Skip to main content

Trust, Cooperation, and Conflict: Neuropolitics and International Relations

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Advancing Interdisciplinary Approaches to International Relations

Abstract

Neuroeconomics or the study of brain activity illuminates how choices are made. Kugler and Zak show how oxytocin impacts brain chemistry and levels of trust, with possible implications for decision-making, and, in turn, conflict and cooperation. They offer a challenge to realist theory by questioning its assumptions about a fully Hobbesian world and by incorporating the notion of trust into our thinking and modeling as well. We are misled by the over-emphasis on anarchy at the systemic level to the neglect of sub-systemic variables such as trust and the neuroscience aspects that help shape it. Kugler and Zak argue that willingness to accept international rules that restrict behavior and help avoid conflict depends critically on the level of trust. While they recognize that numerous variables influence cooperation, and that realists certainly do hold out the prospect for cooperation even if that is difficult to achieve, they believe that our understanding of trust is under-developed as is the role of neuroscience in influencing our decisions. Their chapter combines the path-breaking work of Paul Zak in the laboratory with Kugler’s enormous record in international relations.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 89.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Andreoni, J. 1995. Warm-Glow Versus Cold-Prickle: The Effects of Positive and Negative Framing on Cooperation in Experiments. Quarterly Journal of Economics 110(1): 1–21.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod, R. 1984. The Evolution of Cooperation. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barraza, J.A., and P.J. Zak. 2009. Empathy Toward Strangers Triggers Oxytocin Release and Subsequent Generosity. Annals of the New York Academy of Sciences 1167: 182–189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Benson, Michelle A., and Jacek Kugler. 1998. Power Parity, Democracy, and the Severity of Internal Violence. Journal of Conflict Resolution 42(2): 196–209.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berg, J., J. Dickhaut, and K. McCabe. 1995. Trust, Reciprocity, and Social History. Games and Economic Behavior 10: 122–142.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Binmore, K. 1994. Game Theory and the Social Contract. Vol. 1, Playing Fair. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Booth, Ken, and Nicholas Wheeler. 2008. The Security Dilemma, Fear Cooperation and Trust in World Politics. New York: Palgrave.

    Google Scholar 

  • Boudreau, C., M.D. McCubbins, and S. Coulson. 2009. Knowing When to Trust Others: An ERP Study of Decision Making After Receiving Information from Unknown People. Social, Cognitive, and Affective Neuroscience 4(1): 23–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Braithwaite, V., and M. Levi. 2003. Trust and Governance. New York: Russell Sage Foundation Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breslauer, George. 2002. Gorbachev and Yeltsin as Leaders. Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Brodie, B. 1946. The Absolute Weapon. New York: Harcourt Brace.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce. 1983. War Trap. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, and David Lalman. 1992. War and Reason. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Camerer, C.F. 2003. Behavioral Game Theory: Experiments in Strategic Interaction. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carr, E.H. 1964. The Twenty Years’ Crisis, 1919–1939. New York: Harper.

    Google Scholar 

  • Claude, Inis. 1962. Power and International Relations. New York: Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dahl, Robert. 1961. Who Governs? New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eckel, Catherine C. 2008. Gender Differences (Experimental Evidence). In The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics, 2nd edn, ed. Steven N. Durlauf, and Lawrence E. Blume. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fehr, E., and K. Schmidt. 1999. A Theory of Fairness, Competition and Cooperation. Quarterly Journal of Economics 114: 817–868.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fritsch, Stefan. 2011. Technology and Global Affairs. International Studies Perspectives 12(1): 27–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Glaeser, E.L., D.I. Laibson, J.A. Scheinkman, and C.L. Soutter. 2000. Measuring Trust. Quarterly Journal of Economics 115(3): 811–846.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, D.P., and A. Gerber. 2003. The Underprovision of Experiments in Political Science. The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 589: 94–112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Harrison, G., and J. List. 2004. Field Experiments. Journal of Economic Literature XLII: 1013–1059.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harsanyi, J. C., and R. Selten. 1988. A General Theory of Equilibrium Selection in Games. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press Books, 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hobbes, T. 1966. Leviathan. New York: Collier Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoffman, E., K. McCabe, K. Shachat, and V. Smith. 1994. Preferences, Property Rights, and Anonymity in Bargaining Games. Games and Economic Behavior 7(3): 346–380.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hoge, E., M.H. Pollock, R.E. Kaufman, P.J. Zak, and N.M. Simon. 2008. Oxytocin Levels in Social Anxiety Disorder. CNS Neuroscience & Therapeutics 14: 165–170.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kang, K., and J. Kugler. 2012. Nuclear Weapons: Stability of Terror. In Debating a Post-American World: What Lies Ahead? ed. Sean Clark, and Sabrina Hoque. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kang, K., and J. Kugler. 2015. Assessment of Deterrence and Missile Defense in East Asia: A Power Transtion Perspective. International Area Studies Review 18(3): 280–296.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keohane, Robert. 1984. After Hegemony: Cooperation and Discord in the World Political Economy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Keohane, Robert, and Joseph Nye. 1977. Power and Independence: World Politics in Transition. New York: Little Brown and Company.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kersherner, I. 2009. Trial of Former Israeli Leader Begins. New York Times, September 25.

    Google Scholar 

  • King-Casas, B., D. Tomlin, D. Anen, C.F. Camerer, S.R. Quartz, and P.R. Montague. 2005. Getting to Know You: Reputation and Trust in a Two-Person Economic Exchange. Science 308: 78–83.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Knutson, B., and R. Peterson. 2005. Neurally Reconstructing Expected Utility. Games and Economic Behavior 52: 305–331.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kosfeld, M., M. Heinrichs, P.J. Zak, U. Fischbacher, and E. Fehr. 2005. Oxytocin Increases Trust in Humans. Nature 435(2): 673–676.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kramer, R.M., and K.S. Cook. 2007. Trust and Distrust in Organizations: Dilemmas and Approaches. New York: Russell Sage Foundation Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kugler, J., and D. Lemke (ed). 1998. Parity and War. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kugler J., A. Fisunoglu, and B. Yesilada. 2015. Consequences of Reversing the European Union Integration, Foreign Policy Analysis 11(1): 45–67.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kugler, J., and Frank Zagare. 1987. The Long Term Stability of Deterrence. Boulder: Lynn Rienner.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuhnen, C.M., and B. Knutson. 2005. The Neural Basis of Financial Risk-taking. Neuron 47: 763–770.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kydd, Andrew. 2005. Trust and Mistrust in International Relations. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lake, David. 2009. Hierarchy in International Relations. Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lemke, Douglas, and David Cunningham. 2009. Distinction without A differences? Comparing Civil and Interstate Wars. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of American Political Science Association, Toronto.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lippman, Thomas. 1997. Washington Post Foreign Service, March 22, 1

    Google Scholar 

  • Maoz, Zeev. 1984. The Expected Utility of International Conflict: Some Logical Traps and Empirical Surprises in “The War Trap”. Unpublished Paper. Haifa: University of Haifa.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCabe, K., A. Gunnthursdottir, and V. Smith. 2002. Using the Machiavellian Instrument to Predict Trustworthiness in a Bargaining Game. Journal of Economic Psychology 23: 49–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mearsheimer, J. 2001. The Tragedy of the Great Powers. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merolla, J.L., K. Pyle, G. Burnett, J. Barraza, S. Ahmadi, and P.J. Zak. 2013. Oxytocin and the Biological Basis for Interpersonal and Political Trust. Political Behavior 34(4). doi:10.1007/s11109-012-9219-8.

  • Morhenn, V.B., J.W. Park, E. Piper, and P.J. Zak. 2008. Monetary Sacrifice Among Strangers is Mediated by Endogenous Oxytocin Release after Physical Contact. Evolution and Human Behavior 29: 375–383.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Organski, A.F.K. 1958. World Politics. New York: Knopf.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1968. World Politics, 2nd edn. New York: Knopf.

    Google Scholar 

  • Organski, A.F.K., and Jacek Kugler. 1980. The War Ledger. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. 2005. Trust and Reciprocity: Interdisciplinary Lessons for Experimental Research. New York: Russell Sage Foundation Publications.

    Google Scholar 

  • Park, J.W., and P.J. Zak. 2007. Neuroeconomics Studies. Analyse and Kritik 29: 47–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rabin, M. 1993. Incorporating Fairness into Game Theory and Economics. American Economic Review 83: 1281–1302.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rathbun, Brian C. 2012. Trust in International Cooperation: International Security Institutions, Domestic Politics and American Multilateralism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ray, J.L. 2009. Democracy and International Conflict: An Evolution of the Democratic Peace Proposition. Columbus, SC: University of South Carolina Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Russell Hardin (2006) Trust, Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Russett, B., and J. Oneal. 2000. Triangulating Peace: Democracy, Interdependence, and International Organizations. New York: Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sanfey, A.G. 2007. Social Decision-Making: Insights from Game Theory and Neuroscience. Science 318: 598–602.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Seymour, B., T. Singer, and R. Dolan. 2007. The Neurobiology of Punishment. Nature Reviews Neuroscience 8: 300–311.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sirota, Y.B., and A. Das. 2009. Anticipatory Haemodynamic Signals in Sensory Cortex not Predicted by Local Neuronal Activity. Nature 457: 475–479.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, V.L. 1998. The Two Faces of Adam Smith. Southern Economic Journal 65: 1–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, Julianne. 2008. The Nato-Russia Relationship: Defining Moment of Déjà vu? Center for Strategic & International Studies Report. Washington, DC.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sobel, J. 2002. Can We Trust Social Capital? Journal of Economic Literature XL: 139–154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sugrue, L.P., G.S. Corrado, and W.T. Newsome. 2004. Matching Behavior and the Representation of Value in the Parietal Cortex. Science 304: 1782–1787.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tammen, Ronald L., Jacek Kugler, Douglas Lemke, Allan C. Stam III, Mark Abdollahian, Carole Alsharabati, Brian Efird, and A.F.K. Organski. 2000. Power Transitions. Washington, DC: CQ Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tilly, C. 2005. Trust and Rule. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Uslaner, E.M. 2002. The Moral Foundations of Trust. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Vercoe, M., and P.J. Zak. 2010. Inductive Modeling Using Causal Studies in Neuroeconomics: Brains on Drugs. Journal of Economic Methodology 17(2): 123–137.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Vul, E., C. Harris, P. Winkielman, and H. Pashler. 2009. Puzzlingly High Correlations in fMRI Studies of Emotion, Personality, and Social Cognition. Perspectives on Psychological Science 4(3): 274–290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Waltz, Kenneth N. 1979. Theory of International Politics. New York: McGraw-Hill.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1981. The Spread of Nuclear Weapons: More May Be Better. Adelphi Paper #171. London: International Institute for Strategic Studies.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2012. Why Iran Should Get the Bomb: Nuclear Balancing Would Mean Stability. Foreign Affairs (July/Aug.): 91,4: 2–5.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingert, J.D., and A. Weingert. 1985. Trust as a Social Reality, Social Forces, 63(4): 967–985.

    Google Scholar 

  • Werner, Suzanne, and Jacek Kugler. 1996. Power Transitions and Military Buildups: Resolving the Relationship between Arms Buildups and War. In Parity and War, ed. Jacek Kugler, and Douglas Lemke. Ann Arbor: Michigan University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Westen, D., P.S. Blagov, K. Harenski, C. Kilts, and S. Hamann. 2006. Neural Bases of Motivated Reasoning: An fMRI Study of Emotional Constraints on Partisan Political Judgment in the 2004 U.S. Presidential Election. Journal of Cognitive Neuroscience 18(11): 1947–1958.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wheeler, Nicholas. 2014. From Distrust to Trust in Adversarial Relationships. June 10, 2014, securitydilemmas.wordpress.com/2014/06/10

  • Yetiv, Steve. 2011. History, International Relations, and Integrated Approaches: Thinking about Greater Interdisciplinarity. International Studies Perspectives 12: 94–118.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zagare, F., and D. Kilgour. 2000. Perfect Deterrence. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Zak, P.J. 2004. Neuroeconomics. Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B (Biology) 359(1451): 1737–1748.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2005. Trust: A Temporary Human Attachment Facilitated by Oxytocin. Behavioral and Brain Sciences 28(3): 368–369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2008a. Neuroeconomics. In McGraw-Hill Yearbook of Science & Technology, 248–250. New York: McGraw-Hill Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zak, P. J. 2008b. Rational Rationality. Psychology Today Blogs: The Moral Molecule. Accessed April 1, 2011. http://blogs.psychologytoday.com/blog/the-moral-molecule/200810/rational-rationality

  • ———. 2008c. The Neurobiology of Trust. Scientific American (June) 6: 88–95.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zak, P.J. 2011. The Physiology of Moral Sentiments. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 77: 53–65.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2012. The Moral Molecule: The Source of Love and Prosperity. New York: Dutton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zak, P.J., K. Borja, W.T. Matzner, and R. Kurzban. 2005a. The Neuroeconomics of Distrust: Sex Differences in Behavior and Physiology. American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 95(2): 360–363.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zak, P.J., and A. Fakhar. 2006. Neuroactive Hormones and Interpersonal Trust: International Evidence. Economics & Human Biology 4: 412–429.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zak, P.J., and S. Knack. 2001. Trust and Growth. The Economic Journal 111: 295–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zak, P.J., R. Kurzban, S. Ahmadi, R.S. Swerdloff, J.W. Park, L. Efremidze, K. Redwine, K. Morgan, and W. Matzner. 2009a. Testosterone Administration Decreases Generosity in the Ultimatum Game. Public Library of Science ONE 4(12): e8330. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0008330.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zak, P.J., R. Kurzban, and W.T. Matzner. 2004. The Neurobiology of Trust. Annals of the New York. Academy of Sciences 1032: 224–227.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2005b. Oxytocin is Associated with Human Trustworthiness. Hormones and Behavior 48: 522–527.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zak, P.J., R. Kurzban, J.-W. Park, S. Ahmadi, R.S. Swerdloff, L. Efremidze, K. Redwine, K. Morgan, and W. Matzner. 2009b. Testosterone Administration Decreases Generosity in the Ultimatum Game. Public Library of Science ONE 4(12): e8330. doi:10.1371/journal.pone.0008330.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zak, P.J., A.A. Stanton, and S. Ahmadi. 2007. Oxytocin Increases Generosity in Humans. Public Library of Science ONE 2(11): e1128.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Paul J. Zak .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendix 1

Appendix 1

The game-theoretic NMT proposed here is based on macro studies on power dynamics and the studies Zak’s laboratory has done on the role of OT in facilitating trust. The model is presented to show how findings from neuroeconomics studies can be included in an otherwise standard optimizing model. The model is a dyadic interaction that captures the essence of trust—that one party must make a decision first and the other party subsequently reacts to this. Our hope is that social scientists will use this model as a foundation to incorporate trust into models of political decisions particularly in the complex arena of deterrence where formal models affect policies that impact the safety of millions.

Let us begin with some notation. The players are identified as decision maker 1 (DM1) and decision maker 2 (DM2). These can be considered countries or individual political actors. Table A1 lists the variables in the model and their definitions. The DMs in this model are self-interested but also value the ongoing relationship between the parties. Both parties have identical continuous, increasing, and strictly concave utility functions U(). Decisions are made with full information by both DMs, and we abstract from stochasticity in this version of the model. For simplicity and consistent with the parity conditions previously identified in power transition dynamics, assume both parties begin with equal resources (M1 = M2 = M > 0) and have a history of interacting with each other, V(R) > 0 and V(R) finite. The results of the model do not change if these two assumptions are relaxed.

We know from Zak’s studies of OT release discussed above that under conditions of low stress, when DM2 receives a transfer from DM1, OT is released and this induces a desire to reciprocate. The degree of reciprocity scales with the size of the transfer. We will call DM2’s reciprocity function

α(S, E, V) : R + x[0, 1]xR + → [0, 1]

and assume that it is continuous and increasing in S reflecting status quo level in power dynamics and decreasing in E and V. The shared external environment, E, that both DMs experience affects the reciprocity that DM2 will have toward DM1 by affecting stress levels during the interaction. E is negatively affected by stress that can emanate from an international crisis, imminent elections, a shortage of time to make decisions, or other factors that impact decision-making. As discussed above, high stress reduces OT release and therefore DM2 reciprocity. The implications for the understanding of political exchanges, particularly international exchanges that are currently assumed to be unaffected by reciprocity, are, clearly, fundamental.

Variance of what DM1 sends to DM2, V, captures how trusting DM1 has been in previous interactions with DM2. This permits DM2 to “right old wrongs” by reducing returns R if DM1 has been inconsistent in showing trust. This term R captures the notion that trust takes time to build but is easy to break. The effect of the variance on what is sent causes both DMs to indirectly place value on a continuing relationship; since the game is positive sum, win-win solutions exist if α 2(S, E, V) is large enough.

The model is solved backwards. DM2’s decision problem is:

Max K2 , R U(K 2) + α 2(S, E, V) U(R)

s . t . K 2 = M + ηM+

DM2 is self-interested because greater resources K 2 are valued, but at the same time, she/he receives a utility flow U(R) from reciprocating with DM1. This utility occurs even in a one-shot interaction (V = 0) but is reinforced by a continuing relationship.

The necessary and sufficient condition for an optimum is

U (K 2) = α 2(S, E, V) U (R)

This determines DM2’s optimal amount kept, \( {K}_2^{*} \) and amount returned to DM1, R*. It is straightforward to prove that R* is increasing in α 2. In other words, for a fixed environment E, the more resources DM2 receives, the greater his/her reciprocity toward DM1, and the larger the amount returned to DM1. Nevertheless, for E sufficiently high, α 2(S, E, V) = 0 and as a result DM2 uses the self-interested Nash strategy, R* = 0. One can also show that R* is decreasing in the variance, V.

DM1 is also self-interested, gaining utility from total resources she/he keeps K 1 and from what DM2 returns, R. DM1 understands that for a given environment E, sending an amount S to DM2 will have a neurologic effect on him/her. That is, S will induce OT release that will motivate reciprocity by DM2. DM1 also understands the value of consistency, V, in the trust shown to DM2 and knows that inconsistency will reduce DM2’s reciprocity.

DM1’s decision is to solve

Max K1 , S U(K 1 + R)

s . t . K 1 + S = M

R = η = Mδεχ 2

U (K 2) = α 2(S, E, V) U (R)

The optimum is found from the condition

U (K 1 + R)(ηR)(pt 2(S)/dS) = 0,

or

ηr/(dS)2(S)/dS.

This equation reveals that the amount that DM1 sends to DM2, S, depends on the return, η, as well as on how DM2 responds to being shown trust by DM1, K 2(S). The function K 2(S) is positive and decreasing in S (equivalently, R(S) is increasing) so that DM1 expects a return from DM2 unless E is high or there is a fractured history of reciprocity (V high).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2017 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Kugler, J., Zak, P.J. (2017). Trust, Cooperation, and Conflict: Neuropolitics and International Relations. In: Yetiv, S., James, P. (eds) Advancing Interdisciplinary Approaches to International Relations. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-40823-1_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics