Skip to main content

Two Historical Examples of Deflation

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
In Defense of Deflation

Part of the book series: Financial and Monetary Policy Studies ((FMPS,volume 41))

  • 1058 Accesses

Abstract

Completing the theoretical analysis of deflation, I will now be able to apply the theoretical knowledge in interpreting historical cases of deflation. With knowledge of the possible causes and consequences of deflation, the interpretation of these historical facts should shed new light on the historical examples. Therefore, these examples will serve to illustrate the theoretical points made in the above analysis. Two cases will be discussed: the price deflation in the United States from 1865 to 1896 and the price deflation in Germany during the Great Depression. These cases have been selected for mainly two main reasons. First, they serve as a practical demonstration of the majority of the above analyzed types of deflation. Second, these examples are particularly illustrative. The American deflation is one of the longest in history. The German deflation is one of the sharpest during the Great Depression, which is itself of great interest for the economic historians and source of important misinterpretations.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 89.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 119.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    A very popular argument against a 100 % gold standard is that such a system would hamper economic growth. When the supply of gold could not keep up with economic growth, prices would fall and lead to a recession. It is one of the most widespread myths among economists that the money supply must rise as fast as productivity to prevent price deflation. The American growth deflation illustrates that this argument is simply a myth.

  2. 2.

    For a short summary of the greenback era see Studenski and Kroos (1963, p. 143–146) or Rothbard (2002, p. 123–159).

  3. 3.

    See Rothbard (2002, p. 123).

  4. 4.

    See Studenski and Kroos (1963, p. 143).

  5. 5.

    The name “greenback” resulted from its printing, which was black on the front and green on the back. The name also refers to the backing of these notes by essentially green paper, in contrast to previous notes that were backed by gold.

  6. 6.

    See Mitchell (1903. p. 143).

  7. 7.

    See Shields (1977, p. 115).

  8. 8.

    See Studenski and Kroos (1963, p. 147)

  9. 9.

    See Studenski and Kroos (1963, p. 148)

  10. 10.

    See Studenski and Kroos (1963, pp. 154–155).

  11. 11.

    State banks were only allowed to do business in the borders of the state that chartered them.

  12. 12.

    Vera Smith calls this system a “bond deposit system,” because in order to issue notes government bonds had to be issued (1990, p. 52).

  13. 13.

    See Smith (1990, p. 149).

  14. 14.

    See on this Rothbard (2002, pp. 151–152).

  15. 15.

    See Rothbard (2002, p. 154).

  16. 16.

    See on the Resumption Act, Dewey (1907, pp. 372–274).

  17. 17.

    See Barrett (1931, p. 186).

  18. 18.

    See Rothbard (2002, p. 157).

  19. 19.

    See Rothbard (2002, p. 160).

  20. 20.

    See Smith (1990, p. 151).

  21. 21.

    Source: U.S. Department of Commerce, 1975, Series E 52–63, p. 201.

  22. 22.

    See U.S. Department of Commerce, 1975, Series E 87–89, p. 203.

  23. 23.

    See U.S. Department of Commerce, 1975, Series E 174–182, p. 212.

  24. 24.

    See Friedman and Schwartz (1971, p. 33).

  25. 25.

    See U.S. Department of Commerce (1875, p. 212).

  26. 26.

    See U.S. Department of Commerce (1875), Series F 1–5, p. 224.

  27. 27.

    Currency includes gold coins, gold and silver certificates, U.S. notes, currency notes, treasury notes of 1890, standard silver dollars, subsidiary silver, fractional currency, other U.S. currency, state bank notes, national banknotes, minor coin, federal reserve notes and federal reserve bank notes.

  28. 28.

    These figures are in million dollar. Source: Friedman and Schwartz (1971, pp. 704–705), Table A-1.

  29. 29.

    It must be noted that these numbers cannot be taken at face value. 17 % presents an accuracy that is unrealistic. However, it is safe to state that there was an increase in the money supply over this period between 10 and 30 %.

  30. 30.

    See Friedman and Schwartz (1971, pp. 77–78).

  31. 31.

    See Friedman and Schwartz (1971, pp. 106–107).

  32. 32.

    See Friedman and Schwartz (1971, pp. 108–111).

  33. 33.

    Austria would follow in 1892 and Russia and Japan in 1897.

  34. 34.

    See Palyi (1972, p. 22), fn 19.

  35. 35.

    See on the quality of money Anderson ([1917] 2000) and Bagus (2009).

  36. 36.

    See U.S. Department of Commerce (1975), Series F 1–5, p. 224.

  37. 37.

    The purchasing power of wages increased from 32 (1910–1914 = 100) in 1865 to 104 in 1896. See Warren and Pearson (1933, p.197).

  38. 38.

    See Warren and Pearson (1933, p. 44), Table 5.

  39. 39.

    See U.S. Department of Commerce (1875, pp. 231–300, 689–697).

  40. 40.

    See US Department of Commerce, 1975, W 96–106, pp. 957–959.

  41. 41.

    See Faulkner (1924, pp. 426–428).

  42. 42.

    See Shields (1977, pp. 241–242)

  43. 43.

    See Laughlin (1887, pp. 336–338).

  44. 44.

    See on the industrial concentration Davis et al. (1965), p. 368. See also Shields (1977, p. 12). The possibility of economies of scale is implied in Mises’ Law of Returns (1998, pp. 127–130).

  45. 45.

    Source: US Department of Commerce, 1975, Series A 6–8, p. 8.

  46. 46.

    See US Department of Commerce, 1975, Series C 89–119, pp. 105–106. Of course by counting every immigrant these data are pretending an accuracy which is absurd.

  47. 47.

    See US Department of Commerce, 1975, Series C 138–142, p. 112. For the increase in the work force see US Department of Commerce, 1975, Series D 67–181, p. 189.

  48. 48.

    See US Department of Commerce, 1975, Series U 1–25, pp. 864–865.

  49. 49.

    See Kuznets (1961, p. 64).

  50. 50.

    See Kuznets (1961, p. 65).

  51. 51.

    See Kuznets (1961, p. 92).

  52. 52.

    See US Department of Commerce, 1975, Series Q 321–328, p. 731.

  53. 53.

    See US Department of Commerce, 1975, Series Q 329, p. 732.

  54. 54.

    Thus, the Austrian economist Patrick Newman (2012) argues that there was no depression between 1873 and 1879. He maintains that falling prices were the reason for the misinterpretation of the period. Also new institutionalists seem to come to a largely positive assessment of the period similar to the Austrians. Douglass C. North states: “In the era between the Civil War and World War I, we emerged as the greatest industrial nation in the world, without at the same time forfeiting our preeminence as a world supplier of raw materials and foodstuffs… [the] United States industrial development was spectacular during this period…” (1961, p. 195) Even though North speaks of a longer period than we are considering he makes a very positive statement on it. Thus, it would seem strange to argue that he thinks that in this period a “Great Depression” occurred. Moreover, North mentions the falling prices and does not make them responsible for disruptions but on the contrary sees them as the result of economic growth: “Up until 1896 the international price level fell, reflecting the fact that output was increasing at a more rapid rate than the money supply, but after that date the reverse was true.” (1961, p. 201)

  55. 55.

    See also as positive accounts of the period in the works of Dickey (1977) and Shields (1977) that belong to this first group. Those authors that are not Austrian economists but more in the monetarist tradition. Another case is Coppock (1961). His paper has the title “The Causes of the Great Depression, 1873–1896,” however, he argues that only the trend rate of growth was reduced in this period (p. 216). Interesting is also that Friedman and Schwartz themselves note that the price fall might have misled economists about the severity and length of the recession of the 1870s: “But the sharp decline in financial magnitude, so much more obvious and so much better documented than the behavior of a host of poorly measured physical magnitude, may well have led contemporary observers and later students to overestimate the severity of the contraction and perhaps even its lengths.” (1971, pp. 87–88)

  56. 56.

    See also Fels (1951, p. 325).

  57. 57.

    Achinstein (1961, p. 166, 170)

  58. 58.

    See Rezneck (1950), (1953), and (1956).

  59. 59.

    In Britain the people living at the time and later academics regarded conditions as bad despite the fact that the “average consumer appears to have been considerably better off at the end of the ‘depression’ than before” (Selgin 1997, p. 50). Selgin (1997, pp. 51–52) declares it, thus, as a myth that there was a depression in Britain between 1873 and 1896. He makes out four causes for the myth that can also be found for the case of the U.S. First, some sectors of the economy were depressed indeed, like in the U.S. agriculture. Second, there were cyclical upturns and downturns. Third, there existed wrong theories, namely that falling prices would disturb production. Those theories existed also in the U.S. Fourth, sympathy for negatively affected groups. In the U.S. such a group would be farmers. See on this myth also Musson (1959).

  60. 60.

    See Davis (2006, p. 106). Davis criticizes the NBER chronology. He uses his own data set, consisting of 43 annual components in the manufacturing and mining industries. He reduces the number of recessionary years in the period from 1865 to 1896 to seven eliminating three recessions completely. Davis argues convincingly that the persistent price deflation in the period made Willard Thorp (1926) in his Business Annals (on which NBER data, for example Wesley Mitchell’s work (1927) is based) overestimate the duration and number of recessions (Davis 2006, p. 113). I regard Davis’ data stemming from enterprises located in higher stages of production more adequate than GDP numbers to identify historical economic cycles because cycle movements are more pronounced in the higher stages of production.

  61. 61.

    See Kuznets (1961, p. 72). According to Rothbard (2002, p. 64), per capita income (in 1958 dollars) increased from $531 in the decade average 1869–1878 to $795 in the decade average 1889–1898, an increase of almost 50 %!

  62. 62.

    See Siegel (1998, p. 8).

  63. 63.

    Olson, (1971, p. 132) explains that the free rider problem can be overcome in large groups if they offer as a “by-product” services from which non-members can be excluded.

  64. 64.

    Friedman and Schwartz state that there is the “now [!] widely held view that secular price deflation and rapid economic growth are incompatible” (1971, p. 15). With the “now” it is suggested that this belief was not always so widespread.

  65. 65.

    See Friedman and Schwartz (1971, p. 45).

  66. 66.

    Taussig 1892, p. 90 states that farmers and railroads were mostly hurt by an increase in their long-term debt burden.

  67. 67.

    For the Panic of 1873 see Dewey (1907, pp. 370–372). Fels (1959), claims that railroads had overestimated the amount of capital available.

  68. 68.

    See Unger (1964, pp. 220–221).

  69. 69.

    See Unger (1964, p. 49).

  70. 70.

    Cincinnati Enquirer, Aug. 17, 1867, quoted in Unger (1964, p. 46).

  71. 71.

    See Unger (1964, pp. 46–47).

  72. 72.

    See Unger (1964, p. 47).

  73. 73.

    See Unger (1964, p. 45).

  74. 74.

    See Unger (1962, pp. 59–62). It should be added again that not all business men were opposed to resumption (Unger 1962, p. 69). Textile exporters were in favor while iron masters and business men with western interests were opposed.

  75. 75.

    See Friedman and Schwartz (1971, p. 47). See also Unger (1964, p. 222), for the ironmasters and railroads asking for inflation.

  76. 76.

    Often mortgages would not be renewed in the wake of the Panic of 1873. See Shannon (1957, p. 55).

  77. 77.

    See for the support of farmers for the greenback movement in the 1870s, Shannon (1957, p. 57).

  78. 78.

    See Shannon (1957, p. 59).

  79. 79.

    Hugh Rockoff (1990) argues that the children’s book “The Wizard of Oz” is a monetary allegory about the free silver movement.

  80. 80.

    For the reasons for the fall in the price of silver see Laughlin (1968, pp. 109–206). The ratio of production of silver to production of gold increased from 6.0 in 1861–1865 to 12.5 in 1871–1875, the period of demonetization of silver. The ratio kept increase to its peak in 1890 of 23.4. See Warren and Pearson (1933, p. 145), Table 26.

  81. 81.

    See Friedman (1990, pp. 1174–1175) for an hypothetical estimation of prices under free silver coinage.

  82. 82.

    See Weinstein (1970, p. 6). Shannon states: “Indebted farmers were quick to pick up the chorus of the mine owners” (1957, p. 59). For an overview on the different argument reflecting the different interests also offered for free coinage of silver see Robert F. Hoxie: “(1) A lack of confidence and business enterprise. (2) A low range of prices. (3) Increasing indebtedness. (4) The depression of our great silver mining industry.” (1893, p. 546)

  83. 83.

    See Shannon (1945, p. 314). See also Friedman and Schwartz (1971, p. 48, 115) on debtor farmers in the Middle West and South allying with the Greenback Party.

  84. 84.

    See on this alliance Dewey (1907, p. 406).

  85. 85.

    (Weinstein 1970, p. 293). Weinstein adds that the south was only giving passive support.

  86. 86.

    See Unger (1964, p. 335).

  87. 87.

    See Weinstein (1970, p. 125).

  88. 88.

    See Weinstein (1970, p. 128).

  89. 89.

    See Cong. Record, 45th Cong. 2D see., vol. 7, pt. 2, p. 1,061, Feb. 15, 1878, quoted in Weinstein (1970, p. 302).

  90. 90.

    See Unger (1964, p. 330).

  91. 91.

    For John Percival Jones, see Weinstein (1970, pp. 53–81).

  92. 92.

    See Jones, Resumption and the Double Standard, pp. 92–93, quoted in Weinstein (1970, p. 99).

  93. 93.

    See Friedman and Schwartz (1971, p. 115), fn. 40.

  94. 94.

    Concerning this point, see Hülsmann (2004, p. 40).

  95. 95.

    Fekete argues that gold coins won out in a free market setting and pushed silver out of the market. Advances in metallurgy made it possible to mint small gold coins also (1996, p. 12–13). In fact, the two reasons together, the demonetization of silver and the new technologies might be responsible for the triumph of gold.

  96. 96.

    See Hülsmann (2004, p. 38–39).

  97. 97.

    See Dewey (1907, p. 460).

  98. 98.

    See Goodwyn (1978, p. 239).

  99. 99.

    A silver dollar containing 371.25 grains of fine silver. See Friedman and Schwartz (1971, p. 113).

  100. 100.

    See Friedman and Schwartz (1971, p. 116). Faulkner states about the farmer: “He felt strongly that eastern capital was benefiting from his misfortune” (1924, p. 424). Also Shannons states that Eastern investors kept providing for the mortgages (1945, p. 306). See also Goodwyn who states that the bondholders and the Eastern financial community were almost identical (1978, p. 11).

  101. 101.

    The Populists in addition demanded the end of the national banking system. See Nugent (1968, p. 106).

  102. 102.

    See Shields (1977, p. 201).

  103. 103.

    See Folsom (2003, p. 18).

  104. 104.

    See Faulkner (1924, p. 456).

  105. 105.

    See Shannon (1945, p. 173).

  106. 106.

    See Shannon (1957, p. 48).

  107. 107.

    See Shannon (1945, p. 189). See also Ritter (1997, pp. 196–198), for the farm debt problem and the Eastern mortgage companies.

  108. 108.

    See Shannon (1945, p. 189).

  109. 109.

    See Elliot (1890, pp. 36–52).

  110. 110.

    See Faulkner (1924, p. 424).

  111. 111.

    See Stock (1996, p. 65). According to Mancur Olson’s group theory it is easier to organize a group when services like the educational services can be withheld from non-members. Thus, even large groups can organize and as a additional service start lobbying for the interests of the group as a “by product”. See Olson (1971, p. 132).

  112. 112.

    See Faulkner (1924, p. 424). Also Shannon (1957, pp. 51–52).

  113. 113.

    See Unger (1964, pp. 201–202).

  114. 114.

    See Elliot (1890. pp. 175–186). Shannon (1945, p. 349) states that the changes in the industrial structure challenged the old supremacy of agriculture.

  115. 115.

    See US Department of Commerce, 1975, Series F 250-261, p. 240.

  116. 116.

    Shannon (1957, p. 50); Shannon’s statement has to be qualified in one point. Namely, the necessities of farmers fell also in price. Actually, as U.S. Department of Commerce (1975), Series E 52–63, p. 201, indicates that farm prices did not fall faster than other commodity prices. See on this point also Bemis (1893, p. 208).

  117. 117.

    US Department of Commerce, 1975, Series F 125–129, p. 232.

  118. 118.

    US Department of Commerce, 1975, Series F 216–225, p. 238. Emerick writes that the rural wealth fall from 49 % in 1860 to 25 % in 1890 while urban wealth increased from 51 % to 75 % (1896, p. 493).

  119. 119.

    US Department of Commerce, 1975, Series F 250–261, p. 240.

  120. 120.

    See Unger (1964, p. 202). Shannon states that farmers felt a “lack of parity with other economic groups.” (1957, p. 49)

  121. 121.

    See Rothbard (2002, p. 166). Also Shields states “that income in agriculture in real terms increased at a relatively rapid rate during these years of falling prices, and farm unrest, although not as rapidly as economy-wide income” (1977, p. 219). See also on the absolute increase in farmers’ wealth Emerick (1897, p. 109).

  122. 122.

    However, these theories are not completely new. Rather old theories were used to make the argument that seemed to fit one’s course. The old idea that the amount of money could be insufficient was vindicated by making the quantity theory of money popular. The declining prices thereby indirectly helped the quantity theory to its popularity. As McClean Hardy indicates: “The Quantitäts-Theorie is not a new one, but several circumstances have combined recently to give to it exceptional prominence. In the first place, it forms the basis of the demand for the free coinage of silver: There is not enough silver in the country to supply the needs of business and trade; it is impossible for one metal alone to fulfill all the demands made upon it; and since prosperity can neither be restored nor maintained while there is a scarcity of the circulating medium, silver must be remonetized, if low prices and consequent hard times are not to continue” [Italics in the original] (1895, pp. 145–146). It is also interesting to see the undifferentiated reasoning that equates low prices with hard times as it happens in this quote, not taking into account that price differentials are the relevant factor for the entrepreneur.

  123. 123.

    See Unger (1964, pp. 50–60) or Nugent (1967, pp. 61–63) for information on Carey.

  124. 124.

    It happens that the co-founder of the University and agriculture enthusiast Ezra Cornell entered the railroad business, getting into trouble during the Panic (and credit contraction) of 1873. The anti-deflation stand of Cornell University personell would last longer. Later in the 1930s George F. Warren and Frank A. Pearson from Cornell University would attack deflation, complaining about the injustice it allegedly does to the traditionally long-term indebted farmers (1983, p. 274, 431). Palyi named them “agricultural economists.” (1972, p. 281)

    In the midst of the controversy about his monetary stand in the summer of 1897, Andrews had also accepted the offer received from John Brisben Walker, editor of Cosmopolitan Magazine to take part in his proposed “Cosmopolitan University.” This project was never realized. Walker, who was an automobile and railroad entrepreneur and owner of 1,600 acres in North Denver, was apparently more sympathetic with the monetary views of Andrews. All this is not to say that Andrews became corrupted in his monetary opinion. But it indicates that there were naturally forming alliances between interest groups gaining from a reversal in the price fall and economists that provided theories that seemed to support those interests.

  125. 125.

    One of the most widespread monetary fallacies is that economic growth is only possible if accompanied by a growth of the money supply.

  126. 126.

    See Born (1967, p. 34).

  127. 127.

    See Aldcroft (1978, pp. 36–37) and Bartsch and Eismann (2005, pp. 11–12) for the Treaty of Versailles.

  128. 128.

    Borchardt (1979, p. 121), fn. 43 points out that many people regarded the reparations as the cause of the depression. Thus, the real causes were not seen.

  129. 129.

    See Anderson (1979, pp. 61–69).

  130. 130.

    See Rallo (2006, p. 11).

  131. 131.

    See Rallo (2006, p. 12).

  132. 132.

    See Anderson (1979, pp. 144–150) for the extent of U.S. credit expansion 1922–1928.

  133. 133.

    For accounts on the German hyperinflation see Bresciani-Turroni (2007) or Ferguson (2010).

  134. 134.

    Concerning the Dawes Plan, see Anderson (1979, pp. 115–121); Stucken (1953, pp. 61–76) and Palyi (1972, pp. 160–169). See in general on German post-war monetary history Ahamed (2009).

  135. 135.

    The U.S. wanted the Mark 100 % backed by gold but the British, French and Italian did not want Germany to have a 100 % gold standard while their own redemption was still suspended. Furthermore, Great Britain wanted a sterling-based gold exchange standard. See Rallo (2006, p. 14).

  136. 136.

    See Rallo (2006, p. 28).

  137. 137.

    See Palyi (1972, p. 177).

  138. 138.

    See Schumpeter (1929, p. 849).

  139. 139.

    See Stucken (1953, p. 75) and Palyi 1972, p. 174.

  140. 140.

    See Palyi (1972, p. 162).

  141. 141.

    See Palyi (1972, pp. 46–47).

  142. 142.

    It does not matter whether they were government loans or commercial bank loans. Also the government loans were financed in the end via the expansionary banking system.

  143. 143.

    See also Stucken (1953, p. 70).

  144. 144.

    See Keiser and Benning (1931, p. 154).

  145. 145.

    See Born (1967, p. 19).

  146. 146.

    See Palyi (1972, pp. 206–207).

  147. 147.

    See Palyi (1972, p. 229).

  148. 148.

    Source: Deutsche Bundesbank (1976, p. 4).

  149. 149.

    Source: Deutsche Bundesbank (1976, p. 4).

  150. 150.

    See Palyi (1972, p. 200).

  151. 151.

    See Stucken (1953, p. 76).

  152. 152.

    See Aldcroft (1978, p. 240).

  153. 153.

    See Nussbaum (1978, pp. 270–271).

  154. 154.

    See Anderson (1979, p. 205).

  155. 155.

    See Bartsch and Eismann (2005, p. 14).

  156. 156.

    See Palyi (1972, p. 166).

  157. 157.

    See Palyi (1972, p. 167).

  158. 158.

    See Deutsche Bundesbank (1976, p. 7).

  159. 159.

    See Palyi (1972, p. 219).

  160. 160.

    See Palyi (1972, p. 223).

  161. 161.

    See Palyi (1972, pp. 220–228).

  162. 162.

    See Stucken (1953, p. 79).

  163. 163.

    See Palyi (1972, p. 254, 259).

  164. 164.

    See Born (1967, p. 14, 20).

  165. 165.

    See Stucken (1953, p. 82).

  166. 166.

    See Borchardt (1979, p. 91).

  167. 167.

    See Born (1967, p. 65); It is often maintained, that the Credit-Anstalt became insolvent due to another problem. In the spring of 1931 the plan of a German-Austrian customs union aroused the suspicion of the French that Germany tried to circumvent the prohibition of an “Anschluss” by the Versailles Treaty. The French government threatened consequences were the plan to be put through. Then, it is often stated, French banks withdrew short-term capital from Germany and Austria, with other foreign banks following suit. Karl E. Born, however, shows that until April 1931, Austria enjoyed an influx of foreign exchanges. Thus, the collapse of the Credit-Anstalt was not politically caused but rather caused by the economic losses the bank suffered. Charles Kindleberger shares Born’s assessment (1987, p. 146).

  168. 168.

    See Palyi (1972, p. 252).

  169. 169.

    See Born (1967, p. 65).

  170. 170.

    See Born (1967, p. 71).

  171. 171.

    See Born (1967, p. 67). See Nussbaum (1978, pp. 324–325) for the corporations and companies that went bankrupt.

  172. 172.

    See League of Nations (1935, p. 41). In 1932, the net loss would fall to 3 billion Reichsmarks.

  173. 173.

    See Stucken (1953, p. 85).

  174. 174.

    Concerning “hoarding,” see Born (1967, p. 108, 114–115).

  175. 175.

    See Borchardt (1979, p. 92).

  176. 176.

    See Nussbaum (1978, p. 318) and Born (1967, p. 108).

  177. 177.

    See Anderson (1979, p. 241) and Stucken (1953, p. 83).

  178. 178.

    1936 = 100. Source: Deutsche Bundesbank (1976, p. 7).

  179. 179.

    Chart 10: 1913 = 100 and Chart 11: 1913/14 = 100. Source: Deutsche Bundesbank (1976, p. 7).

  180. 180.

    See for instance, Patch for the bail out of the Danatbank (1998, pp. 174–175); or Nussbaum for the bail out of the Dresdner Bank (1978, p. 318).

  181. 181.

    See Patch (1998, p. 176).

  182. 182.

    See Palyi (1972, pp. 254–256).

  183. 183.

    See Born (1967, pp. 141–149). See on the standstill agreement also Lüke (1958, pp. 328–333).

  184. 184.

    See Palyi (1972, p. 168).

  185. 185.

    See Borchardt (1979, p. 99).

  186. 186.

    See Patch (1998, p. 182).

  187. 187.

    See Nussbaum (1978, p. 295).

  188. 188.

    See Stucken (1953, pp. 90–91) and Nussbaum (1978, p. 305).

  189. 189.

    (Stolper 1966, p. 136). The original text is as follows: “Ziel der Deflationspolitik war es, die politischen Preise auf den Stand herabzudrücken, den sie in einem anpassungsfähigen System von selbst eingenommen hätten”.

  190. 190.

    See Wagenführ (1933, p. 42). Born states that the Great Depression was harshest in Germany and the U.S. (1967, p. 34).

  191. 191.

    Gross social product is an insufficient measure of economic activity. It would be better to have a gross measure of production including all stages of production. Nevertheless, the gross social product can indicate the trend of a depression.

  192. 192.

    1925 = 100. Source: Statistisches Bundesamt (1972, p. 260).

  193. 193.

    See Hülsmann (2013, p. 104).

  194. 194.

    1928 = 100. Source: Deutsche Bundesbank (1976, p. 7).

  195. 195.

    See Borchardt (1979, p. 107).

  196. 196.

    See Stucken (1953, p. 74). See also Schumpeter (1929) for the effects of the excessively high wages.

  197. 197.

    See Mises (1931, p. 21).

  198. 198.

    See Borchardt (1979, p. 104).

  199. 199.

    See Wagemann (1935, p. 16).

  200. 200.

    Mises (1978, p. 185); The original text is as follows: “Es ist nicht zu verkennen, daß die Unrentabilität vieler Produktionszweige und die Arbeitslosigkeit eines nicht unbeträchtlichen Teiles der Arbeitnehmer nicht nur Folge des Abstieges der Konjunktur ist. Unrentabilität und Arbeitslosigkeit werden im Augenblick durch die allgemeine Depression verstärkt, sie sind aber in der Nachkriegszeit zu dauernden Erscheinungen geworden, die auch im Aufschwung nicht ganz verschwunden sind.” (1931, pp. 14–15)

  201. 201.

    See DWI-Forschungshefte, Nr. 3/1968, p. 10 quoted in Nussbaum (1978, p. 166).

  202. 202.

    See Mises (1931, p. 27).

  203. 203.

    See Mises (1931, p. 18).

  204. 204.

    Schacht (1931, p. 181, 184); The original text is as follows: “Der größte Fehler dieses ganzen Systems liegt auf der Hand, es ersetzt die Verantwortung des einzelnen Individuums durch eine angebliche Kollektivverantwortung …. Das Gefühl der Arbeitspflicht und der Antrieb zur Selbsthilfe aus eigener Kraft, kurz das, was ein Volk groß macht und was in jedem gesunden Menschen drin steckt, wird durch die Überspannung und den Mißbrauch der Sozialversicherung getötet: der Wille zum Sparen wird geschwächt, die Neigung zum verschwenderischen Konsum gesteigert.”

  205. 205.

    See Palyi (1972, p. 166).

  206. 206.

    See Borchardt (1979, p. 106).

  207. 207.

    The decade of the 1920s was already a very protectionist phase. Christoph Buchheim sees the “lack of a liberal trade system” as the root for the problems (2002, p. 113).

  208. 208.

    See League of Nations (1935, p. 92).

  209. 209.

    See Stucken (1953, p. 93).

  210. 210.

    See Stucken (1953, p. 94).

  211. 211.

    Another possibility would be to use accumulated gold balances to pay for imports. But this possibility is limited by gold balances and cannot go on forever.

  212. 212.

    Concerning the Hawley-Smoot Tariff, see Anderson (1979, p. 229). The tariff probably caused the stock exchange crash of 1929 (James 2002, p. xi).

  213. 213.

    See Stucken (1953, p. 89).

  214. 214.

    See Mises (1931, p. 21).

  215. 215.

    See Anderson (1979, p. 230).

  216. 216.

    In billion RM. Source: Deutsche Bundesbank (1976, p. 7).

  217. 217.

    See Borchardt (1979, p. 88) for a critique of traditional interpretations and Korsch (1981) for a traditional interpretation of the German depression. Friedman and Schwartz (1971) criticise the failure of central banks and especially the Federal Reserve to inflate the money supply. Aldcroft (1978, pp. 229–331) agrees stating that the restrictive monetary policies of the Federal Reserve were responsible for the severity of the crisis.

  218. 218.

    See, for instance, the Keynesian interpretation by Korsch (1981, p. 16).

  219. 219.

    In fact, Keynes himself recommended both monetary expansion and expansionary fiscal policy to get out of the depression. See Skidelsky (2002, p. 99).

  220. 220.

    Keynesian economist Andreas Korsch, in his discussion of the economic policies during the German depression, argues that it would be the task of the government to engage in expansionary monetary policies when credits are restricted (1981, p. 35). Also Kindleberger states that the Reichsbank should have acted as lender of last resort and bailed out the Danatbank (1987, pp. 294–295).

  221. 221.

    See Bombach (1976); Gottfried Bombach writes: “Man ist sich einig in Brünings Versagen.” (1976, p. 6) [Translation: There is unanimity about Brüning’s failure.] Korsch writes that it would be known that the economic policies of Brüning made the depression more severe (1981, p. 13). Werner Jochmann claims that the effects of the deflationary policies were ravaging (1978, p. 111). Kindleberger writes: “The deflationary policy was followed for two fateful years, though its inadequacy should have been immediately clear” (1987, pp. 131–132), adding that “the verdict is unanimous that Brüning failed” (p. 174).

  222. 222.

    Concerning the Borchard-Controversy, see Borchardt (1979 and 1982, pp. 165–224) or Bartsch and Eismann (2005).

  223. 223.

    See Borchardt (1979).

  224. 224.

    See Borchardt (1979, p. 99). There were two chancelor’s in between Brüning and Hitler. Franz von Papen and Kurt von Schleicher did not change economic policies drastically. Franz von Papen, though, after July 1932, introduced some measure for credit expansion. See Nussbaum (1978, p. 375). He introduced a small public works program and a Steuergutschein program. The Steuergutscheine were tax deductibles for future tax payments and were given when taxes were paid. They were anticipating a reduction of future tax revenues. Kurt von Schleicher introduced another small public work program.

  225. 225.

    See Mises (1931), for this interpretation.

  226. 226.

    See Rothbard (2000, pp. 23–29) for appropriate government policies in a depression.

  227. 227.

    See Mises (1931, p. 20).

  228. 228.

    (Patch 1998, p. 177); See also Kurt Gossweiler concerning the German industry and for the argument that the crisis was caused by too high nominal wages, too high taxes, and social insurance contributions (1971, p. 356).

  229. 229.

    Palyi (1972, p. 293); In relation with the recovery and the next artificial boom in Germany, Palyi comments on Brüning’s deflationary policy: “Actually behind foreign exchange restrictions and a host of petty regulations, Germany, well prepared for an upturn by Brüning’s policy of cost deflation, was the one and only country that managed to establish full employment in the late 1930s—by ‘contra-cyclical’ policies, i.e., resource mobilization for war” (1972, p. 34). Palyi later states: “Brüning’s heroic efforts to save the mark were largely futile, since he was unable to carry the deflation to its logical conclusion” (p. 339). At least, Brüning’s deflationary policies, paved the way for the recovery as Palyi indicated. Also Nussbaum states that when the Brüning government dismissed on May 30th 1932, the end of the crisis was near (1978, p. 373).

  230. 230.

    Hülsmann (2013, p. 105) argues that due to Brüning’s deflationary policies and a lack of similar policies in France, France fell far behind Germany economically in the 1930s. Hitler used the German economic advantage gained thanks to Brüning’s policies to overrun France in 6 weeks in 1940.

  231. 231.

    Later, the government bailed out companies and thus the public sector of the economy increased. See Nussbaum (1978, p. 329).

  232. 232.

    See Patch (1998, p. 176).

  233. 233.

    See Palyi (1972, p. 259). From the fall of 1931 on, the money supply was expanded slightly and the discount rate was reduced from 10 % in the beginning of September to 6 % in March 1932. See Patch (1998, p. 205).

  234. 234.

    See Fischer (1968, p. 46). Stolper remarks that there is unanimity that the crisis had its climax in the summer 1932 (1966, p. 139).

  235. 235.

    See Borchardt (1979, p. 109). Also Palyi writes: “The ‘deflation’ carried out until late July 1931 by Brüning and Luther [President of the Reichsbank] has been blamed for Hitler’s rise to power. This is one of the most pernicious myths which has grown out of the interwar monetary and political confusion” (1972, p. 262). Palyi argues that there was no alternative to Brüning’s policy. The political circumstances and German public opinion did not allow him to agree upon the French conditions for help. He also argues that it was General Schleicher’s mistake to turn to the left, thereby irritating Hindenburg who replaced Schleicher on January 30, 1933 with an anti-labor coalition led by Hitler, whose party was almost bankrupt and falling apart. (p. 264). For a similar assessment see Hülsmann (2013, p. 105).

  236. 236.

    Thus, the capital goods industry was still overextended in 1932. See Zumpe (1980).

  237. 237.

    See Palyi (1972, p. 263).

  238. 238.

    See Born (1967, p. 44).

  239. 239.

    See Aldcroft (1978, p. 167).

  240. 240.

    See Patch (1998, p. 207). Also Nussbaum states that the highly indebted coal and steel industries were in favor of inflationary policies (1978, p. 321).

  241. 241.

    See Patch (1998, p. 179).

  242. 242.

    See Korsch (1981, p. 31). Dräger was also engaged in the founding of the “Studiengesellschaft für Geld- und Kreditwirtschaft” [Research society for the economics of money and credit] in which politicians, state employees, scientists, entrepreneurs and members of labor unions gathered.

  243. 243.

    See Jochmann (1978, p. 103).

  244. 244.

    See Borchardt (1991, p. 37).

  245. 245.

    See Patch (1998, p. 177).

  246. 246.

    See Nussbaum (1978, pp. 333–335). The marxist author Lotte Zumpe argues that the majority of the financial sector, the coal and steel industries, the over-sea trade and the Junkers wanted Hitler to take power (1978, p. 11). She sees the rearmament as a reason for Hitler’s support by for example the Keppler-Kreis, a circle of bankers, heavy industrialists and Junkers who supported Hitler (p. 35). However, it is also possible that the support for Hitler was partially motivated by Hitler’s support of inflationary measures. Those measures would have benefited the economic establishment of bankers, heavy industrialists and Junkers who were threatened by price deflation.

  247. 247.

    As quoted in Borchardt (1979, p. 123), fn. 51; The original text is as follows: “… Der Faschismus bedeutet Inflation! Sein Ziel ist es, den Arbeitern Inflationslöhne zu zahlen, für die sie kaum Brot kaufen können, damit die bankrotten Schwerindustriellen und Großagrarier auf Kosten der Arbeiterschaft gesund gemacht werden können. Der Faschismus ist das Mittel zur politischen Knechtung der Arbeiterschaft, die Inflation ist seine wirtschaftliche Waffe gegen die Arbeiterschaft.”

  248. 248.

    See Nussbaum (1978, p. 224).

  249. 249.

    See Palyi (1972, p. 260).

  250. 250.

    The aim of the Osthilfe was to maintain the structure of ownership in times of price deflation and farm debts. The agricultural establishment did not want to lose its property and opposed the looming redistribution. See Nussbaum (1978, p. 365).

  251. 251.

    For the financial policies of the Third Reich, see Fischer (1968, pp. 66–71). For the Nazi public work programs and its financial policies, also see Stolper (1966, pp. 154–156, 169–173).

  252. 252.

    See Stolper (1966, p. 172).

References

  • Achinstein A (1961) Economic fluctuations. In: Harris SE (ed) American economic history. McGraw-Hill, New York, pp 162–180

    Google Scholar 

  • Ahamed L (2009) Lords of finance—The bankers who broke the world. Penguin Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Aldcroft DH (1978) Die zwanziger Jahre—Von Versailles zur Wall Street 1919-1929 (trans: Bauer HW, Quenzer G, Seip G). Deutscher Taschenbuchverlag, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson BM (1979) Economics and the public welfare—a financial and economic history of the United States, 1924-46, 2nd edn. Liberty Press, Indianapolis, IN

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson BM [1917] (2000) The value of money. Libertarian Press, Grove City, PA (reprint).

    Google Scholar 

  • Andrews B (1895) The fall of prices—the cause and the cure. In: White T (ed) Silver and gold: or, Both sides of the shield; A symposium of the view of all parties on the currency question as expressed by their leading advocates, thoroughly expounding the doctrines of free silver, mono-metalism and bi-metalism, with all arguments, pro. and con. From the pens of John Sherman, Wm. B. Allison, John G. Carlisle…and others. Publisher’s Union, Philadelphia, pp 301–30

    Google Scholar 

  • Angell JW (1929) The recovery of Germany. Published for the Council on Foreign Affairs. Yale University Press, New Haven

    Google Scholar 

  • Barrett DC (1931) The Greenbacks and resumption of specie payments, 1862-1879. Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bartsch M, Henry E (2005) Brünings Wirtschaftspolitik: Maßnahmen—Handlungsspielräume—Alternativen; Eine Retrospektive zur Borchardt-Kontroverse -. Dresden: Sächsische Landesbibliothek—Staats- und Universitätsbibliothek Dresden. http://nbn-resolving.de/urn:nbn:de:swb:14-1139911732466-76552. Accessed 1 Aug 2007.

  • Bemis EW (1893) The discontent of the farmer. J Polit Econ 1(2):193–213

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bombach G (1976) Einleitung. In: Bombach G, Ramser H-J, Timmermann M, Wittmann W (eds) Der Keynesianismus II—Die beschäftigungspolitische Diskussion vor Keynes in Deutschland, Dokumente und Kommentare. Springer, Berlin, pp 1–8

    Google Scholar 

  • Borchardt K (1979) Zwangslagen und Handlungsspielräume in der großen Weltwirtschaftskrise der frühen dreißiger Jahre: Zur Revision des überlieferten Geschichtsbildes. Jahrbuch der Bayerischen Akademie der Wissenschaften: 85–132

    Google Scholar 

  • Borchardt K (1982) Wachstum, Krisen, Handlungsspielräume der Wirtschaftspolitik: Studien zur Wirtschaftsgeschichte d. 19. u. 20. Jh. Vandenhoek und Ruprecht, Göttingen

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Borchardt K (1991) Einleitung. In: Borchardt K, Schötz O (eds) Wirtschaftspolitik in der Krise—die (Geheim-)Konferenz der Friedrich List-Gesellschaft im September 1931 über Möglichkeiten und Folgen einer Kreditausweitung. Nomos Verlag, Baden-Baden, pp 17–50

    Google Scholar 

  • Born KE (1967) Die deutsche Bankenkrise 1931—Finanzen und Politik. R. Piper, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Bresciani-Turroni C (2007) The economics of inflation: a study of currency depreciation in post-war Germany. Ludwig von Mises Institute, Auburn, AL

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchheim C (2002) The ‘Crisis Before the Crisis’—the export engine out of gear. In: James H (ed) The interwar depression in an international context. Oldenbourg Verlag, Munich, pp 113–122

    Google Scholar 

  • Coppock DJ (1961) The causes of the great depression, 1873-96. Manchest School Econ Soc Stud 29:205–232

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis JH (2006) An improved annual chronology of U.S. business cycles since the 1790s. J Econ Hist 66(1):103–121

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Davis LE, North DC (1971) Institutional change and American economic growth. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Davis LE, Hughes JRT, McDougall DM (1965) American economic history. R.D. Irwin, Homewood, IL

    Google Scholar 

  • Deutsche Bundesbank (1976) Deutsches Geld- und Bankwesen in Zahlen 1876-1975. Knapp, Frankfurt am Main

    Google Scholar 

  • Dewey DR (1907) Financial history of The United States, 3rd edn. Longmans, Green, and Co., New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Dickey GE (1977) Money, prices and growth: the American experience. Arno Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Elliot JR (1890) American farms: their condition and future. Putnam’s Sons, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Emerick CF (1896) An analysis of agricultural discontent in the United States I. Polit Sci Quart 11(3):433–463

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Emerick CF (1897) An analysis of agricultural discontent in the United States III. Polit Sci Quart 12(1):93–127

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Faulkner HU (1924) American economic history. Harper & Brothers Publishers, New York and London

    Google Scholar 

  • Fekete AE (1996) Whither gold? Foundation for the advancement of monetary education, New York. http://www.fame.org/HTM/Fekete_Anatal_Whither_Gold_AF-001-B.HTM. Accessed 5 Oct 2007.

  • Fels R (1949) The long-wave depression, 1873-97. Rev Econ Stat 31(1):69–73

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fels R (1951) American business cycles, 1865-79. Am Econ Rev 41(3):325–349

    Google Scholar 

  • Fels R (1959) American business cycles 1865-1897. The University of North Carolina Press, Chapel Hill, NC

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferguson A (2010) When money dies. The nightmare of deficit spending, devaluation, and hyperinflation in Weimar Germany. PublicAffairs, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischer W (1968) Deutsche Wirtschaftspolitik 1918-1945, 3rd exp. edn. C.W. Leske Verlag, Opladen

    Google Scholar 

  • Folsom BW Jr (2003) The myth of the robber barons—a new look at the rise of big business in America, 4th edn. Young America’s Foundation, Herndon, VA

    Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M (1990) The crime of 1873. J Polit Econ 98(6):1159–1194

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Friedman M, Schwartz AJ (1971) A monetary history of the United States 1867-1960. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Goodwyn L (1978) The populist movement, a short hisotry of the agrarian revolt in America. Oxford University Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Gossweiler K (1971) Großbanken, Industriemonopole, Staat—Ökonomie und Politik des staatsmonopolistischen Kapitalismus in Deutschland 1914-1932. VEB Deutscher Verlag der Wissenschaften, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Hamilton EJ (1952) Prices as a factor in business growth: prices and progress. J Econ Hist 12(4):325–349

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoxie RF (1893) The silver debate of 1890. J Polit Econ 1(1):535–587

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hülsmann JG (2004) Legal tender laws, and fractional reserve banking. Quart J Aust Econ 18(3):33–55

    Google Scholar 

  • Hülsmann JG (2013) Krise der Inflationskultur. FinanzBuchVerlag, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • James H (2002) Introduction. In: James H (ed) The interwar depression in an international context, VII–XV. Oldenbourg Verlag, Munich

    Google Scholar 

  • Jochmann W (1978) Brünings Deflationspolitik and der Untergang der Weimarer Republik. In: Stegmann D (ed) Industrielle Gesellschaft und politisches System: Beiträge zur politischen Sozialgeschichte; Festschrift für Fritz Fischer zum 70. Geburtstag. Verlag Neue Gesellschaft, Bonn

    Google Scholar 

  • Kazin M (1998) The populist persuasion. An American history. Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Keiser G, Benning B (1931) Kapitalbildung und Investitionen in der deutschen Volkswirtschaft. Vierteljahreshefte zur Konjunkturforschung. Sonderheft 22, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Kindleberger CP (1987) The world in depression 1929-1939. Pelican Books, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Korsch A (1981) Der Stand der beschäftigungspolitischen Diskussion zur Zeit der Weltwirtschaftskrise in Deutschland. In: Bombach G, Ramser H-J, Timmermann M, Wittmann W (eds) Der Keynesianismus I—Theorie und Praxis keynesianischer Wirtschaftspolitik, Entwicklung und Stand der Diskussion. Springer, Berlin, pp 9–132

    Google Scholar 

  • Kuznets S (1961) Capital in the American economy: its formation and financing. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Laughlin LJ (1887) Gold and prices since 1873. Q J Econ 1(3):319–355

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Laughlin LJ (1968) The history of bimetallism in the United States, 4th edn. Greenwood Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • League of Nations (1935) World production and prices: 1925-1934. League of Nations, Economic Intelligence Service, Geneva

    Google Scholar 

  • League of Nations (1944) International currency experience. League of Nations, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Lüke RE (1958) Von der Stabilisierung zur Krise. Polygraphischer Verlag, Zurich

    Google Scholar 

  • McClean HS (1895) The quantity of money and prices, 1860-1891. J Polit Econ 3(2):145–168

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell WC (1903) A history of the greenbacks with special reference to the economics consequences of their issue: 1892-1895. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Mitchell WC (1927) Business cycles: the problem and its setting. NBER studies in business cycles, vol 1. NBER, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Musson AE (1959) The great depression in Britain, 1873-1896: a reappraisal. J Econ Hist 19(2):199–228

    Google Scholar 

  • Newman P (2012) The long depression of 1873-1879: an Austrian examination. Winning essay of society for the development of Austrian economics’ 2012 Carl Menger Essay Contest

    Google Scholar 

  • North DC (1961) The United States in the international economy. In: Harris SE (ed) American economic history. McGraw-Hill, New York, pp 1790–1950

    Google Scholar 

  • Nugent WTK (1967) The money question during reconstruction. Norton & Company, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Nugent WTK (1968) The tolerant populists; Kansas, populism and nativism. The University of Chicago Press, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Nussbaum M (1978) Wirtschaft und Staat in Deutschland während der Weimarer Republik. Topos Verlag, Vaduz

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson M (1971) The logic of collective action: public goods and the theory of groups. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Palyi M (1972) The twilight of gold, 1914-1936, myths and realities. Henry Regnery, Chicago

    Google Scholar 

  • Patch WL Jr (1998) Heinrich Brüning and the dissolution of the Weimar republic. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge

    Google Scholar 

  • Rallo JR (2006) La Gran Depresión. Paper presented at the Juan de Mariana Institute, December 15

    Google Scholar 

  • Rezneck S (1950) Distress, relief, and discontent in the United States during the depression 1873-78. J Polit Econ 58(6):494–512

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rezneck S (1953) Unemployment, unrest, and relief in the United States during the depression of 1893-1897. J Polit Econ 61(4):324–345

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rezneck S (1956) Pattern of thought and action in an American depression, 1882-86. Am Hist Rev 61(2):284–307

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ritschl A (2002) International capital movements and the onset of the great depression: some international evidence. In: James H (ed) The interwar depression in an international context. Oldenbourg Verlag, Munich, pp 1–14

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Ritter G (1997) Goldbugs and greenbacks: the antimonopoly tradition and the politics of finance in America. Cambridge University Press, New York

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Rockoff H (1990) The “Wizard of the Oz” as a Monetary Allegory. J Polit Econ 98(4):739–760

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard MN (2000) America’s great depression, 5th edn. Ludwig von Mises Institute, Auburn, AL

    Google Scholar 

  • Rothbard MN (2002) A history of money and banking in the United States: The colonial Era to World War II. Ludwig von Mises Institute, Auburn, AL

    Google Scholar 

  • Schacht H (1931) Das Ende der Reparationen. Gerhard Stalling, Oldenburg

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter J (1929) Grenzen der Lohnpolitik. Der Deutsche Volkswirt 3(26):847–851

    Google Scholar 

  • Selgin G (1997) Less than zero: the case for a falling price level in a growing economy. The Institute for Economic Affairs, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Shannon FA (1945) The farmer’s last Frontier: agriculture, 1860-1897. Harper & Row, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Shannon FA (1957) American farmers’ movement. D. Van Nostrand Company, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • Shields RE (1977) Economic growth with price deflation. Arno Press, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Siegel JJ (1998) Stocks for the long run, 2nd rev. edn. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Skidelsky R (2002) The Great Depression: Keynes’s Perspective. In: Harold J (ed) The interwar depression in an international context. Oldenbourg Verlag, Munich, pp 99–112

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith VC (1990) The rational of central banking and the free banking alternative. Liberty Press, Indianapolis, IN

    Google Scholar 

  • Statistisches Bundesamt (1972) Bevölkerung und Wirtschaft 1872-1972. Kohlhammer, Stuttgart

    Google Scholar 

  • Stock CMN (1996) Rural radicals: righteous rage in the American Grain. Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Stolper G (1966) Deutsche Wirtschaft seit 1870. Continued by Karl Häuser and Knut Borchardt, 2nd rev. edn. J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck), Tübingen

    Google Scholar 

  • Stucken R (1953) Deutsche Geld- und Kreditpolitik: 1914-1953, 2nd edn. J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck), Tübingen.

    Google Scholar 

  • Studenski P, Kroos HE (1963) Financial history of the United States, 2nd edn. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Taussig FW (1892) The silver situation in the United States. Publ Am Econ Assoc 7(1):7–118

    Google Scholar 

  • Thorp WL (1926) Business annals. NBER, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Unger I (1962) Business men and specie resumption. Polit Sci Quart 74(1):46–70

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Unger I (1964) The Greenback Era, a social and political history of American finance, 1865-1879. Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ

    Google Scholar 

  • US Department of Commerce (1975) Historical statistics of the United States. Colonial times to 1970. Government Printing Office, Washington, DC

    Google Scholar 

  • von Mises L (1931) Die Ursachen der Wirtschaftskrise: Ein Vortrag. J.C.B. Mohr (Paul Siebeck), Tübingen

    Google Scholar 

  • von Mises L (1978) On the manipulation of money and credit (trans. and eds: Greaves BB, Greaves PL Jr). Freemarket Books, Dobbs Ferry, NY

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagemann E (ed) (1935) Konjunkturstatistisches Handbuch 1936. Institut für Konjunkturforschung. Hanseatische Verlagsanstalt Hamburg, Berlin

    Google Scholar 

  • Wagenführ R (1933) Die Industriewirtschaft, Entwicklungstendenzen der deutschen und internationalen Industrieproduktion 1860 bis 1932. Vierteljahreshefte zur Konjunkturforschung, Special Issue 31, Berlin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walker FA (1883) Money. Henry Holt and Company, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Warren GF, Pearson FA (1933) Prices. Wiley, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Warren GF, Pearson FA (1983) Gold and prices. Garland, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Weinstein A (1970) Prelude to populism: origins of the silver issue, 1867-1878. Yale University Press, New Haven, CT

    Google Scholar 

  • Wells DA (1891) Recent economic changes: and their effect on the production and distribution of wealth and the well-being of society. D. Appleton, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Zumpe L (1980) Wirtschaft und Staat in Deutschland 1933 bis 1945. Topos Verlag, Vaduz

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2015 Springer International Publishing Switzerland

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Bagus, P. (2015). Two Historical Examples of Deflation. In: In Defense of Deflation. Financial and Monetary Policy Studies, vol 41. Springer, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-319-13428-4_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics