Skip to main content
Log in

Committees in legislatures: A property rights perspective

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Conclusion

Without the imposition of some institutional structure, a legislature is a non-exclusive resource, and legislators will have a tendency to overuse the resource and reduce its productivity. The committee system is a method for granting property rights over the legislature's agenda by subdividing the agenda and assigning each committee rights over a portion of the agenda. Just as common grazing ground could be more productive if it were subdivided and assigned to individual owners, the legislature is more productive if access to the agenda is subdivided and assigned to committees.

Ownership rights to committee assignments are allocated based on seniority because this makes the rights more secure and therefore more valuable to their owners. In the United States Congress, the seniority rule replaced a system in which assignments were made at the discretion of party leaders. In the former system, legislators needed to expend effort to retain their assignments, which diminished their ability to use their assignments productively. Because individuals can use resources more productively if they do not have to be concerned about protecting their ownership interest, the seniority system enables the legislature to be more productive in producing legislation.

Viewing the legislature in this property rights framework sheds some light on two controversial issues in public choice. The question about legislators voting based on ideology rather than constituent interests is an example of discretionary behavior on the part of a legislator who is spending political capital. A legislator engaged in a very competitive battle for reelection will have little room for discretion, but surely the candidate is motivated by more than just the selfless desire to further constituent interests. Where there are barriers to entry, legislators build majorities capable of producing political capital. This political capital can be spent through discretionary behavior — including ideological voting — by the legislator (Parker, 1989). The other issue is stability under majority rule. By observing that the legislature is a valuable resource that can be used by legislators to further their own interests, it is clear that they have an incentive to manage the resource to be as productive as possible, which produces institutions that generate output valuable to the legislators rather than cycles.

Economic theory suggests that when a small number of individuals are sharing a non-exclusive resource, they should be able to negotiate a rights structure that maximizes the value of the resource to those individuals. The committee system, with assignments protected by the seniority system, assigns rights to produce legislation in such a way as to maximize the value of the legislature to the legislators.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Black, D. (1958). The theory of committees and elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J.M. and Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bullock, C.S. (1971). The influence of state party delegations on House party assignments. Midwest Journal of Political Science 15 (3): 525–546.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cheung, S.N.S. (1970). The structure of a contract and the theory of a non-exclusive resource. Journal of Law & Economics 13 (1): 49–70.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crain, W.M. (1977). On the structure and stability of political markets. Journal of Political Economy 85 (4): 829–842.

    Google Scholar 

  • Crain, W.M., Leavens, D.R. and Tollison, R.D. (1986). Final voting in legislatures. American Economic Review 76 (4): 833–841.

    Google Scholar 

  • Demsetz, H. (1986). Why regulate utilities? Journal of Law & Economics 11: 55–65.

    Google Scholar 

  • Downs, A. (1957). An economic theory of democracy. New York: Harper & Row.

    Google Scholar 

  • England, D. and Bullock, C.S. (1986). Prescriptive seats revisited. American Journal of Political Science 30 (2): 496–502.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fenno, R.F., Jr. (1973). Congressmen in committees. Boston: Little, Brown.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferejohn, J.A. and Calvert, R.L. (1984). Presidential coattails in historical perspective. American Journal of Political Science 28 (1): 127–146.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina, M.P. (1977). Congress: Keystone to the Washington establishment. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fiorina, M.P., Rhode, D.W. and Wissel, P. (1975). Historical change in House turnover. In N.J. Ornstein (Ed.), Congress in change, 24–57. New York: Praeger.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R.G. (1983). Public finance and the political process. Carbondale: Southern Illinois University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R.G. (1985). An economic analysis of democracy. Carbondale: Southern Illinois University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcombe, R.G. (1989). A note on seniority and political competition. Public Choice 61 (3): 285–288.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kalt, J.P. and Zupan, M.A. (1984). Capture and ideology in the theory of politics. American Economic Review 74: 279–300.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kau, J.B. and Rubin, P.H. (1979). Self-interest, ideology, and logrolling in congressional voting. Journal of Law & Economics 22: 365–384.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koford, K.J. (1982). Centralized vote trading. Public Choice 39 (2): 245–268.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leibowitz, A. and Tollison, R.D. (1980). A theory of legislative organization: Making the most of your majority. Quarterly Journal of Economics 94: 261–277.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, G.J. and Oppenheimer, J.A. (1982). Universalism in experimental committees. American Political Science Review 76 (3): 561–574.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W.A. (1971). Bureaucracy and representative government. Chicago and New York: Aldine-Atherton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Niskanen, W.A. (1975). Bureaucrats and politicians. Journal of Law & Economics 18 (3): 617–643.

    Google Scholar 

  • Olson, M. (1965). The logic of collective action. New York: Schocken Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parker, G.R. (1989). Looking beyond reelection: Revising assumptions about factors motivating congressional behavior. Public Choice 63 (3): 237–252.

    Google Scholar 

  • Parker, G.R. and Parker, S.L. (1985). Factions in House committees. Knoxville: University of Tennessee Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peltzman, S. (1976). Toward a more general theory of regulation. Journal of Law & Economics 19 (2): 211–240.

    CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  • Polsby, N. (1968). The institutionalization of the House of Representatives. American Political Science Review 62 (1): 144–168.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W.H. (1962). The theory of political coalitions. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Riker, W.H. (1980). Implications from the disequilibrium of majority rule for the study of institutions. American Political Science Review 74 (2): 432–446.

    Google Scholar 

  • Romer, T. and Rosenthal, H. (1978). Political resource allocation, controlled agendas, and the status quo. Public Choice 33 (4): 27–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K.A. (1979). Institutional arrangements and equilibrium in a multidimensional voting model. American Journal of Political Science 23 (1): 27–59.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K.A. and Weingast, B.R. (1981). Structure-induced equilibrium and legislative choice. Public Choice 37 (3): 503–519.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K.A. and Weingast, B.R. (1987). The institutional foundations of committee power. American Political Science Review 81 (1): 85–104.

    Google Scholar 

  • Smith, S.S. (1986). Decision-making on the House floor. Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association.

  • Stigler, G.J. (1972). Economic competition and political competition. Public Choice 13: 91–106.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thomas, M. (1985). Election proximity and senatorial roll call voting. American Journal of Political Science 29 (1): 96–111.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1965). Entry barriers in politics. American Economic Review 15 (2): 458–466.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1967). The welfare costs of tariffs, monopolies, and theft. Western Economic Journal 4: 224–232.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1982). Why so much stability? Public Choice 37 (2): 189–202.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B.R., Shepsle, K.A. and Johnsen, C. (1981). The political economy of benefits and costs: A neoclassical approach to distributive politics. Journal of Political Economy 89 (4): 642–664.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Holcombe, R.G., Parker, G.R. Committees in legislatures: A property rights perspective. Public Choice 70, 11–20 (1991). https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00239341

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/BF00239341

Keywords

Navigation