Skip to main content

Abstract

Competition policy1 and trade policy can be mutually reinforcing policy tools, working in tandem to foster markets that are contestable and competitive to the benefit of foreign and domestic interests alike. In some ways, these two policy instruments are flip sides of a coin—competition policy addresses private restraints of trade, whereas trade policy focuses on governmental restraints of trade. In the absence of effective competition policy, private restraints of trade can nullify the benefits of negotiated trade liberalization measures, reducing the benefits of the negotiated trade bargains such as tariff reductions and perhaps even public support for liberalization of trade.

From 1997–2000, Professor Janow served as Executive Director of the International Competition Policy Advisory Committee to the Attorney General and Assistant Attorney General for Antitrust, US Department of Justice.

This discussion uses the term competition policy to encompass those national laws (such as U.S. antitrust laws) and policies designed to promote competition in the marketplace and to deter and punish restrictive or abusive business practices. The main concern of competition law and policy is therefore private firm actions.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 429.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 549.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

References

  1. The antidumping laws require a showing that the dumping contributed to material injury, which is defined as harm that is not “inconsequential, immaterial or unimportant.” Section 771(7)(A) of the Tariff Act as amended, 19 U.S.C. §1677 (7)(A) (2001). US antitrust laws, however, have a higher standard of injury and causation and tend to require a showing of a substantial lessening of competition or unreasonable restraint of trade. Moreover, price discrimination in the context of the Robinson Patman Act provides certain defenses which are unavailable in the antidumping context, such as meeting competition. For an excellent comparison of antitrust and trade remedies and standards, see Harvey M. Applebaum, The Interface of the Trade Laws and the Antitrust laws, 6 Geo. Mason L. Rev 479 (1998).

    Google Scholar 

  2. In Section 2411(d)(3)(B)(i)(IV) of the Omnibus Trade and Competitiveness Act of 1988, 19 U.S. C. Section 2901(d)(3)(B)(i)(IV), Congress clarified that the “toleration by a foreign government of systematic anticompetitive activities by enterprises or among enterprises in the foreign country that have the effect of restricting, on a basis that is inconsistent with commercial considerations, access of United States goods or services to a foreign market” constitutes an “unreasonable” practice, actionable under Section 301 of the Trade Act of 1974, 19 U.S.C. §2411–2420. The Senate Finance Committee Report describes the inclusion of this “toleration” claim as stemming from the “growing conviction... that anti-competitive, market-restrictive behavior on the part of private firms, when coupled with the failure of a foreign government to intervene to eliminate such behavior, can act as a barrier to market access, which is as great as any formal government act, policy or practice alone.” See, S. Report No. 167, 100th Cong., 1st Sess. 85 (1987). Section 301 of the Trade Act of 1974, as amended, is the statutory basis by which the U.S. government initiates a trade case vis-à-vis a foreign government for possible violation of a trade agreement (e.g., a GATT or WTO commitment) or with respect to foreign governmental practices that are deemed unreasonable or discriminatory and that burden or restrict US commerce. This provision also provides the legal framework by which private parties, such as corporations, can petition the US government to investigate, and if necessary, take trade action against such governmental practices.

    Google Scholar 

  3. A recent study undertaken at the behest of the World Bank presents interesting new evidence regarding the adverse impact of international cartels on developing nations. See Margaret Levenstein and Valerie Suslow, Private International Cartels and Their Effect on Developing Countries, Background Paper for the World Bank’s World Development Report 2001, January 9, 2001. See also, Simon J. Evenett, Margaret C. Levenstein & Valerie Sulsow, International Cartel Enforcement: Lessons from the 1990s, 24 (9) World Economy 1221 (2001).

    Google Scholar 

  4. There have been a number of major international cartel cases prosecuted by the Antitrust Division, Department of Justice in the lysine, citric acid, vitamins and graphite electrodes industries. There are also numerous historical examples, such as in the heavy electrical machinery sector, For additional details see International Competition Policy Advisory Committee (“ICPAC”), Final Report, March 2000, U.S. Department of Justice, at 168. (“ICPAC Final Report”).

    Google Scholar 

  5. See United States v. Aluminum Co. of America, 148 F.2d, 416, 443 (2d. Cir. 1945).

    Google Scholar 

  6. See American Bar Association, Report of the Special Committee on International Antitrust, September 1, 1991.

    Google Scholar 

  7. This is the type of problem that the feature of Section 301 of the 1974 Trade Act, discussed in note 4, supra, was designed to reach.

    Google Scholar 

  8. See Merit E. Janow, Public and Private Restraints that Limit Access to Markets, in Market Access After the Uruguay Round (OECD, 1996).

    Google Scholar 

  9. For a period of time during the late 1980s and early 1990s, a particular set of problems was thought to be presented by the Japanese keiretsu, groups of companies with cross-ownership of shares and established patterns of doing business with other members of the group. As discussed in the section that follows, a major US-Japan trade dispute involving allegations of discriminatory access to distribution channels was the US Film case, often referred to as Kodak-Fuji since it was first brought to the attention of the U.S. government by Kodak Photo Film Company. See Report of the WTO Panel, Japan—Measures Affecting Consumer Photographic Film and Paper, W/DS44/R (1998) (“Japan-Film”).

    Google Scholar 

  10. See Statement of Chairman Robert Pitofsky and Commissioners Janet D. Steiger, Roscoe B. Starek III and Christine A. Varney in The Matter of The Boeing Company/McDonnell Douglas Corporation, File No. 971-0051, available at http://www.ftc.gov/opa/1997/9707/boeingsta.htm

  11. For a more complete discussion of this case, see Merit E. Janow, Unilateral and Bilateral Approaches to Competition Policy: An Analysis Drawing Lessons from the Trade Experience, in Brookings Trade Forum 1998 (Robert Z. Lawrence ed. 1999) at 253.

    Google Scholar 

  12. See Clair Wilcox, A Charter for World Trade 105 (1949).

    Google Scholar 

  13. William Diebold, The End of the ITO, 16 International Finance 18 (1952).

    Google Scholar 

  14. The draft convention included the same list of restrictive practices as the Havana Charter, with one exception relating to technology agreements. See Diane P. Wood, The Impossible Dream: Real International Antitrust, U. Chi. Legal F. 277, 284 (1992). For details of the draft convention, see F. M. Scherer, Competition Policies for an Integrated World Economy 39 (1994).

    Google Scholar 

  15. Wood, supra Diane P. Wood, The Impossible Dream: Real International Antitrust, U. Chi. Legal F. (1992) note 18, at 284–85.

    Google Scholar 

  16. See GATT BISD 7th Supp. 29 (1960).

    Google Scholar 

  17. Specifically the recommendation states that “... the party addressed should accord sympathetic consideration to and should afford adequate opportunity for consultations with the requesting party, with a view to reaching mutually satisfactory consultations, and if it agrees that such harmful effects are present it should take such measures as it deems appropriate”. See, GATT BISD 9th Supp. 28 (1961). This resolution existed in relative obscurity until it was invoked in 1996 by the United States in the context of a film dispute with Japan. See discussion later in this section.

    Google Scholar 

  18. The GATT provided legal remedies for government actions that had the effect of nullifying and impairing the benefits that another GATT member received as part of the market access it was promised in its quid pro quo for the market access that it provided. The GATT also recognized there could be measures or developments that were not a direct violation of agreed-upon commitments but which nevertheless had the effect of nullifying or impairing the intended benefits of the liberalization measures. For additional discussion of this subject see Bernard M. Hoeckman and Petros C. Mavroidis, Competition Policy and the GATT, 17 The World Economy 141 (1994).

    Google Scholar 

  19. See Report of the GATT Panel (adopted), Japan-Trade in Semiconductors, BISD 35th Supp. 116, at 155 (1988).

    Google Scholar 

  20. See Dewey Ballantine for Eastman Kodak Company, Privatizing Protection: Japanese Market Barriers in Consumer Photographic Film and Consumer Photographic Paper (May 1995). The facts in this case are well known and exhaustively documented. For purposes of this discussion, I shall highlight some of the policy and procedural consequences of the case. Relevant background writings include: James Durling, Anatomy of A Trade Dispute: A Documentary History of the Kodak-Fuji Film Dispute (2001); John Linarelli, The Role of Dispute Settlement in World Trade Law: Some Lessons from the Kodak-Fuji Dispute, 31 Law and Policy in Int. Business 2 (2000); Sara Dillon, Fuji-Kodak, the World Trade Organization and the Death of Domestic Political Constituencies, 8(2) Minnesota Journal of Global Trade 197 (1999).

    Google Scholar 

  21. See supra, note 4. One earlier petition, which involved amorphous metal transformers, had focused on this provision but was ultimately withdrawn and negotiated bilaterally without invoking Section 301.

    Google Scholar 

  22. See Dewey Ballantine, supra note 25. This paper also argues that an anticompetitive market structure operated in Japan in violation of Japan’s Antimonopoly Act, and that the Japan Fair Trade Commission had acted indirectly to support it, allegedly by suppressing promotional activity in the consumer photographic film and paper industry through the Government of Japan’s laws against premiums and other marketing restraints.

    Google Scholar 

  23. Japan Fair Trade Commission (JFTC), Survey of Transactions Among Firms Regarding Photographic Color Film for General Use, July 23, 1997. Available at http://www.ftc.go.jp/e-page/press/1997/film1/film1.htm

  24. The US argued that certain distribution-related measures, restrictions on large stores and promotional measures resulted in a GATT Article XXIII:1(b) non-violation nullification or impairment of benefits accruing to the United States based on tariff concessions made by Japan in the Kennedy, Tokyo and Uruguay Rounds. The Panel rejected these claims, relying in part on the fact that many of the challenged measures were relatively old, and that the causality between the measure and the distribution system was not well established. The Panel also rejected the U.S. violation claims, which included an argument that the JFTC and certain fair trade council’s failure to publish certain enforcement actions were a violation of GATT Article X: 1. See Japan—Film, supra note 12, ¶¶ 10.390–393.

    Google Scholar 

  25. Id. at ¶ 10.389. The Panel found that “government policy or action need not necessarily have a substantially binding or compulsory nature for it to entail a likelihood of compliance by private actors in a way so as to nullify or impair legitimately expected benefits within the purview of Article XXII:1(b). Indeed, it is clear that non-binding actions, which include sufficient incentives or disincentives for private parties to act in a particular manner can potentially have adverse effects on competitive conditions of market access.” Id. at ¶¶ 10.389–90.

    Google Scholar 

  26. Id. at ¶¶ 10.43–46

    Google Scholar 

  27. For a more complete discussion of this potential application of GATT rules, see also Merit E. Janow, Competition Policy and the WTO, in The Uruguay Round and Beyond (Jagdish Bhagwati and Mathias Hirsch eds. 1998).

    Google Scholar 

  28. This voluntary code contained several provisions calling for special concern to the problems facing developing nations. The code’s substantive provisions condemn collusive anticompetitive actions such as price-fixing, collusive tendering, market or customer allocations, sales, or production quotas and various kinds of concerted refusals to deal. The Code also condemns abuses of dominant position such as predatory behavior, discriminatory commercial terms and anticompetitive mergers. Wood, supra Diane P. Wood, The Impossible Dream: Real International Antitrust, U. Chi. Legal F. (1992) note 18, at 286.

    Google Scholar 

  29. Wood, supra Diane P. Wood, The Impossible Dream: Real International Antitrust, U. Chi. Legal F. (1992) note 18, at 28. See also, Global Forum Oncompetition and Trade Policy, Harmonization of International Competition Law Enforcement 15, n. 73 (1995).

    Google Scholar 

  30. See Agreement between the Government of the United States of America and the Commission of the European Communities Regarding the Application of the Competition Laws, September 23, 1991, available at: http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/international/docs

  31. This agreement contained six comity principles that would be considered by the parties in seeking an appropriate accommodation of the competing interests. These include factors such as the relative importance of the activities involved within the enforcing party’s territory; the presence or absence of a purpose to affect consumers, suppliers or competitors within the enforcing Party’s territory; the relative significant of the effects of the anticompetitive activities on the enforcing jurisdiction; the existence or absence of expectations that would be furthered or defeated; the degree of conflict or consistency between the enforcement activities and the other party’s laws; and the extent to which the enforcement activities of one party would impact the other jurisdiction. For additional detail see, Agreement, supra note 36, Article VI.

    Google Scholar 

  32. Agreement between the Government of the United States of America and the Government of Australia, A Mutual Legal Antitrust Enforcement Assistance Agreement, available at: http://www.usdoj.gov/atr/public/international

  33. For a more detailed assessment of bilateral antitrust cooperation agreements, see Janow, supra Merit E. Janow, Unilateral and Bilateral Approaches to Competition Policy: An Analysis Drawing Lessons from the Trade Experience, in Brookings Trade Forum 1998 (Robert Z. Lawrence ed. 1999) note 14 and Transatlantic Cooperation on Competition Policy in Antitrust Goes Global (Simon J. Evenett, Alexander Lehman and Benn Steil eds. 2000).

    Google Scholar 

  34. See Report of the GATT Panel (adopted), Italian Discrimination Against Imported Agricultural Machinery BISD 7th Supp. 60 (1958).

    Google Scholar 

  35. See, for example, the discussion of these concepts in Report of the WTO Panel, Korea-Taxes on Alcoholic Beverages, W/DS75/R and W/DS84/R (1998), ¶¶ 10.95–10.97 and 10.44–10.45. The Appellate Body upheld the Panel’s decision. Report of the Appellate Body, Korea-Taxes on Alcoholic Beverages, W/DS75/AB/R and W/DS84/AB/R (1999).

    Google Scholar 

  36. See Fourth Protocol to the General Agreement on Services (April 30, 1996) S/L 20, available at http://www.wto.org/services

  37. See WTO, Report to the Council for Trade in Services on the Development of Disciplines on Domestic Regulation in the Accountancy Sector, S/WPPS/4 (December 10, 1998).

    Google Scholar 

  38. See Report (1998) of the Working Group on the Interaction Between Trade and Competition Policy to the General Council, WT/WGTCP/2 (December 8, 1998).

    Google Scholar 

  39. Former U.S. Trade Representative Charlene Barshefsky suggested that the EU was virtually alone in its interest in global negotiations on competition policy. See 17 Inside U.S. Trade, No. 51, at 3 (December 24, 1999). This appears to be less the case today than when that statement was made.

    Google Scholar 

  40. World Trade Organization, Ministerial Declaration (Fourth Session of the Ministerial Conference, Doha), WT/MIN(01)/DEC/1, November 9–14, 2001, ¶¶ 23–25.

    Google Scholar 

  41. Robert D. Anderson and Frederic Jenny, Current Developments on Competition Policy in the World Trade Organization, Antitrust Magazine, Fall 2001.

    Google Scholar 

  42. See K. Mehta, The Role of Competition in a Globalized Trade Environment, Speech to the Third WTO Symposium on Competition Policy and the Multilateral System, Geneva, (April 7, 1999).

    Google Scholar 

  43. See Communication from the European Community and its Member States, WT/WGTCP/W/152.

    Google Scholar 

  44. At a regional WTO workshop in Capetown, South Africa, an EU official clarified that the EU thought there was significant interest around the world in entering into a multilateral agreement at the WTO. However, if at the conclusion of negotiations, there were still developing countries that were hesitant and not convinced that such an agreement was in their interest, they should have the possibility to opt out of it. See Informal Report on Workshop Proceedings, WTO Regional Workshop on Competition Policy, Economic Development and the Multilateral Trading System, organized by the WTO Secretariat in Cooperation with the Governments of South Africa and the United Kingdom (February 22–24, 2001).

    Google Scholar 

  45. See, e.g., Joel Klein, A Note of Caution with Respect to a WTO Agenda on Competition Policy (Remarks to the Royal Institute of International Affairs, Chatham House, November 1996).

    Google Scholar 

  46. See “USTR Zoellick outlines US efforts to promote growth and development by launching new trade round; US-EU effort directed at expanding and strengthening global trading system”, http://www.ustr.gov/releases/2001/07/01-54.pdf This statement contains the following language, “The United States can see merit in adherence to core principles of transparency, non-discrimination and procedural fairness. We can also support consultative and capacity building efforts to help countries develop modern competition policy that promotes efficient, effective and dynamic markets.”

  47. See Joel Klein, A Reality Check on Antitrust Rules in the World Trade Organization, And a Practical Way Forward on International Antitrust, Address before the OECD Conference on Trade and Competition. (Paris, June 30, 1999).

    Google Scholar 

  48. Id.

    Google Scholar 

  49. See The Interaction Between Trade and Competition Policy, Communication from Kenya on behalf of the African Group, Preparations for the 1999 Ministerial Conference, WT/GC/W/300, August 6, 1999.

    Google Scholar 

  50. See Communication from the Republic of South Africa, WT/WGTCP/W/138, October 11, 1999, pp. 2, 4. In recent years, South Africa has introduced an active competition law and policy regime. Perhaps as a result, South African trade and competition officials have indicated a certain receptivity to some WTO rules in this policy area.

    Google Scholar 

  51. For a reprint of the Code developed by the Munich Group, see: 64 Antitrust & Trade Reg. Rep (BNA), August 19, 1993.

    Google Scholar 

  52. See Report of the Group of Experts, Competition Policy in the New Trade Order: Strengthening International Cooperation and Rules (July 1995)

    Google Scholar 

  53. See ICPAC Final Report, supra note 6.

    Google Scholar 

  54. Id. at 268

    Google Scholar 

  55. Id.

    Google Scholar 

  56. See Merit E. Janow, The Initiative for a Global Competition Forum: A Report on a Meeting Convened and Hosted by the IBA and Held at Ditchley Park, Business Law International, Issue 2 (2001).

    Google Scholar 

  57. See Remarks by Assistant Attorney-General Joel I. Klein, Antitrust Division, Department of Justice, Presented at Fordham Law Institute, 24th Annual Conference on International Antitrust Law and Policy (New York, October 16, 1997).

    Google Scholar 

  58. See Robert Howse From Politics to Technology—and Back Again: The Fate of the Multilateral Trading Regime, 96 American Journal of International Law 94 (2002).

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2005 Springer Science+Business Media, Inc.

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Janow, M.E. (2005). Trade and Competition Policy. In: Macrory, P.F.J., Appleton, A.E., Plummer, M.G. (eds) The World Trade Organization: Legal, Economic and Political Analysis. Springer, Boston, MA. https://doi.org/10.1007/0-387-22688-5_57

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics