Skip to main content

From Luxemburg to Sweezy: Notes on the Intellectual Influence of Hilferding’s Finance Capital

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
Rudolf Hilferding

Part of the book series: Luxemburg International Studies in Political Economy ((LISPE))

  • 157 Accesses

Abstract

This chapter is about the key political economy contributions which originated from Hilferding’s “Finance Capital”. It covers the period from its publication in 1910 to 1966 the year Monopoly Capital by Paul Sweezy and Paul Baran came out. I will show that the ideas associated with Finance Capital dominated economic thinking in the left during the second and third decades of the twentieth century. In the 1930s the Great Depression marked a setback for the book’s prestige. However, important economists, like Natali Moszkowska and Paul Sweezy, who elaborated on the realization/underconsumption version of monopoly theory during that period, initiated fresh interest in this line of thought. It was the conclusion of an intellectual effort that stemmed from the insights of Rosa Luxemburg. Their input established a scientific paradigm that gained recognition in the economic profession. Moreover, it offers an analytical explanation for the booming growth of finance following 1980 and the economic crisis which began in 2007/2008. The most serious criticism toward Hilferding, Moszkowska, and Sweezy is that their conclusions rely on the neoclassical theory of perfect competition and its “dark side”, that is monopoly “price setting”. Neoclassical monopoly pricing means the rejection of the labor theory of value and constitutes a different argument from the one in Marx.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 169.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 219.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. 1.

    The promoters’ profit is very close to what Marx called the “rate of profit of enterprise”, the latter is the difference of the rate of profit from the rate of interest. This category is very important in Marx and his crisis theory although Hilferding thinks otherwise (Hilferding 1981, p. 115).

  2. 2.

    For example, in mainstream theory the formula has the following form for the price (P) of preferred stock:

    $$ P=\frac{\textrm{dividend}}{\textrm{rroi}}\kern0.28em \textrm{and}\kern0.28em \textrm{rroi}=\textrm{required}\kern0.28em \textrm{rate}\kern0.28em \textrm{of}\kern0.28em \textrm{return}. $$
  3. 3.

    In other words, he believes that “finance capital” will sell preferred shares to the public to realize their profit and will keep common stocks to maintain control of the companies.

  4. 4.

    The “interest-bearing capital” is a Marxist category and refers to a portion of total capital invested in companies yielding dividends. In the third volume of Capital Marx treats the growth of interest-bearing capital as a countervailing influence against the declining rate of profit (Marx 1959, pp. 169, 170).

  5. 5.

    The discussion of Marx’s theory of effective demand is kind of novel in Marxist economics. The paper by Peter Kenway “Marx Keynes and the Possibility of a Crisis” is a good introduction to this subject (Kenway 1980).

  6. 6.

    One can make obvious associations with the European Union from the slogan. However, the matter is more complicated and beyond the scope of the present chapter.

  7. 7.

    I flipped the chart 90 degrees clockwise so that time will appear in the horizontal axis.

  8. 8.

    The bold line is the US golden price index and the lighter line the UK golden price index.

  9. 9.

    c stands for constant (machinery, energy, and production materials) and v for variable capital (workers).

  10. 10.

    The influence of Keynes and Kalecki on “Monopoly Capital” is beyond doubt. There is express reference to the “General Theory”, Joan Robinson, Michal Kalecki, and Joseph Steindl in the book (Sweezy and Baran 1968, pp. 55, 56).

  11. 11.

    This clearly explains why the ideas of Baran and Sweezy diverge from mainstream oligopoly theory. In the latter there is no rule preventing oligopoly prices from declining. For example, in a Cournot duopoly companies have the option to act in collusion by setting prices or independently. In the latter case prices will decline due to competition. In Baran and Sweezy this is not an option and the group of oligopolies behaves like a neoclassical monopoly.

References

  • Barsky, R., and J. De Long. 1993. Why Does the Stock Market Fluctuate? Quarterly Journal of Economics CVIII (2): 291–311.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bauer, O. 1912–1913. Die Akkumulation des Kapitals. Die Neue Zeit, pp. 831–838, 862–874.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bukharin, N. 1920. Programme of the World Revolution. Glasgow: Socialist Labour Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1929. Imperialism and the World Economy. New York: International Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1972. Imperialism and the Accumulation of Capital. London: Penguin Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, S.F. 1980. Nikolai Bukharin and the Bolshevik Revolution. New York: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Day, R.B. 1976. The Theory of Long Waves: Kondratiev, Trotsky, Mandel. New Left Review, September, October.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dohan, M.R. 1969. Soviet Foreign Trade in the NEP Economy and Soviet Industrialization Strategy. Ph.D. Dissertation Department of Economics Massachusetts Institute of Technology, Boston.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eckstein, G. 1913. Rosa Luxemburg: Die Akkumulation des Kapitals: Ein Beitrag zur okonomischen Erklarung des Imperialismus. Vorwarts.

    Google Scholar 

  • Grossman, H. 1929. The Law of Accumulation and the Breakdown of the Capitalist System. Leipzig: Hirshfeld (extract translation marxist.org).

  • Henderson, J., and R. Quant (1958). Microeconomic Theory a Mathematical Approach McGraw Hill Book Company, Inc. New York, Toronto, London 1958.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilferding, R. 1981. Finance Capital—A Study of the Latest Phase of Capitalist Development. London: Routledge & Kegan Paul.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kautsky, K. 1911. Finance Capital and Crises. Social Democrat, August–December.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1914. Der Imperialismus. Die Neue Zeit 2: 908–922.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kenway, P. 1980. Marx, Keynes and the Possibility of a Crisis. Cambridge Journal of Economics 4: 23–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kondratiev, N. 1998. The Works of Nikolai Kondratiev. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lapavitsas, C. 2009. Financialised Capitalism: Crisis and Financial Expropriation. Historical Materialism 17: 114–148.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lenin, V. 1974. On the slogan for a United States of Europe. In Collected Works, ed. V. Lenin, vol. 21, 339–343. Moscow: Progress Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lenin, V.I. 1999. Imperialism the Highest Stage of Capitalism-A Popular Outline. Sydney: Resistance Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Luxemburg, Rosa. 2016a. Accumulation of Capital. A Contribution to the Economic Theory of Imperialism. London: Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2016b. The Accumulation of Capital, Or, What the Epigones Have Made Out of Marx’s Capital—An Anti-Critique. London: Verso.

    Google Scholar 

  • Magdoff, F., and J.B. Foster. 2014. Stagnation and Financialization. Monthly Review, May 1.

    Google Scholar 

  • Magdoff, H., and P. Sweezy. 1987. Stagnation and the Financial Explosion. New York: Monthly Review Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mandel, E. 1980. Long Waves of Capitalist Development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marx, K. 1853. The East India Company—Its History and Results. New York Daily Tribune. https://www.marxists.org/archive/marx/works/1853/07/11.htm

  • ———. 1959. Capital. Vol. III. New York: International Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1964. Capital. Vol. I. Moscow: Progress Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1973. Grundrisse. London: Penguin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Moszkowska, N. 1929. The System of Marx. Berlin: Engelmann, H.R.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1935. Zur Kritik moderner Krisetheorien. Prague: Michael Kacha.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1943. The Dynamics of Late Capitalism. Zurich: Der Aufbruch.

    Google Scholar 

  • Okishio, N. 1961. Technical Change and the Rate of Profit. Kobe University Economic Review 7: 85–99.

    Google Scholar 

  • Preobrazhensky, E. 1965. New Economics. London: Oxford University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shaikh, A. 1980. Marxist Competition Versus Perfect Competition: Further Comments on the So Called Choice of Technique. Cambridge Journal of Economics 4: 75–83.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 1997. The Stock Market and the Corporate Sector: A Profit-Based Approach. In Markets Employment and Economic Policy-Essays in Honour of Geoff Harcourt VII, ed. M. Sawyer and P.E. Arestis, 389–404. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2016. Capitalism, Competition, Conflict, and Crises. Oxford: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Shakh, A. 2011. The First Great Depression oF the 21st Century. Socialist Register, October, 44–63.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sherman, H. 1966. Monopoly Capital. An Essay on the American Economic and Social Order (Book Review). American Economic Review 56 (4): 919–921.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shiller, R. 1989. Comovements in Stock Prices and Comovements in Dividends. Journal of Finance 44 (3): 719–729.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stravelakis, N. 2014. Financial Crisis and Economic Depression: Post Hoc Ergo Propter Hoc? In Challenges to Financial Stability–Perspective, Models, and Policies-Volume I, ed. R. K., 187–210. Warsaw: Assers Publishers.

    Google Scholar 

  • ———. 2019. Marx’s Theory of Finance and the 21st Century. In IIPPE-AFEP Conference. Lille: IIPE-AFEP.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sweezy, P. 1980. The Crisis of American Capitalism. Monthly Review 32 (5): 1–13.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sweezy, P., and P. Baran. 1968. Monopoly Capital. New York: Monthly Review Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trotsky, L. 1941. The Curve of Capitalist Development. In Collected Works, ed. L. Trotsky, vol. 2, 111–114. New York: Fourth International.

    Google Scholar 

  • Trotsky, L., and E. Varga. 1921. Report on the World Economic Crisis and the New Tasks of the Communist International. In To the Masses: Proceedings of the Third Congress of the Communist International, 1921, ed. John Riddell, 102–133. Chicago: Haymarket Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsoulfidis, L. 2011. Classical vs. Neoclassical Conceptions of Competition. Discussion Paper No. 11 Department of Economics University of Macedonia.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsoulfidis, L., and D. Paitarides. 2018. Capital Intensity, Unproductive Activities, and the Great Recession in the US. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 1–25. https://doi.org/10.1093/cje/bey051.

  • Tugan-Baranowski, M. 1901. Theorie und Geschichte der Handelkrisen in England-Studies on the Theory and History of Business Crises in England. Jena: Gustav Fischer.

    Google Scholar 

  • Varga, E. 1934. The Great Crisis and Its Political Consequences on Economics and Politics 1928–1934. London: Modern Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zarembka, P. 2015. Materialized Composition of Capital and Its Stability in the United States, 1948–2011. Findings stimulated by Paitaridis and Tsoulfidis (2012). Review of Radical Political 47 (1): 106–111.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Appendices

Appendix 1: Commodity Prices in Hilferding

When referring to competitive capitalism Hilferding says:

the tendencies which give rise to a protracted decline in the rate of profit and in its average level, … can only be overcome by eliminating their cause—competition [emphasis added-NS]. (Hilferding [1910] 1981, p. 193)

This is not the case in Marx. In Capital Vol.I (Marx [1964], Ch. 12, pp. 220–226) Marx argues that automation becomes the dominant form of increasing the social productivity of labor, and this is done not to get additional profit from other capitalists but to increase the extraction of relative surplus value from workers, the source of profit in capitalism. Mechanization thus results from the labor process itself. This inherent tendency, as we know, leads to an increasing organic composition of capital and a declining rate of profit as presented in The Capital V. III (Marx 1959, Part III, pp. 153–171). Competition does not produce this law of capitalist accumulation (i.e., the declining rate of profit) it makes it evident.

This process has an impact on the competition itself. Because capitalist competition emerges out of the fundamental conflicting production relations in capitalism, it is not a game, it is a war fought by the “cheapening of commodities” (Marx [1964], p. 441), it decides who lives or dies. This means that in the Classical/Marxian notion, capitalist competition cannot be abolished for long because it emerges from the production process as a labor process. In the neoclassical world of “perfect competition”, competition can be easily eliminated. For this reason, neoclassical economists propose and accept laws and regulations “protecting” competition. In other words, the mainstream theory assumes that the market cannot protect itself from monopolies and cartels.

This explains why Hilferding applies “perfect competition” to justify the tendency toward cartelization. The latter implies also the abolition of the labor theory of value, as admitted by Hilferding himself (Hilferding [1910] 1981, p. 228), and the determination of prices in a similar fashion to that of monopoly prices in neoclassical micro textbooks. The following extract is indicative:

The latter [Monopoly prices-NS] would themselves be determined, however, by the reciprocal relationship between costs of production and volume of output on the one hand, and prices and the volume of sales on the other. The monopoly price would be that price that makes possible a volume of sales such that the scale of production does not increase the costs of production so greatly as to reduce the profit per unit significantly. A higher price would reduce sales, and hence the scale of production, thus raising costs and reducing the profit per unit of output; a lower price would reduce profit so greatly that even the greater volume of sales would not compensate for it. (Hilferding [1910] 1981, p. 227)

The solution to Hilferding’s exercise is no other than the familiar figure we have all seen in our neoclassical micro textbooks. Here it is copied from Henderson and Quant “Microeconomic Theory—A Mathematical Approach” McGraw-Hill Book Company, Inc. New York 1958, p. 169. Where D is the demand curve, MC is the marginal cost, and MR the marginal revenue.

A line graph depicts P, P zero versus Q zero, Q 1, Q 2 with the two decreased lines of M C, M R plotted, and line plotted from p zero to Q zero.

Similarly to Hilferding, the neoclassical economist states: “The monopolist can increase her profit by increasing (or contracting) her output as long as the addition to her marginal revenue exceeds (or is less than) the addition to her cost (MC)” (Henderson & Quant 1958, p. 169).

Appendix 2: Stock Market Prices

A curve graph depicts values versus years with three curves of S and P 500, profit-based, efficient market, where the curves of S P 500, profit based has a peak value of 2000 in the year 2017.

This chart is indicative in many respects. The blue line pictures the real price of the S&P 500 from 1947 to 2019. It is the benchmark for the warranted price data simulation using the Incremental Rate of Profit as the rate of return (brown line) (Stravelakis 2019). The gray line shows the Efficient Market Hypothesis prices calculated by Robert Shiller with a constant discount factor of 7.6%. A constant or slowly varying discount factor appears also in Hilferding for the pricing of common and preferred stock (see “Finance Capital and the Dynamics of Capitalism” section). However, we can see that constant discount factor prices like the efficient market prices are not relevant. This led Shiller to consider the volatility and the diversion in actual prices compared to the “gray” line as an indication of “irrationality” from the side of “economic agents”.

The application of the Incremental Rate of Profit as the required rate of return implies that “warranted prices” are the gravity center of actual prices (Shaikh 1997). This leaves room for bubbles or under-pricing. Nevertheless, fundamentals rule in the end. The preceding simulation confirms this insight. In the boom of the 50s and the 60s, actual stock prices exceeded fundamental prices. The opposite happened during the times of the great stagflation (1970–1981) when actual prices underscored warranted prices. This continued in the first years of the neoliberal era. However, following 1985 actual prices overshoot the underlying fundamentals reaching a climax in the dot com bubble (around the year 2000). The correction that follows was steep but short. Thereafter, actual prices gravitated around fundamental prices. In 2007/2008 stock prices fell shortly after the collapse in the underlying fundamentals. The latter supports the analytical conclusion that the financial crisis was the trigger and not the cause of the depression that followed. This indicates also why the application of the Baran-Sweezy theory (see “Conclusion: Crisis and Finance” section) in understanding the current crisis, although analytically sound, is unsupported. No bubble appears at least in stock market prices following 2000 to justify this reasoning.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2023 The Author(s), under exclusive license to Springer Nature Switzerland AG

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Stravelakis, N. (2023). From Luxemburg to Sweezy: Notes on the Intellectual Influence of Hilferding’s Finance Capital. In: Dellheim, J., Wolf, F.O. (eds) Rudolf Hilferding. Luxemburg International Studies in Political Economy. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-08096-8_3

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-031-08096-8_3

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-031-08095-1

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-031-08096-8

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics