Skip to main content

Models of Repression and Inclusion

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
An Economic Analysis of Conflicts
  • 446 Accesses

Abstract

The Collier-Hoeffler model is extended in two ways: first by examining the possibility of altogether avoiding the conflict if mutual concessions are agreed upon, and, second, to include the application of repression and reprisals by the government as deterrence for the guerrillas staging the rebellion. By allowing the fighting effectiveness to differ for the two sides, the effect of other factors such as terrain on the development of guerrilla forces is examined. Combinations of high repression and low inclusion in power sharing seem to be conducive to the onset of a civil war. Moreover, the application in the Greek civil war shows that persecutions tended to inflame the severity of the conflict, rather than suppress it.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

eBook
USD 16.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 109.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    Marx and Engels (1978).

  2. 2.

    For a description, see Rizospastis (2011, p. 292).

  3. 3.

    Second Plenary, February 1946; reprinted in KKE (1964, p. 549).

  4. 4.

    Fifth Plenary, January 1949; reprinted in KKE (1964, p. 577).

  5. 5.

    Sixth Plenary, October 1949; reprinted in KKE (1964, p. 583).

References

  • Balkelis T (2015) War, revolution and terror in the Baltic states and Finland after the Great War. J Baltic Stud 46(1):1–9. doi:10.1080/01629778.2015.1009685

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chirot D, Ragin C (1975) The market, tradition and peasant rebellion: the case of Romania in 1907. Am Sociol Rev 40(4):428–444

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Collier P, Hoeffler A (2004) Greed and grievance in civil war. Oxf Econ Pap 56:563–595. doi:10.1093/oep/gpf064

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Conway M (2012) The sorrows of Belgium: liberation and political reconstruction 1944–1947. Oxford University Press, Oxford

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Grammenos B, Rodakis P (1947) That’s how civil war started: reproduction of “The DAG Report to the UN”. Glaros Editions, Athens (in Greek)

    Google Scholar 

  • Gurr TR (1974) Persistence and change in political systems 1800–1971. Am Polit Sci Rev 68:1482–15047

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hegre H, Ellingsen T, Gates S, Gleditsch NP (2001) Toward a democratic civil peace? democracy, political change, and civil war, 1816–1992. Am Polit Sci Rev 95:33–48

    Google Scholar 

  • Kissane B (2015) After civil war. University of Pennsylvania Press, Philadelphia, PA

    Google Scholar 

  • KKE (1964) Forty years 1918–1958: collection of documents. Communist Party edition, Athens (in Greek)

    Google Scholar 

  • Konstantin S, Schwarz M (2008) A theory of brinkmanship, conflicts, and commitments. J Law Econ Org 24(1):163–183

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx K, Engels F (1978) The communist manifesto. In: Marx K (ed) The revolutions of 1848. Penguin, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Michiotis N (2007) In the name of the king: emergency martial courts in Greece 1946–1960. Synchroni Epochi Editions, Athens (in Greek)

    Google Scholar 

  • Rizospastis (2011) The three-year epic of the Democratic Army of Greece 1946–1949. Synchroni Epochi Editions, Athens (in Greek)

    Google Scholar 

  • Sambanis N (2002) A review of recent advances and future directions in the quantitative literature on civil war. Def Peace Econ 13(3):215–243

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Skaperdas S (2008) An economic approach to analyzing civil wars. Econ Gov 9:25–44. doi:10.1007/s10101-007-0043-2

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • van Boeschoten R (2015) Enemies of the Nation-A nation of enemies: the long Greek civil war. In: Kissane B (ed) After civil war. University of Pennsylvania Press, Philadelphia, PA

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Appendix

Appendix

4.1.1 Proof of Proposition 1

Differentiating (4.3) we get

$$ \frac{\partial {p}_1}{\partial r}=\frac{m_1}{r}\bullet \frac{A_1{A}_2{r}^{m_1}{q}^{m_2}}{{\left[{A}_1{r}^{m_1}+{A}_2{q}^{m_2}\right]}^2}=\frac{m_1}{r}\bullet {p}_1\bullet {p}_2 $$
(4.21a)

Similarly

$$ \frac{\partial {p}_2}{\partial q}=\frac{m_2}{q}\bullet \frac{A_1{A}_2{r}^{m_1}{q}^{m_2}}{{\left[{A}_1{r}^{m_1}+{A}_2{q}^{m_2}\right]}^2}=\frac{m_2}{q}\bullet {p}_1\bullet {p}_2 $$
(4.21b)

Dividing (4.21a, 4.21b) by parts, expression (4.4) is readily obtained.

4.1.2 Proof of Proposition 2

Recalling (4.9a, 4.9b), taking into account (4.3), the concavity of (p j , j = 1,2) and the fact that (L j <V j , j = 1,2) we obtain:

$$ \frac{\partial^2{H}_1}{\partial {r}^2}=\frac{\partial^2{p}_1}{\partial {r}^2}\bullet \left({V}_1-{L}_1\right)<0 $$
(4.22a)

and

$$ \frac{\partial^2{H}_2}{\partial {q}^2}=-\frac{\partial^2{p}_2}{\partial {q}^2}\bullet \left({V}_2-{L}_2\right)>0 $$
(4.22b)

4.1.3 Proof of Proposition 3

The first-order condition for maximizing 1 ) as in (4.6a) yields that guerrillas should mobilize an army of a size such that it satisfies

$$ {w}_1=\left({V}_1-{L}_1\right)\bullet \frac{\partial {p}_1}{\partial r} $$
(4.23a)

Substituting from (4.21a) it gives that

$$ {w}_1r={m}_1\bullet \left({V}_1-{L}_1\right)\bullet {p}_1\bullet \left(1-{p}_1\right) $$
(4.23b)

The maximum payoff becomes

$$ {\varPi}_{1 max}=\left({V}_1-{L}_1\right)\bullet \left[{m}_1{p}_1^2+\left(1-{m}_1\right){p}_1-\frac{D-{L}_1}{V_1-{L}_1}\right] $$
(4.24)

For a repression strong enough so that D>L 1, the second-order expression within the square brackets has only one positive root, say π 1 >0. In terms of model parameters it becomes:

$$ {\pi}_1=-\frac{1-{m}_1}{2{m}_1}+\frac{1}{2{m}_1}\bullet {\left\{{\left(1-{m}_1\right)}^2+4\frac{D-{L}_1}{V_1-{L}_1}\right\}}^{\raisebox{1ex}{$1$}\!\left/ \!\raisebox{-1ex}{$2$}\right.} $$
(4.25)

For the maximum payoff to be positive, and thus entering the conflict to be meaningful, it requires that p 1 1. Given that probability p 1 is increasing in (r), this condition is translated into an army threshold of r>r MIN . The threshold in (4.15) is calculated in terms of model parameters from the inverse conflict success function:

$$ {r}_{MIN}=inv\;{p}_1\left[{\pi}_1\right] $$
(4.26)

Similarly the government’s maximum payoff is obtained as

$$ {\varPi}_{2 max}=\left({V}_2-{L}_2\right)\bullet \left[{m}_2{p}_2^2+\left(1-{m}_2\right){p}_2+\frac{L_2}{V_2-{L}_2}\right] $$
(4.27)

This remains always positive; therefore, no threshold for the state army applies.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2016 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Christodoulakis, N. (2016). Models of Repression and Inclusion. In: An Economic Analysis of Conflicts. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-32261-2_4

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics