Skip to main content
Log in

Good news and bad news: evidence of media bias in unemployment reports

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This study employs information obtained from media content analyses, as well as economic and political data, to investigate negativity in unemployment news between 2001 and 2010 in Germany. The data indicate a substantial bias in terms of the amounts of negative and positive reports, compared with the actual development of unemployment. Moreover, the media tend to place negative unemployment reports more prominently than positive ones. The estimates suggest that the bias is not the consequence of journalists asymmetrically interpreting the official unemployment numbers. Instead, it is associated with the exploitation of often non-economic information and structural influences in the process of news production.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Note that government unemployment statistics are merely estimates of the “true” unemployment rate insofar as they are based on statistical sampling techniques and usually are corrected or adjusted at least once after they are first made public.

  2. News media also can “go easy” on the government, for example when policies comport with the political preferences of journalists..

  3. The sample contains information about every article and television segment that provides economic news (e.g., reports about economic conditions, economic policy, industries, companies, or unions), excluding articles from the financial or stock section, press reviews, letters by readers, and notes from the publisher.

  4. The seasonally unadjusted unemployment rate, as well as quarterly and annual changes, lead to very similar ratios. However, it is preferable to show the seasonally adjusted data in Figs. 1 and 2, because the seasonal pattern would make it more difficult to quickly recognize the overall trend.

  5. The model diagnostics support a statistical comparison of the estimates with and without seasonally adjusted data. In general, all specifications are satisfactory, as the link tests indicate. However, the Akaike and Bayesian information criteria and McFadden’s R2 suggest that the specifications with seasonally unadjusted unemployment and industrial production data provide a better model fit than the specifications with adjusted data (this result holds when conducting the test comparing only the unemployment rate or industrial production). The seasonally unadjusted data generally exhibit greater variation and thus provide more information to explain the dependent variables. However, this result also might be an indication that the seasonally unadjusted numbers are more important for journalists, maybe because they appear to be more impressive and thus more newsworthy. In line with this finding, the presentation of results refers to the estimates with seasonally unadjusted data only.

  6. The model specification is satisfactory when using seasonally unadjusted data. The different R2 measures and information criteria consistently indicate that specifying the model with seasonally adjusted data would reduce the model’s fit. Therefore, only the results based on the unadjusted data are presented.

References

  • Andina-Díaz, A. (2007). Reinforcement vs. change: The political influence of the media. Public Choice, 131(1/2), 65–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baumeister, R. F., Bratslavsky, E., Finkenauer, C., & Vohs, K. D. (2001). Bad is stronger than good. Review of General Psychology, 5(4), 323–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Behr, R. L., & Iyengar, S. (1985). Television news, real-world cues, and changes in the public agenda. Public Opinion Quarterly, 49(1), 38–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., & Prat, A. (2006). Handcuffs for the grabbing hand? Media capture and government accountability. American Economic Review, 96(3), 720–736.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Birz, G., & Lott, J. R., Jr. (2011). The effect of macroeconomic news on stock returns: New evidence from newspaper coverage. Journal of Banking & Finance, 35(11), 2791–2800.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bovitz, G. L., Druckman, J. N., & Lupia, A. (2002). When can a news organization lead public opinion? Ideology versus market forces in decisions to make news. Public Choice, 113(1/2), 127–155.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brosius, H.-B., & Weimann, G. (1995). Medien oder Bevölkerung: Wer bestimmt die Agenda? Rundfunk und Fernsehen, 43(3), 312–329.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cacioppo, J. T., & Gardner, W. L. (1999). Emotion. Annual Review of Psychology, 50(1), 191–214.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Carroll, C. D. (2003). Macroeconomic expectations of households and professional forecasters. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 118(1), 269–298.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Corner, J. (1998). Television news and economic exposition. In N. T. Gavin (Ed.), The economy, media and public knowledge (pp. 53–70). London: Leicester University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Curtin, R. T. (2003). Unemployment expectations: The impact of private information on income uncertainty. Review of Income and Wealth, 49(4), 539–554.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Die Landesmedienanstalten. (2007). Crossmediale Verflechtungen als Herausforderung für die Konzentrationskontrolle. Berlin: Vistas.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dua, P., & Smyth, D. J. (1993). Survey evidence on excessive public pessimism about the future behavior of unemployment. Public Opinion Quarterly, 57(4), 566–574.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Easaw, J. (2010). It’s all ‘bad’ news! Voters’ perception of macroeconomic policy competence. Public Choice, 145(1–2), 253–264.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Garz, M. (2013). Unemployment expectations, excessive pessimism, and news coverage. Journal of Economic Psychology, 34(1), 156–168.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gasper, J. T. (2009). Reporting for sale: The market for news coverage. Public Choice, 141(3/4), 493–508.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gentzkow, M., & Shapiro, J. M. (2006). Media bias and reputation. Journal of Political Economy, 114(2), 280–316.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gentzkow, M., & Shapiro, J. M. (2010). What drives media slant? Evidence from U.S. daily newspapers. Econometrica, 78(1), 35–71.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Goddard, P., Corner, J., Gavin, N. T., & Richardson, K. (1998). Economic news and the dynamics of understanding: The Liverpool project. In N. T. Gavin (Ed.), The economy, media and public knowledge (pp. 9–37). London: Leicester University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Goidel, R. K., & Langley, R. E. (1995). Media coverage of the economy and aggregate economic evaluations: Uncovering evidence of indirect media effects. Political Research Quarterly, 48(2), 313–328.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Groseclose, T., & Milyo, J. (2005). A measure of media bias. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 120(4), 1191–1237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hagen, L. M. (2005). Konjunkturnachrichten, Konjunkturklima und Konjunktur. Cologne: Herbert von Halem.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harrington, D. E. (1989). Economic news on television: The determinants of coverage. Public Opinion Quarterly, 53(1), 17–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lott, J. R. Jr., & Hassett, K. A. (2013). Is newspaper coverage of economic events politically biased? Discussion paper, American Enterprise Institute, Washington, DC.

  • Hester, J. B., & Gibson, R. (2003). The economy and second-level agenda setting: A time-series analysis of economic news and public opinion about the economy. Journalism & Mass Communication Quarterly, 80(1), 73–90.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hetherington, M. J. (1996). The media’s role in forming voters’ national economic evaluations in 1992. American Journal of Political Science, 40(2), 372–395.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., Knetsch, J. L., & Thaler, R. H. (1991). The endowment effect, loss aversion, and status quo bias. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 5(1), 193–206.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47(2), 263–292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kepplinger, H. M. (2000). Die Demontage der Politik in der Informationsgesellschaft. Freiburg: Alber.

    Google Scholar 

  • Liao, T. F. (2004). Comparing social groups: Wald statistics for testing equality among multiple logit models. International Journal of Comparative Sociology, 45(1–2), 3–16.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • MacKuen, M. B., Erikson, R. S., & Stimson, J. A. (1992). Peasants or bankers? The American electorate and the U.S. economy. American Political Science Review, 86(3), 597–611.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manning, P. (2001). News and news sources: A critical introduction. London: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mullainathan, S., & Shleifer, A. (2005). The market for news. American Economic Review, 95(4), 1031–1053.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mutz, D. C. (1992). Mass media and the depoliticization of personal experience. American Journal of Political Science, 36(2), 483–508.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nadeau, R., Niemi, R. G., Fan, D. P., & Amato, T. (1999). Elite economic forecasts, economic news, mass economic judgments, and presidential approval. Journal of Politics, 61(1), 109–135.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neuman, W. R. (1990). The threshold of public attention. Public Opinion Quarterly, 54(2), 159–176.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action: Public goods and the theory of groups. Cambridge: Havard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Patterson, T. E., & Donsbach, W. (1996). News decisions: Journalists as partisan actors. Political Communication, 13(4), 455–468.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rozin, P., & Royzman, E. B. (2001). Negativity bias, negativity dominance, and contagion. Personality and Social Psychology Review, 5(4), 296–320.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Schultz, J. (1998). Reviving the Fourth Estate: Democracy, accountability and the media. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Soroka, S. N. (2006). Good news and bad news: Asymmetric responses to economic information. Journal of Politics, 68(2), 372–385.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tortorice, D. L. (2012). Unemployment expectations and the business cycle. B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics, 12(1), 1–47.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1991). Loss aversion in riskless choice: A reference-dependent model. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(4), 1039–1061.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Urban, C. D. (1999). Examining our credibility: Examining credibility, explaining ourselves. Reston: American Association of Newspaper Editors.

    Google Scholar 

  • Williams, R. (2009). Using heterogeneous choice models to compare logit and probit coefficients across groups. Sociological Methods & Research, 37(4), 531–559.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Marcel Garz.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Garz, M. Good news and bad news: evidence of media bias in unemployment reports. Public Choice 161, 499–515 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-014-0182-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-014-0182-2

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation