rischio azionario e la Borsa. EGEA, Milano

    Google Scholar 

  • Pennisi G, Scandizzo PL (2003) Valutare l’incertezza. L’analisi costi benefici nel XXI secolo. Giappichelli, Torino

    Google Scholar 

  • Penza G (2016) Pope Francis: The Laudato si’ encyclical and the urban issue. Valoro e Valutazioni 17:5–8

    Google Scholar 

  • Peterson DM (1974) Financial ratios and investment results. Lexington Books, USA

    Google Scholar 

  • Piccolo D, Vitale C (1984) Metodi statistici per l’analisi economica. il Mulino, Bologna

    Google Scholar 

  • Pivato G (ed) (1993) Trattato di Finanza aziendale. FrancoAngeli, Milano

    Google Scholar 

  • Pope Francis (2015) On care for our common home. Encyclical Letter Laudato Si’ of the Holy Father Francis. Vatican Press, Rome

    Google Scholar 

  • Reutlinger S (1970) Techniques for project appraisal under uncertainty, World Bank (Staff Paper no. 10). John Hopkins Press, Baltimore

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson PA (1952) Probability, utility and the independence axiom. Econometrica

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Saraceno P (1970) La produzione industriale. Libreria Universitaria, Venezia

    Google Scholar 

  • Sassi S (1940) Il sistema dei rischi d’impresa. Vallardi, Milano

    Google Scholar 

  • Savvides Savvakis C (1994) Risk analysis in investment appraisal. Proj Appraisal J 9(1). Guildford, Surrey

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schlaifer R (1969) Analysis of decision under uncertainty. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Schlosser M (1999) Modelli operativi di Finanza aziendale. Prentice Hall International, Hemel Hempstead—ISEDI, UTET Libreria, Torino

    Google Scholar 

  • Sobrero M (1999) La gestione dell’innovazione. Strategia, organizzazione, tecnica operativa. Carocci, Roma

    Google Scholar 

  • Spencer MH, Siegelman L (1964) Managerial economics. Homewood, Irwin, Illinois

    Google Scholar 

  • Stool HR, Whaley RE (1993) Future and options: theory and applications. South-Western Publishing Co., Cincinnati

    Google Scholar 

  • Trigeorgis L (1995) Real options in capital investment: models, strategies and applications. Praeger, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Ventriglia F (2005) La strategia di innovazione. Opzioni e problematiche valutative. Giappichelli, Torino

    Google Scholar 

  • Von Neumann J, Morgenstern O (1944) Theory of games and economic behavior. Princeton University Press, Princeton

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Vose D (1996) Quantitative risk analysis: a guide to Monte Carlo simulation modelling. Wiley, New York

    MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Zerbe RO Jr, Bellas AS (2006) A primer for benefit-cost analysis. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Antonio Nesticò .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 Springer International Publishing AG, part of Springer Nature

About this paper

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this paper

Nesticò, A. (2018). Risk-Analysis Techniques for the Economic Evaluation of Investment Projects. In: Mondini, G., Fattinnanzi, E., Oppio, A., Bottero, M., Stanghellini, S. (eds) Integrated Evaluation for the Management of Contemporary Cities. SIEV 2016. Green Energy and Technology. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-78271-3_49

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-78271-3_49

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Springer, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-319-78270-6

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-319-78271-3

  • eBook Packages: EnergyEnergy (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics