Skip to main content
Log in

Stage-specific family structure models: implicit parameter restrictions and Bayesian model comparison with an application to prosocial behavior

  • Published:
Review of Economics of the Household Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

The two most frequently used specifications in stage-specific family structure analyses of young adult outcomes-state × stage and event × stage-impose restrictions on the parameters of the underlying model of child development. The restrictions imposed by the state specification have substantive a priori disadvantages, implying that use of the state specification requires justification by a specification test. Because the state and event specifications are non-nested, a classical approach to specification testing runs into practical problems. We demonstrate the advantages of a Bayesian approach to the specification testing problem using two applications to young adult prosocial behavior-charitable giving and volunteering. Substantive results are that family structure transitions during adolescence are negatively associated with subsequent giving, and transitions during middle childhood are positively associated with subsequent volunteering. There are other substantive results that would have been missed had we not realized that the state and event specifications impose restrictions on the underlying model and had we not made specification testing a prerequisite for substantive analysis.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Substantive interest in the family structure—prosocial behavior association was initiated by Chase-Lansdale et al. (1995) who argue that marital distress interferes with the development of caring in children. Brown and Lichter (2007) estimate a small negative (statistically insignificant) association between being born to a single mother and subsequent volunteering when 18–25 years old, but they do not examine a stage-specific family structure specification.

  2. Eighty-one and a half percent of young adults in our sample meet these criteria. Once we make our main points in the model with the “birth-mother throughout” and “no more than two changes” assumptions, it will be easy to trace the further implications for young adults whose family structures involved time apart from the birth-mother or three-plus changes.

  3. The theory is that parental control and/or stress mediate the effects of family structure on child outcomes. However, the majority of papers in the family structure—child outcome literature, the present paper among them, do not have direct measures of parental control or stress, so it must be kept in mind that there are ways unrelated to family structure that parental control and/or stress may affect child outcomes that are not captured by eq. (1). Interestingly, there is evidence that parental control is not related to the giving and volunteering done by 12–18 year-olds (Ottoni-Wilhelm and Perdue under review). Other channels may mediate the effects of family structure. Parental role-modeling desired behavior and peer effects are examples.

    Family structure changes may have effects because they induce changes in family income (“economic hardship theory”; see Hill et al. 2001; Fronstin et al. 2001), mothers’ employment, or residential location. Stage-specific measures of these variables are not included in eq. (1) to maintain a focus on the restrictions imposed by standard family structure specifications. However, these variables are included in our empirical analysis. It is straightforward to extend our theoretical analysis to describe restrictions imposed by standard stage-specific specifications of these variables.

  4. To our knowledge the only previous paper constructing entire-childhood family structure histories using the PSID is Hill et al. 2001.

  5. Corak (2001) finds that experiences of death and divorce during the teenage years have similar associations with labor market outcomes and the use of public assistance, but that divorce has stronger associations with marriage outcomes. In our sample, 26 instances where a birth-mother, birth-father or step-father leaves the child’s household are due to the death of the parent. If these 26 are dropped the change in results is negligible.

  6. Bayesian model comparison rewards parsimony. The results indicate that the additional variables in the event-complementarity-interaction specification do not improve the model fit enough relative to the any-complementarity-interaction specification to offset the latter’s advantage in parsimony.

  7. Transition in adolescence is associated with −.09 (SD = .04) in the probability of giving. For brevity we focus on the conditional expected giving, but further results about the probability of giving are available upon request.

  8. The volunteering models are standard time allocation specifications: the log current income is replaced by the log wage and log non-labor income.

  9. In the giving models the birth-mother-leaves variables do not add explanatory power beyond the divorce/(re)marriage variables in the event specification and the transition variables in the any-transition specification.

  10. In column 4 the complementary and interaction parameters are dropped from the event and any specifications because there is not evidence of associations between these variables and volunteering in column 3’s event-complementarity-interaction and any-complementarity-interaction specifications.

  11. Booth and Amato (2001) find evidence consistent with the stress relief hypothesis for young adult psychological well-being, number of close relatives, number of close friends, and happiness in intimate relationships. Consistent with a stress relief interpretation, estimates from an event specification (not shown) indicate that middle childhood divorces (rather than (re)marriages) are primarily responsible for the positive stage 2 transition–giving association.

  12. In an applications like volunteering where the state specification’s restrictions (relative to the event specification) do not severely constrain the estimation—hence the state specification is very similar empirically to the event specification—the state and event specifications can be seen as complementary rather than as alternatives. In such cases one might choose to do further research with the event specification by extending it to model complementarity across stages and interactions within a stage (as pointed out above) or by more detailed modeling of the different reasons why the events occur (e.g., death, institutionalization, etc.). We are grateful to a reviewer for pointing this out.

References

  • Antecol, H., & Bedard, K. (2007). Does single parenthood increase the probability of teenage promiscuity, substance use, and crime? Journal of Population Economics, 20, 55–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berk, L. E. (2003). Child development (6th ed.). Boston: Allyn and Bacon.

    Google Scholar 

  • Booth, A., & Amato, P. R. (2001). Parental predivorce relations and offspring postdivorce well-being. Journal of Marriage and Family, 63, 197–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown, J. B., & Lichter, D. T. (2007). Childhood disadvantage, adolescent development, and pro-social behavior in early adulthood. In T. Owens (Ed.), Advances in life course research (Vol. 11). Greenwich, CT: Elsevier/JAI Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chase-Lansdale, P. L., Wakschlag, L. S., & Brooks-Gunn, J. (1995). A psychological perspective on the development of caring in children and youth: The role of the family. Journal of Adolescence, 18, 515–556.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chib, S. (1992). Bayes inference in the Tobit censored regression model. Journal of Econometrics, 51, 79–99.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corak, M. (2001). Death and divorce: The long-term consequences of parental loss on adolescents. Journal of Labor Economics, 19, 682–715.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cunha, F., & Heckman, J. J. (2008). Formulating, identifying and estimating the technology of cognitive and noncognitive skill formation. Journal of Human Resources, 43(4), 738–782.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ermisch, J. F., & Francesoni, M. (2001). Family structure and children’s achievements. Journal of Population Economics, 14, 249–270.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ermisch, J. F., Francesoni, M., & Pevalin, D. J. (2004). Parental partnership and joblessness in childhood and their influence on young people’s outcomes. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society. Series A (Statistics in Society), 167(1), 69–101.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fronstin, P., Greenberg, D. H., & Robins, P. K. (2001). Parental disruption and the labour market performance of children when they reach adulthood. Journal of Population Economics, 14, 137–172.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Geweke, J. (2005). Contemporary bayesian econometrics and statistics. Hoboken, NJ: Wiley-Interscience.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ginther, D. K., & Pollak, R. A. (2004). Family structure and children’s educational outcomes: Blended families, stylized facts, and descriptive regressions. Demography, 41, 671–696.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hill, M. S., Yeung, W.-J. J., & Duncan, G. J. (2001). Childhood family structure and young adult behaviors. Journal of Population Economics, 14, 271–299.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Honoré, B. E. (1992). Trimmed LAD and least squares estimation of truncated and censored regression models with fixed effects. Econometrica, 60(3), 533–565.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koop, G. (2003). Bayesian econometrics. West Sussex, England: Wiley.

    Google Scholar 

  • Krein, S. F., & Beller, A. H. (1988). Educational attainment of children from single-parent families: Differences by exposure, gender, and race. Demography, 25(2), 221–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McAleer, M. (1995). The significance of testing empirical non-nested models. Journal of Econometrics, 67, 149–171.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ottoni-Wilhelm, M., Estell D. B., Perdue, N. H. (under review). Role-modeling and conversations about giving in the socialization of adolescent charitable giving and volunteering. Mimeo.

  • Ruhm, C. J. (2004). Parental employment and child cognitive development. Journal of Human Resources, 39(1), 155–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stafford, F. P. R. F. S., Jacquelynne, S. E., Katherine, M., Wei–Jun Jean Yeung, & Wallace, R. B. (2001). The panel study of income dynamics Wave XXXII [machine-readable data file]/Director and Principal Investigator, Frank P. Stafford; Associate Director and Principal Investigator Robert F. Schoeni; Co-Principal Investigators, Jacquelynne, S. E., Katherine M., Wei-Jun J. Y., Wallace, R. B. Ann Arbor: Institute for Social Research, The University of Michigan.

  • Wheaton, B. (1990). Life transitions, role histories and mental health. American Sociological Review, 55, 209–223.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilhelm, M. O. (2006a). New data on charitable giving in the PSID. Economics Letters, 92(1), 26–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wilhelm, M. O. (2006b). Volunteering data in the 2003 Center on philanthropy panel study: A user’s guide. Mimeo, IUPUI. https://resources.oncourse.iu.edu/access/content/user/mowilhel/Web_page/data.htm.

  • Wojtkiewicz, R. A. (1993). Simplicity and complexity in the effects of parental structure on high school graduation. Demography, 30(4), 701–717.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu, L. L. (1996). Effects of family instability, income, and income instability on the risk of a premarital birth. American Sociological Review, 61, 386–406.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wu, L. L., & Martinson, B. C. (1993). Family structure and the risk of a premarital birth. American Sociological Review, 58, 210–232.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

We are grateful for financial support from NICHD Grant Number 1 R01 HD04645633-01. We are thankful to the agencies that fund the PSID data infrastructure necessary for this research. We thank the foundations, corporations, and individuals who since 2001 have funded the Center on Philanthropy Panel Study—the PSID’s prosocial behavior module. These include the following, who have supported the Center Panel with major grants: The Atlantic Philanthropies, The Bill & Melinda Gates Foundation, the Charles Stewart Mott Foundation, the Corporation for National and Community Service, the Fidelity Investments Charitable Gift Fund, and the John Templeton Foundation. We are grateful for helpful comments from Dave Ribar, Anne Royalty, Judith Seltzer, Ye Zhang, and to Jim Heckman (who suggested the Bayesian approach). Finally, thanks go to seminar participants at the University of Michigan’s CDS Workshop and at the University of North Carolina-Greensboro. Robert Bandy is now at Eli Lilly and Company, Indianapolis, Indiana.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Mark Ottoni-Wilhelm.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (PDF 182 kb)

Appendix: Brief overview of the Bayesian estimation method

Appendix: Brief overview of the Bayesian estimation method

For readers less accustomed to Bayesian methods we provide a brief overview, but see Koop (2003) and Geweke (2005) for complete details. In the Bayesian approach the β parameters (our short-hand term for all the parameters in equation (1)) are random variables. Estimation proceeds by selecting a likelihood function for the y (the vector of outcomes y i , i = 1,…, n), selecting a prior density for the β parameters, and writing down the posterior density of the β parameters using Bayes’ Theorem:

$$ p\left( {{\varvec{\beta}} ,h|{\varvec{y}}} \right) = \frac{{p\left( {{\varvec{y}}|{\varvec{\beta}} ,h} \right)p_{0} \left( {{\varvec{\beta}} ,h} \right)}}{p\left( {\varvec{y}} \right)} $$
(2)

where p(y | β, h) is the likelihood, p 0(β, h) is the prior density, and the parameter h ≡ 1/σ 2 (σ 2 is the variance of u i ). Once the posterior density p(β, h | y) is known, it can be used to estimate any quantity of interest. For example, the mean β—analogous to the point estimate of the slope parameters in ordinary least squares—is:

$$ {\text{E}}\left[ {\varvec{\beta}} \right] \, = \int {{\varvec{\beta}} p\left( {{\varvec{\beta}} ,h|{\varvec{y}}} \right){\text{ d}}{\varvec{\beta}} } $$
(3)

In our models y is either log charitable giving or log volunteer hours. We assume the u i are normal, hence the likelihood function of the data y is normal conditional on the β parameters and h. For the parameters’ prior density we use the independent normal-gamma prior: p 0(β, h) = p β0(β) × p h0(h) where p β0(β) is normal and p h0(h) is Gamma. For most of the β parameters we set the mean of the prior density equal to zero. In a few cases we have good prior information about a parameter and set the prior accordingly (e.g., we set the prior mean elasticity of giving with respect to current young adult income to 1.0). We set the prior mean of h to be \( 1/\widehat{\sigma }^{2} \) where \( \widehat{\sigma }^{2} \) comes from maximum likelihood estimation of the model. We understand that some may prefer different prior means, so accordingly we set the prior variances of the β parameters to be relatively large (about the same magnitude as the prior variance of the outcome \( \widehat{\sigma }^{2} \), implying prior standard deviations on the β parameters of around 3.0), and furthermore give the prior density very little weight relative to the data by setting the prior’s degrees of freedom to only five (compared to the data’s n = 1,011).

The posterior density p(β, h | y) cannot be analytically solved, but is simulated using the Gibbs sampler with data augmentation (see Koop 2003 and Geweke 2005; the algorithm was developed by Chib 1992). We take 1,000 burn-in draws from the posterior density to allow the effect of the initial draw to dissipate, and then take 10,000 additional draws to simulate the posterior. We check convergence by making sure that the 10,000 draws are not autocorrelated and by checking Geweke’s convergence diagnostic (Koop 2003, p. 66). Computations were done in part using the Bayesian Analysis, Computation, and Communication software (http://www.econ.umn.edu/~bacc) and in part using our own software. We also check convergence by (i) thinning the chain (getting our 10,000 draws by taking 1 out of every 10 from 100,000 draws) to reduce autocorrelation between draws and (ii) increasing the number of burn-in draws to 50,000.

The starting point for Bayesian model comparison is to re-write equation (2) to show explicit dependence on the particular model specification of family structure being used (M m ):

$$ p(\left. {{\varvec{\beta}},h} \right|{\varvec{y}},M_{m} ) = \frac{{p(\left. {\varvec{y}} \right|{\varvec{\beta}},h,M_{m} )\,p_{o} (\left. {{\varvec{\beta}},h} \right|M_{m} )}}{{p(\left. {\varvec{y}} \right|M_{m} )}} $$
(4)

where p(y | M m ) is the “marginal likelihood” conditional on M m being the correct specification and m = 1,…,5 indexes the candidate family structure specifications. We estimate the five marginal likelihoods using the Gelfand-Dey method (Koop pp. 104–106). We use these estimates and our prior beliefs about the probability that M m is the correct model ((p(M m ) = 1/5 for all m) in Bayes Theorem (again) to calculate the posterior odds ratio between any pair of models—e.g., p(M 2|y)/p(M 1 | y) – where p(M m | y) is the posterior model probability that M m is the correct model. An assumption that our set of models is exhaustive:

$$ \sum\limits_{m = 1}^{5} {p(\left. {M_{m} } \right|{\varvec{y}}) = 1} $$

allows us to calculate the five posterior model probabilities.

In some applications the posterior model probabilities may indicate that one model specification is strongly preferred: p(M m |y) ≫ p(M m′ | y), m  m′. In other applications it may be that more than one model has a non-negligible posterior model probability. However, when such ambiguity arises it can be handled in an intuitively appealing way using Bayesian model averaging: the posterior of any quantity of interest is a weighted average (weights = p(M m | y)) of the posterior densities p(β, h | y, M m ) from the models with a non-negligible probability.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ottoni-Wilhelm, M., Bandy, R. Stage-specific family structure models: implicit parameter restrictions and Bayesian model comparison with an application to prosocial behavior. Rev Econ Household 11, 313–340 (2013). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-012-9148-7

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11150-012-9148-7

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation