Skip to main content
  • 4533 Accesses

Abstract

The Uruguay Round negotiation was the eighth postwar multilateral trade negotiation conducted under the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (“GATT”). As with other GATT negotiations, its purpose was to liberalize trade. One might have expected the Uruguay Round, as with other GATT negotiations, to continue the steady movement toward a more open and predictable international trade regime. It did not do this. Instead, the Uruguay Round produced a profound alteration of the trade regime in response to an equally profound transformation of international economic relations. It amounted to system change in the world economy.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this chapter

Chapter
USD 29.95
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
eBook
USD 429.00
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Available as PDF
  • Read on any device
  • Instant download
  • Own it forever
Hardcover Book
USD 549.99
Price excludes VAT (USA)
  • Durable hardcover edition
  • Dispatched in 3 to 5 business days
  • Free shipping worldwide - see info

Tax calculation will be finalised at checkout

Purchases are for personal use only

Institutional subscriptions

Preview

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Unable to display preview. Download preview PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  1. Ernest H. Preeg, Traders in a Brave New World: the Uruguay Round and the Future of the International System 28 (1995).

    Google Scholar 

  2. Gatt, International Trade 1985–86 (1986) at 26. See alsoGilbert R. Winham, International Trade and the Tokyo Round Negotiation (1986).

    Google Scholar 

  3. By March 31, 1994, only 29 developing and transitional countries had signed one or more of the Tokyo Round Agreements, GATT, GUIDE TO GATT LAW AND PRACTICE 1056–59 (1994).

    Google Scholar 

  4. Results of the Uruguay Round Signing Ceremony of April 15th, 1994 in Marrabesh, Morocco. GATT, NUR086, 18 April 1994.

    Google Scholar 

  5. Raymond Vernon, The World Trade Organization: A New Stage in International Trade and Development, 36 Harvard International Law Journal 329 (Spring 1995).

    Google Scholar 

  6. Winham, supraGilbert R. Winham, International Trade and the Tokyo Round Negotiation (1986) note 2, Chapter 2, “Background: Creating the Capacity to Negotiate.”

    Google Scholar 

  7. The reader is encouraged to consult two excellent histories and two excellent memoirs: John Croome, Reshaping Theworld Trading System: a History of the Uruguay Round (1995); Preeg, supra note 1; Alan Oxley, the Challenge of Free Trade (1990); and Hugo Paemen and Alexandra Bensch, From the GATT to the WTO: the European Community in the Uruguay Round (1995).

    Google Scholar 

  8. Odell has examined market conditions as an explanation for international economic negotiations, which is analogous to the argument presented here. See John Odell, Understanding International Trade Policies: An Emerging Synthesis, 43 World Politics 139 (October 1990).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  9. Senior Officials Group, Record of Discussions: Note by the Secretariat (GATT Doc., SR.SOG/2 of November 22, 1985) at 17. This observation was supported by the Chief Negotiator of the European Union: “Its [the Uruguay Round] aim was quite simply to carry out a complete overhaul of the multilateral trading system, whilst at the same time broadening and deepening its scope.” Paemen and Bensch, supra note 7, at 89.

    Google Scholar 

  10. A former Australian Head of Delegation to the Uruguay Round has observed: “When the United States started advocating a new trade round, its first supporters were Japan, the smaller industrialized countries and some of the Latin Americans, mainly the agricultural exporters. The European Community was ambivalent.” Oxley, supra Alan Oxley, The Challenge of Free Trade (1990) note 7, at 97.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Angus Maddison, The World Economy in the 20th Century 36, 67 (1989).

    Google Scholar 

  12. Id. at 88.

    Google Scholar 

  13. Sylvia Ostry, The Post-Cold War Trading System: Who’s on First? (1997), esp. Chapter 5, “The East Asian Challenge”.

    Google Scholar 

  14. Maddison, supraAngus Maddison, The World Economy in the 20th Century 36, (1989) note 11 at 67.

    Google Scholar 

  15. Data compiled from GATT, International Trade, Vols 1981/82, 1983/84, 1985/86, and 1986/87.

    Google Scholar 

  16. Maddison, supraAngus Maddison, The World Economy in the 20th Century 36, (1989) note 11, at 88.

    Google Scholar 

  17. Paul Krugman, The Age of Diminished Expectations: U.S. Economic Policy in the 1990s (1992), Chapter 3.

    Google Scholar 

  18. GATT, International Trade, Vol. 1987/88, 29.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Maddison, supraAngus Maddison, The World Economy in the 20th Century 36, (1989) note 11, at Table D-6, 143.

    Google Scholar 

  20. Senior Officials’ Group, supra note 9 (GATT doc. SR.SOG/2 of November 22, 1985), at 8.

    Google Scholar 

  21. See Services in the Domestic and Global Economy, GATT International Trade 1988–1989 Vol. I, at 23–43 (1989).

    Google Scholar 

  22. Id. at 25.

    Google Scholar 

  23. See William E. Brock, A Simple Plan for Negotiating on Trade in Services 5:3 The World Economy 229 (November 1982). See alsoPaemen and Bensch, supra note 7, at 17: “For societies keen to retain the privileges of wealth, the limits to the development of the North-North trade in goods provide justification enough for launching a new initiative to conquer new markets. When it comes to expanding markets, the services sector appears to be promising.”

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. GATT International Trade 1990–91 Vol. II, 1 (1990).

    Google Scholar 

  25. Senior Officials’ Group, Record of Discussions: Note by the Secretariat (GATT doc. SR.SOG/9 of November 22, 1985), at 1.

    Google Scholar 

  26. Senior Officials’ Group, supra note 25 at 6.

    Google Scholar 

  27. GATT, International Trade 1988–89 Vol. I (1989), Tables 22, 31. Western Europe had 58 per cent of services trade (exports plus imports), followed by Asia with 18 per cent and North America with 14 per cent.

    Google Scholar 

  28. See Gilbert R. Winham, Explanations of Developing Country Behaviour in the Uruguay Round, 21 World Competition 109–34 (March 1998).

    Google Scholar 

  29. GATT, International Trade 1985–1986 (G 1986), Table 1.9, 23.

    Google Scholar 

  30. GATT, International Trade 1987–1988, Vol. II (1988), at 39.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Id.

    Google Scholar 

  32. GATT, International Trade, 1987–1988, Vol. I, at 18 (1988).

    Google Scholar 

  33. Senior Officials’ Group, Record of Discussions: Note by the Secretariat (GATT doc. SR.SOG/10 of November 22, 1985), at 13.

    Google Scholar 

  34. SeePeter J. Katzenstein, Small States in World Markets: Industrial Policy in Europe (1985).

    Google Scholar 

  35. Maddison, supraAngus Maddison, The World Economy in the 20th Century 36, (1989) note 11, 27.

    Google Scholar 

  36. C. Fred Bergsten, The United States and the World Economy, 294 The Annals 12 (March 1982).

    Google Scholar 

  37. Id.

    Google Scholar 

  38. SeePatrick Low, Trading Free: the GATT and US Trade Policy (1993). Low suggests that unilateral actions alarmed U.S. trading partners including the EU and may have created an incentive to negotiate.

    Google Scholar 

  39. Lipsey has noted: “Rarely in human history has such a decisive verdict been delivered on two competing systems.” Richard G. Lipsey, Global Change and Economic Policy, in The Culture and Power of Knowledge (Nico Stehr and Richard V. Ericson eds. 1992) 279–283.

    Google Scholar 

  40. See generally, Francis Fukuyama, The End of History and the Last Man (1992).

    Google Scholar 

  41. Cerny has defined deregulation as meaning “... the lifting or abolishing of government regulations on a range of economic activities in order to allow markets to work more freely....” Philip G. Cerny, The Limits of Deregulation: Transnational Interpenetration and Policy Change, 19 European Journal of Political Research 173 (1991).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  42. Report of the Royal Commission on the Economic Union and Development Prospects for Canada, I, at 66 (1985) (“Report”).

    Google Scholar 

  43. Peter Katzenstein, Small States in World Markets: Industrial Policy in Europe (1985).

    Google Scholar 

  44. Robert Wade, Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization (1990).

    Google Scholar 

  45. Wayne Sandholtz and John Zysman, 1992: Recasting the European Bargain, 42:1 World Politics 95, 112 (October 1989).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  46. See e.g., Thomas J. Biersteker, The ‘Triumph’ of Liberal Economic Ideas in the Developing World, in Global Change, Regional Response: the New International Context of Development (Barbara Stallings ed. 1995).

    Google Scholar 

  47. Report, I, supra note 43, at 60.

    Google Scholar 

  48. Oxley, supraAlan Oxley, The Challenge of Free Trade (1990) note 7, at 42.

    Google Scholar 

  49. Cohen and Zysman, Manufacturingmatters: The Myth of the Post-Industrial Economy 4 (1987).

    Google Scholar 

  50. Robert Reich, The Work of Nations 3 (1991).

    Google Scholar 

  51. Peter Dicken, Global Shift: Transforming the World Economy 5 (1998).

    Google Scholar 

  52. Id.

    Google Scholar 

  53. Cohen has defined global finance as encompassing “... all types of cross-border portfolio-type transactions—borrowing and lending, trading of currencies or other financial claims, and the provision of commercial banking or other financial services. It also includes capital flows associated with foreign direct investment....” Benjamin J. Cohen, Phoenix Risen: The Resurrection of Global Finance, 48 World Politics 268, 269 (January 1996).

    Article  Google Scholar 

  54. Goldblatt et al have stated: “The ratio of foreign-exchange turnover to world trade has climbed from 10:1 in the early 1980s to more than 60:1 today.” David Goldblatt, David Held, Anthony McGrew and Jonathan Perraton, Economic Globalization and the Nation-State: Shifting Balances of Power, 22 Alternatives 269, 276 (1997).

    Google Scholar 

  55. John B. Goodman, Monetary Sovereignty: the Politics of Central Banking in Western Europe 18 (1992).

    Google Scholar 

  56. Morris Goldstein, David Folkerts-Landau, Peter Garber, Liliana Rojas-Suarez, and Michael Spencer, International Capital Markets: Part I. Exchange Rate Management and International Capital Flows 24 (1993).

    Google Scholar 

  57. See Cohen, supra, Benjamin J. Cohen, Phoenix Risen: The Resurrection of Global Finance, 48 World Politics 268, 269 (January 1996) note 54.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  58. Examples include central and local government securities, corporate debt, equities, commercial paper, bank certificates of deposit, asset-backed securities, and exchange-traded and over-the-counter derivatives. See Morris Goldstein et al., supra DAVID FOLKERTS-LANDAU, PETER GARBER, LILIANA ROJAS-SUAREZ, and MICHAEL SPENCER, International Capital Markets: Part I. Exchange Rate Management and International Capital Flows 24 (1993) note 57, at 2.

    Google Scholar 

  59. World Investment Repoprt: Transnational Corporations, Employment and the Workplace 120 (UNCTAD, 1994).

    Google Scholar 

  60. See, e.g., Howard M. Wachtel The Money Mandarins: The Making of a New Supranational Economic Order (1990); and Richard Mckenzie and Dwight Lee Quicksilver Capitalism: How the Rapid Movement of Wealth Has Changed the World (1991).

    Google Scholar 

  61. World Investment Report: Transnational Corporations, Employment and Theworkplace, supra, note 60, at 120.

    Google Scholar 

  62. Capital Goes Global (Schools Brief ) The Economist October 25, 1997, at 87. See also Alan M. Taylor, International Capital Mobility in History: The Saving-Investment Relationship (Working Paper 5743) (Cambridge, MA: National Bureau of Economic Research, September, 1996).

    Google Scholar 

  63. Survey: The World Economy, The Economist September 20, 1997, at 7–8.

    Google Scholar 

  64. Shallow integration refers to “the spread of market linkages through greater trade and factor flows”, while deep integration involves “participation in the international division of labour at the level of production”, and “establishes a more lasting linkage between economic agents located in different countries.” World Investment Report (UNCTAD, 1994), at 118.

    Google Scholar 

  65. Richard Blackhurst and Adrian Otten, Trade and Foreign Direct Investment: New Report by the Wto 6 (1996) (emphasis supplied).

    Google Scholar 

  66. See e.g., Jean Jacques Servan-Schreiber, The American Challenge (1969).

    Google Scholar 

  67. Rutter defined stocks as “the cumulative historical book value of direct investors’ equity (including reinvested earnings) in, and net outstanding loans to, their foreign affiliates.” Flows are “annual direct investment capital flows (equity, reinvested earnings and intercompany debt)....” John Rutter, Recent Trends in International Direct Investment (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Department of Commerce, Investment Analysis Division, August, 1992), at 1.

    Google Scholar 

  68. Id., at 8. In 1989, the U.S. share of world outward stocks of IDI was 27.9 per cent, and its share of inward stocks was 26.85. per cent.

    Google Scholar 

  69. Recent Developments in International Investment and Transnational Corporations: Trends in Foreign Direct Investment 5 (1995).

    Google Scholar 

  70. For example, Ostry defines it as follows: “The ever tightening and more complex linkages among nationstates, first by trade, then by financial flows, and more recently by a surge of foreign direct investment have greatly enhanced the power and ubiquitousness of the multilateral enterprise in the international arena. This deepening integration of the world economy, fed or even led by the continuing revolution in information and communication technology has reinforced the shift to trade policy inside the border and the latent push to system harmonization.” Ostry, supra Sylvia Ostry, The Post-Cold War Trading System: Who’S on First? (1997), esp. Chapter 5, “The East Asian Challenge” note 13, at xvi–xvii.

    Google Scholar 

  71. OECD, Globalization of Industry: Overview and Sector Reports 15 (1996).

    Google Scholar 

  72. Lipsey, supra Richard G. Lipsey, Global Change and Economic Policy, in The Culture and Power of Knowledge (Nico Stehr and Richard V. Ericson eds. 1992) note 40 at 285.

    Google Scholar 

  73. Globalization of Industry, supra note 72, at 31.

    Google Scholar 

  74. Id. at 37, 39 and accompanying tables.

    Google Scholar 

  75. Paul F. Anderson, Hugh M. Dickinson and Gerald Komlofske, Globalization: Its Meaning for the Automotive Industry, 15.2 JAMA Forum (October 1996) at 3.

    Google Scholar 

  76. The OECD report notes: “[Globalization] reinforces the general policy prescriptions of trade liberalisation and non-discriminatory trade and investment regimes.... it also underscores the costly and ineffective character of discriminatory policies at a time when “domestic” firms and products are more difficult to recognise and interlinkages and policy leakages are the order of the day.” Globalization of Industry, supra note 72, at 42.

    Google Scholar 

  77. See The World Economy: The Future of the State, The Economist, September 20, 1997; and Robert Wade Globalization and Its Limits: Reports of the Death of the National Economy are Greatly Exaggerated in National Diversity and Global Capitalism 60–88 (Suzanne Berger and Ronald Dore eds. 1996).

    Google Scholar 

  78. Geza Feketekuty, The New Trade Agenda at 29, Occasional Paper 40 (Washington, D.C.: Group of Thirty, 1992).

    Google Scholar 

  79. The paper commenced with the statement: “As the Uruguay Round draws to a close... a whole new set of challenges [vi3, globalization of production and markets] has emerged since the Uruguay Round was launched.” The report concluded: “The multilateral trading system must inevitably adapt to the process of internationalization and globalization.” Geza Feketekuty, The New Trade Agenda at 29, Occasional Paper 40 (Washington, D.C.: Group of Thirty, 1992) Id. at 1, 31.

    Google Scholar 

  80. Countdown for the Uruguay Round, Address by Peter Sutherland to the Forum de l’Expansion, Paris, October 19, 1993, at 1.

    Google Scholar 

  81. Id. at 2–3.

    Google Scholar 

  82. Statement by Peter D. Sutherland, Director-General of GATT, to the Interim Committee of the International Monetary Fund, Washington, D.C., September 26, 1993, at 1.

    Google Scholar 

  83. Economic Relations: A Necessary Basis for Peace, Address by Peter D. Sutherland, Director-General, World Trade Organization, to the Inaugural Conference of UCC 150, University College, Cork, January 3, 1995, at 2.

    Google Scholar 

  84. Sutherland went on to say that: “The achievement of the Uruguay Round [was] to extend liberalisation to international markets for goods, services and technology.” Consolidating Economic Globalization, Address by Peter D. Sutherland to the Canadian Club, Toronto, March 21, 1994, at 2–3.

    Google Scholar 

  85. Key Issues in the Global Economy-How the WTO Contributes to Global Solutions, Address by Peter D. Sutherland, Director-General, World Trade Organization, to senior media representatives, Davos, January 29, 1995, at 2–3.

    Google Scholar 

  86. Id. at 9.

    Google Scholar 

  87. Leaders and Choices: What the Uruguay Round Needs to Succeed, Address by Peter D. Sutherland to the National Conference of the Confederation of British Industry, Harrogate, November 15, 1993, at 5.

    Google Scholar 

  88. A New Framework for International Economic Relations, Third Hayek Memorial Lecture by Peter Sutherland, Director-General GATT to the Institute of Economic Affairs in London, June 16, 1994, at 6.

    Google Scholar 

  89. Id. at 6.

    Google Scholar 

  90. Countdown for the Uruguay Round, supra note 81, at 2–3.

    Google Scholar 

  91. Editorial, Wall Street Journal, December 15, 1993.

    Google Scholar 

  92. Paul Krugman, The Age of Diminished Expectations: U.S. Economic Policy in the 1990S 61 (1992).

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Editor information

Editors and Affiliations

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

Copyright information

© 2005 Springer Science+Business Media, Inc.

About this chapter

Cite this chapter

Winham, G.R. (2005). An Interpretative History of the Uruguay Round Negotiation. In: Macrory, P.F.J., Appleton, A.E., Plummer, M.G. (eds) The World Trade Organization: Legal, Economic and Political Analysis. Springer, Boston, MA. https://doi.org/10.1007/0-387-22688-5_1

Download citation

Publish with us

Policies and ethics