Skip to main content

On the Definition and Nature of Fiscal Coercion

  • Chapter
  • First Online:
James M. Buchanan

Part of the book series: Remaking Economics: Eminent Post-War Economists ((EPWE))

  • 880 Accesses

Abstract

We introduce ideas about how coercion in public finance can be formally defined, building on recent work in the literature. Our discussion illustrates the connection between selected aspects of this research and earlier seminal work on coercion by Wicksell, Lindahl, and Buchanan and Tullock. We also attempt to contribute modestly towards a fuller understanding of the nature of coercion in a public finance setting. We use a Lindahl solution as the counterfactual social state relative to which coercion inherent in any situation is to be judged in order to evaluate and compare the nature of coercion imposed by a social planner and in an electoral equilibrium.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 149.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as EPUB and PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 279.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Notes

  1. 1.

    This and the next section make use of some ideas from Martinez-Vazquez and Winer, eds. (2014) and WTH (2014). For exploration of the connections between the two fundamental sources of coercion and the implications of this relationship for public finance from differing points of view, see Skaperdas (2014) and Wallis (2014).

  2. 2.

    ‘Non-coercive’ does not necessarily mean that same thing as ‘voluntary’. For a discussion of related issues in the definition of coercion, see Congleton (2014).

  3. 3.

    Personal communication from Dan Usher.

  4. 4.

    It may be noted that a median voter is essentially a dictator imposing coercion on everyone else.

  5. 5.

    The issues involved in determining the practicality of Coasian bargaining are well known and will not be enumerated here.

  6. 6.

    We may use the latter to calculate an economy-wide average income tax rate as follows. Funding \( G^{L} \) requires a tax revenue of \( t\sum\nolimits_{i}^{N} {Y_{i} } = G^{L} \) which implies that the notional tax rate is \( t = \bar{\alpha } + \frac{{\sigma_{Y\alpha }^{2} }}{{\bar{Y}}} \). However, this is not the actual rate levied on taxpayers in a Lindahl solution. Each individual pays a personalized tax tailored to their preferences.

  7. 7.

    Buchanan (1964, pp. 229–230): “A more general statement of the necessary condition (for a Lindahl solution—our addition) is as follows: The income elasticity of demand for the public good divided by the price elasticity of demand must be equal to, and opposed in sign to, the income elasticity of the tax-price schedule. Full neutrality is present when this condition is met throughout the range of possible incomes.”

References

  • Boadway, R. (2014). The Role of Coercion in Public Economic Theory. In Martinez-Vazquez and Winer, eds., pp. 195–200.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breton, A. (1996). Competitive Governments: An Economic Theory of Politics and Public Finance. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1964). Fiscal Institutions and Efficiency in Collective Outlay. American Economic Review, 54(3), 227–235.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M. (1968). The Demand and Supply of Public Goods. Chicago: Rand McNally.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The Calculus of Consent: Logical Foundations of Constitutional Democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press. (Page reference in text is to the Ann Arbor paperback edition of 1967).

    Google Scholar 

  • Coase, R. (1960). The Problem of Social Cost. Journal of Law and Economics, 3, 1–44.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Congleton, R. (2014). Coercion, Taxation, and Voluntary Association. In Martinez-Vazquez and Winer, eds., pp. 91–116.

    Google Scholar 

  • Coughlin, P. (1992). Probabilistic Voting Theory. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Hettich, W., & Winer, S. L. (1999). Democratic Choice and Taxation: A Theoretical and Empirical Investigation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hintermann, B., & Rutherford, T. (2017). Social Planning and Coercion Under Bounded Rationality with an Application to Environmental Policy. International Tax and Public Finance, 24, 854–878.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kaplow, L. (2001). Horizontal Equity: New Measures, Unclear Principles. In K. Hassett & G. Hubbard (Eds.), Inequality and Tax Policy (pp. 75–97). Washington: American Enterprise Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ledyard, J. O. (2014). Non-Coercion, Efficiency and Incentive Compatibility in Public Goods. In Marinez-Vazquez and Winer, eds., pp. 143–159.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lindahl, E. (1919). Just Taxation: A Positive Solution. In R. A. Musgrave & A. T. Peacock. Classics in the Theory of Public Finance (pp. 168–176) London: Macmillan, 1958. An excerpt from Erik Lindahl, Die Gerechtigkeit der Besteuerung (Lund: Gleerupska Universitets-Bokhandeln 1919).

    Google Scholar 

  • Martinez-Vazquez, J., & Winer, S. L. (Eds.). (2014). Coercion and Social Welfare in Public Finance: Economic and Political Perspectives. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Martinez-Vazquez, J., & Winer, S. L. (2014). Coercion, Welfare, and the Study of Public Finance. In Martinez-Vazquez and Winer, eds., pp. 1–26.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public Choice III. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Munger, M. C. (2014). Kaldor-Hicks-Scitovsky Coercion, Coasian Bargaining, and the State. In Martinez-Vazquez and Winer, eds., pp. 117–135.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sehili, S., & Martinez-Vazquez, J. (2014). Lindahl Fiscal Incidence and the Measurement of Coercion. In Martinez-Vazquez and Winer, eds., pp. 201–240.

    Google Scholar 

  • Skaperdas, S. (2014). Proprietary Public Finance: On Its Emergence and Evolution Out of Anarchy. In Martinez-Vazquez and Winer, eds., pp. 60–81.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wallis, J. J. (2014). The Constitution of Coercion: Wicksell, Violence, and the Ordering of Society. In Martinez-Vazquez and Winer, eds., pp. 29–59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wicksell, K. (1896). A New Principle of Just Taxation. In R. A. Musgrave & A. T. Peacock (Eds.), Classics in the Theory of Public Finance (pp. 73–118). London: Macmillan. An excerpt from KnutWicksell, Finanztheoretische Untersuchungen (Jena: Fischer).

    Google Scholar 

  • Winer, S. L., Tridimas, G., & Hettich, W. (2014). Social Welfare and Coercion in Public Finance. In Martinez-Vazquez and Winer, eds., pp. 160–194.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Stanley L. Winer .

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2018 The Author(s)

About this chapter

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this chapter

Tridimas, G., Winer, S.L. (2018). On the Definition and Nature of Fiscal Coercion. In: Wagner, R. (eds) James M. Buchanan. Remaking Economics: Eminent Post-War Economists. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-03080-3_23

Download citation

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/978-3-030-03080-3_23

  • Published:

  • Publisher Name: Palgrave Macmillan, Cham

  • Print ISBN: 978-3-030-03079-7

  • Online ISBN: 978-3-030-03080-3

  • eBook Packages: Economics and FinanceEconomics and Finance (R0)

Publish with us

Policies and ethics