Skip to main content
Log in

Export spillovers in Hungary

  • Published:
Empirical Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Spillovers from peers in the immediate environment can encourage firms to engage in trade. This study examines whether there are spillover effects in exporting activity, using Hungarian product–country-level manufacturing trade data used from 1993 to 2003. Evidence suggests that exporting activity exhibits spillovers and benefits that are country and product specific. In addition, export spillovers exhibit considerable heterogeneity. Foreign-owned firms benefit from peers generally and domestic firms only from the agglomeration of domestic exporters. Spillovers are positively related to country distance and negatively to market size.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Dynamic trade participation decision is not easy to model. Except for the structural approach on export entry by Das et al. (2007), studies use reduced form models, e.g., Clerides et al. (1998) and model decision of engaging in trading via choice modeling. This study takes this latter route.

  2. In this paper, I will use terms good and product interchangeably.

  3. Note that these examples contain both fixed and variable cost elements.

  4. A third benefit is avoiding the following econometric problem. Simply using trade dummies would require the use of lagged dependent variables. Lagged dependent variables would control for the persistent nature of export behavior in the presence of fixed costs. However, in the case, we would like to use a fixed effects model, as I will in this paper, including lagged dependent variable would result in biased estimation. While there are econometric techniques developed for models with lagged dependent variables with fixed effects using dynamic panel data models (see Bond 2002), previous finding is, however, that GMM estimations on the Hungarian data show very unstable results with the starting points and lag structure being excessively important.

  5. Lagging the peer variable by one year also targets the reflection problem raised by Manski (1993) where the individual’s performance is explained by the average behavior of a group which the firm is part of.

  6. See, among many others, Marshall (1920), Henderson (2003), Puga (2010), Rosenthal and Strange (2004).

  7. The spatial sorting of heterogeneous firms has been investigated by Melitz and Ottaviano (2008) and Baldwin and Okubo (2006).

  8. See among many others, Ellison and Glaeser (1997), Barrios et al. (2003), Maurel and Sedillot (1999) or Duranton and Overman (2008)

  9. Another option would be to use spatial concentration indices as they allow for time variation. Calculating Ellison and Glaeser (1997) over Hungarian manufacturing industries shows only little variation over time; hence, sector dummies are sufficient.

  10. IE-HAS is the Institute of Economics of the Hungarian Economy of Sciences. CeFiG is a research project and community, Center for Firms in Global Economy, which is a joint effort of academic and researchers at Central European University and IE-HAS. For a detailed description of the dataset, see Békés et al. (2011).

  11. Merging the balance sheet data with the exports dataset is facilitated by the firms’ tax identifier. In the process, we omit, on average, 17 % of the trade volume each year, which corresponds to the 72 % of the firms observed in the trade dataset. The loss is due to omitting non-manufacturing firms and non-incorporated economic agents. We capture all manufacturing trade reported in the data.

  12. I will convert this information into a dummy variable, taking on the value of one if firm is more than 50 % foreign-/state-owned.

  13. That is, individual transactions are not observed but are summed up to product–country observations for each year for each firm.

  14. Trade with transition countries being previously, e.g., Czechoslovakia, Soviet Union, Yugoslavia cannot be captured in 1992.

  15. The distance between Hungary and the partner country is taken from CEPI’s GeoDist geography dataset.

  16. On the heterogeneity of firms in international trade see, e.g., Bernard et al. (2007), Mayer and Ottaviano (2008), Andersson et al. (2008) or Muûls and Pisu (2009)

  17. Given the estimation strategy, one actually needs temporal variation in firm distribution as well.

  18. See Chaney (2008) for modeling trade at firm level with gravity variables.

  19. The definition of spillovers are different from the ones used in the analysis of Koenig et al. (2010). They consider “all countries” rather than countries other than \(k\). This modification allows us to incorporate all spillover variable in a single regressions and test their difference within one model.

  20. I will include the value of trade to give weight to local information or export strategies.

  21. It is important to note that the distribution of the number of firms is not additive. As a firm can export to more than one country, it can appear more than once in the table.

  22. While in the literature, size often correlates positively with trade entry, the results on the state dummy are not as expected. However, the results is not stable over time; the coefficient gets negative if regression is carried out for the post- 1997 period. This reflects the results of the privatization literature, foreign investors cherry-picking the more productive firms. See, e.g., Brown et al. (2006).

  23. The result are analogous in an alternative specification when spillover variables are included separately. See Table 12 in the “Appendix.”

  24. The inference is reinforced by investigating the result when the country dimension is shut down entirely. Results are available at request.

References

  • Aitken B, Hanson GH, Harrison AE (1997) Spillovers, foreign investment, and export behavior. J Int Econ 43(1–2):103–132

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akerman A, Forslid R (2009) Firm heterogeneity and country size dependent market entry cost. Working paper series 790, Research Institute of Industrial Economics

  • Altomonte C, Békés G (2009) Trade complexity and productivity. IE-HAS working papers 14

  • Anderson JE, van Wincoop E (2003) Gravity with gravitas: a solution to the border puzzle. Am Econ Rev 93(1):170–192

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andersson M, Lööf H, Johansson S (2008) Productivity and international trade: firm level evidence from a small open economy. Rev World Econ (Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv) 144(4):774–801

    Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin RE, Okubo T (2006) Heterogeneous firms, agglomeration and economic geography: spatial selection and sorting. J Econ Geogr 6(3):323–346

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barrios S, Bertinelli L, Eric S, Antonio Carlos T (2003) Agglomeration economies and the location of industries: a comparison of three small European countries. MPRA paper 5704, University Library of Munich, Germany

  • Békés G, Muraközy B, Harasztosi P (2011) Firms and products in international trade: evidence from Hungary. Econ Syst 35(1):4–24

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernard A, Jensen B (1999) Exceptional exporter performance: cause, effect, or both? J Int Econ 47(1):1–25

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernard AB, Jensen B (2004) Why some firms export. Rev Econ Stat 86(2):561–569

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernard AB, Jensen JB, Redding SJ, Schott PK (2007) Firms in international trade. J Econ Perspect 21(3):105–130

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bond S (2002) Dynamic panel data models: a guide to microdata methods and practice. CeMMAP working papers CWP09/02, Centre for Microdata Methods and Practice, Institute for Fiscal Studies

  • Brooks EL (2006) Why don’t firms export more? Product quality and Colombian plants. J Dev Econ 80(1):160–178

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brown JD, Earle JS, Telegdy A (2006) The productivity effects of privatization: longitudinal estimates from Hungary, Romania, Russia, and Ukraine. J Polit Econ 114(1):61–99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Castellani D, Serti F, Tomasi C (2010) Firms in international trade: importers’ and exporters’ heterogeneity in Italian manufacturing industry. World Econ 33(3):424–457

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chaney T (2008) Distorted gravity: the intensive and extensive margins of international trade. Am Econ Rev 98(4):1707–1721

  • Clerides SK, Lach S, Tybout JR (1998) Is learning by exporting important? Micro-dynamic evidence from Colombia, Mexico, and Morocco. Quart J Econ 113(3):903–947

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Das S, Roberts MJ, Tybout JR (2007) Market entry costs, producer heterogeneity, and export dynamics. Econometrica 75(3):837–873

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dumont M, Merlevede B, Piette C, Rayp G (2010) The productivity and export spillovers of the internationalisation behaviour of Belgian firms. Working paper research 201, National Bank of Belgium

  • Duranton G, Overman HG (2008) Exploring the detailed location patterns of U.K. manufacturing industries using microgeographic data. J Reg Sci 48(1):213–243

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Duranton G, Puga D (2004) Micro-foundations of urban agglomeration economies. In: Henderson JV, Thisse JF (eds) Handbook of regional and urban economics. Vol. 4 of handbook of regional and urban economics. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 2063–2117 Ch. 48

    Google Scholar 

  • Eaton J, Kortum S, Kramarz F (2011) An anatomy of international trade: evidence from French firms. Econometrica 79(5):1453–1498

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ellison G, Glaeser EL (1997) Geographic concentration in U.S. manufacturing industries: a dartboard approach. J Polit Econ 105(5):889–927

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greenaway D, Kneller R (2008) Exporting, productivity and agglomeration. Eur Econ Rev 52(5):919–939

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Henderson JV (2003) Marshall’s scale economies. J Urban Econ 53(1):1–28

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Imbriani C, Morone P, Testa G (2008) Exporting quality: is it the right strategy for the Italian manufacturing sector? MPRA paper 13327. University Library of Munich, Germany

  • Koenig P (2009) Agglomeration and the export decisions of French firms. J Urban Econ 66(3):186–195

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koenig P, Mayneris F, Poncet S (2010) Local export spillovers in France. Eur Econ Rev 54(4):622–641

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Koenig P, Mayneris F, Poncet S (2011) Économies d’agglomération l’export et difficult d’accés aux marchés. Universit Paris1 Panthon-Sorbonne (Post-print and working papers) hal-00633773, HAL

  • Lawless M (2005) Firm export participation: entry, spillovers and tradability. MPRA paper 10005, University Library of Munich, Germany

  • Lawless M (2006) Geography and firm exports: new evidence on the nature of sunk costs. Research technical papers 1/RT/06, Central Bank and Financial Services Authority of Ireland (CBFSAI)

  • Levinsohn J, Petrin A (2003) Estimating production functions using inputs to control for unobservables. Rev Econ Stud 70(2):317–341

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lovely ME, Rosenthal SS, Sharma S (2005) Information, agglomeration, and the headquarters of U.S. exporters. Reg Sci Urban Econ 35(2):167–191

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manski CF (1993) Identification of endogenous social effects: the reflection problem. Rev Econ Stud 60(3):531–542

  • Marshall A (1920) Principal of economics: an introductory volume, 8th edn. Procupine Press, Philadelphia

    Google Scholar 

  • Maurel F, Sedillot B (1999) A measure of the geographic concentration in french manufacturing industries. Reg Sci Urban Econ 29(5):575–604

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mayer T, Ottaviano G (2008) The happy few: the internationalisation of European firms. Intereconomics: review of European. Econ Policy 43(3):135–148

    Google Scholar 

  • Mayneris F, Poncet S (2011) Entry on difficult export markets by Chinese domestic firms: the role of foreign export spillovers. Working papers 2011–32, CEPII research center

  • Mayneris F, Poncet S (2011) Export performance of Chinese domestic firms: the role of foreign export spillovers. Discussion papers (IRES - Institut de Recherches Economiques et Sociales) 2011003, Universit catholique de Louvain, Institut de Recherches Economiques et Sociales (IRES)

  • Mayneris F, Poncet S (2011) French firms at the conquest of Asian markets: the role of export spillovers. Working papers 2011–31, CEPII research center

  • Melitz MJ (2003) The impact of trade on intra-industry reallocations and aggregate industry productivity. Econometrica 71(6):1695–1725

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Melitz MJ, Ottaviano GIP (2008) Market size, trade, and productivity. Rev Econ Stud 75(1):295–316

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mion G, Opromolla LD (2014) Managers’ mobility, trade performance, and wages. J Int Econ 94(1):85–101

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moulton BR (1990) An illustration of a pitfall in estimating the effects of aggregate variables on micro unit. Rev Econ Stat 72(2):334–338

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Muûls M, Pisu M (2009) Imports and exports at the level of the firm: evidence from Belgium. World Econ 32(5):692–734

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Puga D (2010) The magnitude and causes of agglomeration economies. J Reg Sci 50(1):203–219

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pupato G (2007) Non-market interactions and entry into export markets: an empirical analysis. Working paper, University of British Columbia, http://grad.econ.ubc.ca/pupa/Research.html

  • Rosenthal SS, Strange WC (2004) Evidence on the nature and sources of agglomeration economies. In: Henderson JV, Thisse JF (eds) Handbook of regional and urban economics, vol 4. Elsevier, Amsterdam, pp 2119–2171

  • Rauch JE (1999) Networks versus markets in international trade. J Int Econ 48(1):7–35

  • Soon L, K D, Fraser C (2006) Making tacit knowledge explicit: designing an export trading knowledge portal. In: Ruth A (Ed.), Quality and impact of qualitative research. 3rd annual QualIT conference, Brisbane

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Péter Harasztosi.

Additional information

The author is grateful for comments by the anonymous referees, Pamina Koenig, Cecilía Hornok, Gábor Békés, Miklós Koren, Gábor Antal, Álmos Telegdy and the participants of ETSG Lausanne, EEA Oslo and the Granada Workshop on International trade, Local spillover and Productivity of firms. Any remaining error is mine. Opinions expressed in the paper are those of the author and may not reflect the views of the institution he is affiliated with.

Appendix

Appendix

1.1 The impact of large or multi-site firms

There may be several problems related to large firms possibly operating several sites or at least a separate HQ.

To see the size of the potential bias when other plants are not within the same location, one can rely on another dataset. This data source comes from the annual labor survey (LFS) that covers all firms with at least 20 employees and a randomly selected set of small firms. In firms with at least 20 employees, one in ten employees is surveyed and the exact location of their workplace is duly noted.

I look at this data for all years in our sample. From this sample, one learns that only 7–8 % of firms have multiple sites, most multi-plant firms have two plants. On average, firms have 1.15 plants—so this is the maximum size of our bias. As for firms with more than one plant, the largest plant (which, in 80 % of the cases, is also the site of the firm’s headquarters) has 67 % of the employees.

Table 11 Within firm share of identified location in matched LFS sample for 2002

In Table 11, the share of employment of a firm in the settlement is checked and in the microregion that I use as the identifier on the LFS sample. On a 2230 firm sample of 2002, it shows that 91 % of the firms are within the same municipality and also in the same microregion. In the case when a firm is located in more than one municipality, the one that I am able to identify holds 65–70 % of the firm’s employment. Finally, note that these figures mostly refer to firms with above 20 employees, and thus, whole economy figures are much smaller, since the majority of firms are small- and medium-sized enterprizes. This suggests that our biases due to multi-plant firms are probably small.

1.2 Additional tables and figures

See Tables 12, 13 and 14.

Table 12 Collected estimates when spillover variables are included separately
Table 13 Estimations including value spillovers at the country–product level
Table 14 Coefficients of same country, same product spillover

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Harasztosi, P. Export spillovers in Hungary. Empir Econ 50, 801–830 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-015-0965-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s00181-015-0965-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation