Skip to main content

Political and Economic Thought of German Neo-Liberals

  • Chapter
German Neo-Liberals and the Social Market Economy

Part of the book series: Trade Policy Research Centre ((TPRC))

Abstract

In the last ten years the economic and political consensus that characterised the Western world has disintegrated. This consensus, holding that economic growth, full employment and a more or less stable price level could be achieved by macro-economic management of the economy without any fundamental damage being done to the micro-structure of a basically private enterprise system or to that impersonal rule of law on which free economic transactions depend, seemed to signal the end of ideological disputes between advocates of collectivist and individualist forms of social and economic organisation. Indeed, the famous ‘calculation debate’, which divided the two schools in the 1930s and 1940s, seemed to have receded into the textbooks on the history of economic thought.1

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 129.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Softcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Compact, lightweight edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info
Hardcover Book
USD 169.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Notes and References

  1. For details of this debate, which is highly relevant to German classical liberalism, see The Journal of Libertarian Studies, Oxford and Frankfurt, Vol. V, 1981. The Winter issue was devoted entirely to socialist calculation.

    Google Scholar 

  2. Edwin Dolan (ed.), The Foundations of Austrian Economics (Kansas: Sheed & Ward, 1976)

    Google Scholar 

  3. or Milton Friedman, Capitalism and Freedom (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1962). Milton Friedman’s book is still the best simple introduction.

    Google Scholar 

  4. Hans Willgerodt, ‘Planning in West Germany: the Social Market Economy’, in Lawrence Chickering (ed.), The Politics of Planning (San Francisco: Institute for Contempoary Studies, 1976) p. 64.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Norman P. Barry, ‘Ideas Versus Interests, the Classical Liberal Dilemma’, in Barry et al., Hayek’s ‘Serfdom’ Revisited (London: Institute of Economic Affairs, 1984) pp. 45–64;

    Google Scholar 

  6. Barry, ‘Agreement, Unanimity and Liberalism’, Political Theory, Beverly Hills, London and New Delhi, Vol. 12, 1984, pp. 579–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  7. John Gray, Hayek on Liberty (Oxford: Blackwell, 1984) p. 70.

    Google Scholar 

  8. See Walter Eucken, ‘On the Theory of the Centrally Administered Economy: an Analysis of the German Experience’, Economica, London, Vol. 15, 1948, Part I, pp. 79–100 and Part II, pp. 173–93.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. For an account of the introduction of neo-liberal policies in West Germany see Ludwig Erhard, Prosperity Through Competition (London: Thames & Hudson, 1959).

    Google Scholar 

  10. For the intellectual background see Henry M. Oliver, ‘German Neo-Liberalism’, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Forge Village, Cambridge, Massachusetts, Vol. 74, 1960, pp. 117–49

    Article  Google Scholar 

  11. and Christian Watrin, ‘The Principles of the Social Market Economy’, Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft, Tübingen, Vol. 135, 1979, pp. 405–25.

    Google Scholar 

  12. See Walter Eucken, The Foundations of Economics (Edinburgh: William Hodge, 1950) p. 314.

    Google Scholar 

  13. Terence W. Hutchison, ‘Institutionalist Economics Old and New’, in Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft, Vol. 140, 1984, pp. 20–29.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Erhard, op. cit.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Alfred Müller-Armack, ‘Soziale Martwirtschaft’, Handwörterbuch der Sozialwissenschaften, Vol. 9 (Stuttgart, Tübingen and Göttingen: Gustav Fischer, J. C. B. Mohr [Paul Siebeck] and Vandenhoeck & Ruprecht, 1956) pp. 390–92. For a translation, see the companion volume, Germany’s Social Market Economy: Origins and Evolution (London: Macmillan for the Trade Policy Research Centre, 1989).

    Google Scholar 

  16. Quoted in Konrad Zweig, The Origins of the German Social Market Economy (London: Adam Smith Institute, 1980).

    Google Scholar 

  17. See also Müller-Armack: ‘The market is incapable of integrating society as a whole and of producing common attitudes and value norms without which society cannot exist’. ‘The Social Market Economy as an Economic and Social Order’, Review of Social Economy, Milwaukee, Wisconsin, Vol. 3, 1978, pp. 325–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  18. Eucken, The Foundations of Economics, op. cit., p. 32.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Müller-Armack, ‘The Principles of the Social Market Economy’, German Economic Review, Stuttgart, Vol. 3, 1965, p. 94.

    Google Scholar 

  20. Friedrich A. von Hayek, Law, Legislation and Liberty (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1973).

    Google Scholar 

  21. Eucken, This Unsuccessful Age (Edinburgh: William Hodge, 1951).

    Google Scholar 

  22. Wilhelm Röpke, The Social Crisis of Our Time (Edinburgh: William Hodge, 1950) p. 119.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Erhard, op. cit., p. 182.

    Google Scholar 

  24. ‘Neither the initial social data entering the market process nor the distribution of income issuing from it need be in harmony with our social standards and our concepts of justice.’ Müller-Armack, ‘The Social Market Economy as an Economic and Social Order’, loc. cit., pp. 325–31.

    Google Scholar 

  25. Röpke, op. cit., p. 177.

    Google Scholar 

  26. Eucken, This Unsuccessful Age, op. cit., p. 31.

    Google Scholar 

  27. Erhard, op. cit., p. 126.

    Google Scholar 

  28. Ludwig von Mises, Human Action, 3rd edn (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1963) p. 723.

    Google Scholar 

  29. Von Mises, The Anti-capitalistic Mentality (New Jersey: van Nostrand, 1956). The Ordo writers, however, would deny that the social market economy constituted any kind of a ‘middle way’.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Von Hayek, ‘What is “Social”? What does it Mean?’, in Studies in Philosophy, Politics and Economics (London: Routledge & Kegan Paul, 1967).

    Google Scholar 

  31. Barry, ‘Ideas versus Interests, the Classical Liberal Dilemma’, loc. cit.

    Google Scholar 

  32. James Buchanan, The Limits of Liberty: Between Anarchy and Leviathan (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1975).

    Google Scholar 

  33. For example, social justice is an end-state doctrine that stresses the intrinsic desirability of income and wealth distribution based on need and desert rather than market allocation.

    Google Scholar 

  34. Charles K. Rowley and Alan T. Peacock, Welfare Economics: a Liberal Restatement (London: Martin Robertson, 1975) p. 79.

    Google Scholar 

  35. Franz Böhm, ‘Left-wing and Right-wing Approaches to the Market Economy’, Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft, Vol. 135, 1979, p. 447.

    Google Scholar 

  36. Wirtschaftsordnungspolitik may be translated as ‘economic policy towards the organisation of the market’. See note 27 in ch. 4.

    Google Scholar 

  37. See Eucken, The Foundations of Economics, op. cit., and his posthumous Grundsätze der Wirtschaftspolitik (Bern and Tübingen: Francke, J. C. B. Möhr [Paul Siebeck], 1952).

    Google Scholar 

  38. For an informative discussion of Eucken’s political economy, see Dieter Schmidtchen, ‘German “Ordnungspolitik” as Institutional Choice’, Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft, Vol. 140, 1984, pp. 54–70.

    Google Scholar 

  39. See Eucken, The Foundation of Economics, op. cit., pp. 85–6.

    Google Scholar 

  40. Ibid, p. 83.

    Google Scholar 

  41. Eucken, ‘On the Theory of the Centrally Administered Economy’, loc. cit.

    Google Scholar 

  42. For an excellent discussion of these see Schmidtchen loc. cit., and Zweig, The Origins of the German Social Market Economy, op. cit.

    Google Scholar 

  43. Schmidtchen, loc. cit., p. 59.

    Google Scholar 

  44. L. N. White, ‘Bankruptcy as an Economie Intervention’, Journal of Libertarian Studies, Vol. 1, 1977, p. 281.

    Google Scholar 

  45. See also Bohm’s concise description of a market process: ‘The competitive order is an arrangement of coordination. This order must establish a broadly based freedom for the individual and a widely dispersed economic power structure. The market structures for demand and supply are distributed over many hands and the arbitrariness of collectivism is excluded’. ‘Freiheit und Ordnung in der Marktwirtschaft’, Ordo, Vol. 22, 1971, pp. 11–27.

    Google Scholar 

  46. Eucken, This Unsuccessful Age, op. cit., p. 66.

    Google Scholar 

  47. Ibid., p. 35.

    Google Scholar 

  48. Israel Kirzner, Competition and Entrepreneurship (Chicago and London: University of Chicago Press, 1973).

    Google Scholar 

  49. Henry C. Wallich, Mainsprings of the German Revival (New Haven: Yale University Press, 1955). It should be pointed out that prior to 1957 an Allied decartelisation law operated efficiently.

    Google Scholar 

  50. Eucken, This Unsuccessful Age, op. cit., p. 349.

    Google Scholar 

  51. Eucken, The Foundations of Economics, op. cit., p. 29.

    Google Scholar 

  52. For a short introduction to Alexander Rüstow’s political philosophy see Carl J. Friedrich, ‘Political Thought of Neo-liberalism’, American Political Science Review, Washington, Vol. 49, 1955, pp. 509–25.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  53. Peter Bernholz, ‘Freedom and Constitutional Order’, in Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft, Vol. 135, 1979, pp. 510–32.

    Google Scholar 

  54. Röpke, op. cit., p. 4.

    Google Scholar 

  55. Ibid., p. 86.

    Google Scholar 

  56. Ibid., p. 118.

    Google Scholar 

  57. Röpke, A Humane Economy: The Social Framework of the Free Market (London: Wolf, 1960) p. 78.

    Google Scholar 

  58. Christian Watrin, ‘Gesellschaftliches Eigentum und Arbeiterselbstverwaltung-ein Weg zur Humanisierung der Gesellschaft?’, in Ordo, Vol. 26, 1975. Translated in the companion volume of translations, Germany’s Social Market Economy: Origins and Evolution, op. cit., ch. 8.

    Google Scholar 

  59. Röpke, The Social Crisis of Our Time, op. cit., pp. 201–13.

    Google Scholar 

  60. Müller-Armack, ‘The Principles of the Social Market Economy’, loc. cit., p. 97.

    Google Scholar 

  61. See Wallich, op. cit., p. 2 and Egon Sohmen, ‘Competition and Growth: the Lesson of West Germany’, American Economic Review, Evanston, Vol. 49, 1959, pp. 54–70.

    Google Scholar 

  62. See especially Wallich, op. cit. and Wolfgang Stolper and Karl W. Roskamp, ‘Planning a Free Economy: Germany 1945–60’, in Zeitschrift für die gesamte Staatswissenschaft, Vol. 135, 1979, pp. 374–403.

    Google Scholar 

  63. Walter Hamm, ‘An den Grenzen des Wohlfahrtsstaates’, Ordo, Vol. 32, 1981, pp. 117–39; also reprinted in the companion volume of translations, Germany’s Social Market Economy: Origins and Evolution, op. cit., ch. 12.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Copyright information

© 1989 Trade Policy Research Centre

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Barry, N.P. (1989). Political and Economic Thought of German Neo-Liberals. In: Peacock, A., Willgerodt, H. (eds) German Neo-Liberals and the Social Market Economy. Trade Policy Research Centre. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1007/978-1-349-20148-8_5

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics