Skip to content
BY 4.0 license Open Access Published by De Gruyter Open Access January 29, 2015

Entrepreneurship, Knowledge, and the Industrial Revolution

  • M. Aykut Attar EMAIL logo
From the journal Economics

Abstract

This paper constructs a two-sector unified growth model. Learning-by-doing in agriculture eventually allows the preindustrial economy to leave its Malthusian trap. But entrepreneurs in the manufacturing sector do not attempt invention if not much is known about natural phenomena. This delays the industrial revolution. Since entrepreneurs identify new useful knowledge at all times in a serendipitous way, the industrial revolution is an inevitable outcome. The paper characterizes the equilibrium path from ancient times to the infinite future. According with this characterization, the model economy successfully captures the qualitative aspects of England’s unified growth experience.

JEL Classification: O31; O33; O41; J13; N33

References

Aghion, P., and Howitt, P. (1992). A Model of Growth through Creative Destruction. Econometrica, 60(2): 323–351. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/ecm/emetrp/v60y1992i2p323-51.html.Search in Google Scholar

Aghion, P., and Howitt, P. (2009). The Economics of Growth. Cambridge: MIT Press.Search in Google Scholar

Akcigit, U., and Kerr, W. R. (2010). Growth Through Heterogeneous Innovations. NBER Working Papers 16443, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc. URL http://ideas.repec.org/p/nbr/nberwo/16443.html.10.3386/w16443Search in Google Scholar

Bar, M., and Leukhina, O. (2010). The Role of Mortality in the Transmission of Knowledge. Journal of Economic Growth, 15(4): 291–321. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/kap/jecgro/v15y2010i4p291-321.html.Search in Google Scholar

Baumol, W. J. (1990). Entrepreneurship: Productive, Unproductive, and Destructive. Journal of Political Economy, 98(5): 893–921. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/ucp/jpolec/v98y1990i5p893-921.html.Search in Google Scholar

Bekar, C. T., and Lipsey, R. G. (2004). Science, Institutions and the Industrial Revolution. Journal of European Economic History, 33(3): 709–753.Search in Google Scholar

Boldrin, M., and Jones, L. E. (2002). Mortality, Fertility, and Saving in a Malthusian Economy. Review of Economic Dynamics, 5(4): 775–814. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/red/issued/v5y2002i4p775-814.html.Search in Google Scholar

Clark, G. (2010). The Macroeconomic Aggregates for England, 1209-2008. Research in Economic History, 27: 51–140. URL http://dx.doi.org/10.1108/S0363-3268(2010)0000027004.10.1108/S0363-3268(2010)0000027004Search in Google Scholar

Clark, G. (2014). The Industrial Revolution. In Handbook of Economic Growth, volume 2 of Handbook of Economic Growth, chapter 5, pages 217–262. Elsevier. URL http://ideas.repec.org/h/eee/grochp/2-217.html.Search in Google Scholar

Crafts, N., and Harley, K. (1992). Output Growth and the British Industrial Revolution: A Restatement of the Crafts-Harley View. Economic History Review, 45(4): 703–730. URL http://EconPapers.repec.org/RePEc:bla:ehsrev:v:45:y:1992:i:4:p:703-730.Search in Google Scholar

Crafts, N., and Mills, T. C. (2009). From Malthus to Solow: How Did the Malthusian Economy Really Evolve? Journal of Macroeconomics, 31(1): 68–93. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/eee/jmacro/v31y2009i1p68-93.html.Search in Google Scholar

de la Croix, D., and Licandro, O. (2013). The Child Is Father of the Man: Implications for the Demographic Transition. Economic Journal, 123(567): 236–261. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/ecj/econjl/v123y2013i567p236-261.html.Search in Google Scholar

Desmet, K., and Parente, S. (2012). The Evolution of Markets and the Revolution of Industry: A Unified Theory of Growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 17(3): 205–234. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/kap/jecgro/v17y2012i3p205-234.html.Search in Google Scholar

Doepke, M. (2004). Accounting for Fertility Decline During the Transition to Growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 9(3): 347–383. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/kap/jecgro/v9y2004i3p347-383.html.Search in Google Scholar

Doepke, M., and Zilibotti, F. (2008). Occupational Choice and the Spirit of Capitalism. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 123(2): 747–793. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/tpr/qjecon/v123y2008i2p747-793.html.Search in Google Scholar

Easterlin, R. A. (1995). Industrial Revolution and Mortality Revolution: Two of a Kind? Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 5(4): 393–408. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/spr/joevec/v5y1995i4p393-408.html.Search in Google Scholar

Galor, O. (2005). From Stagnation to Growth: Unified Growth Theory. In P. Aghion, and S. Durlauf (Eds.), Handbook of Economic Growth, volume 1 of Handbook of Economic Growth, chapter 4, pages 171–293. Elsevier. URL http://ideas.repec.org/h/eee/grochp/1-04.html.Search in Google Scholar

Galor, O. (2010). The 2008 Lawrence R. Klein Lecture-Comparative Economic Development: Insights From Unified Growth Theory. International Economic Review, 51(1): 1–44. URL http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.1468-2354.2009.00569.x.10.1111/j.1468-2354.2009.00569.xSearch in Google Scholar

Galor, O., and Michalopoulos, S. (2012). Evolution and the Growth Process: Natural Selection of Entrepreneurial Traits. Journal of Economic Theory, 147(2): 759–780. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/eee/jetheo/v147y2012i2p759-780.html.Search in Google Scholar

Galor, O., and Weil, D. N. (2000). Population, Technology, and Growth: From Malthusian Stagnation to the Demographic Transition and Beyond. American Economic Review, 90(4): 806–828. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/aea/aecrev/v90y2000i4p806-828.html.Search in Google Scholar

Grossmann, V. (2009). Entrepreneurial Innovation and Economic Growth. Journal of Macroeconomics, 31(4): 602–613. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/eee/jmacro/v31y2009i4p602-613.html.Search in Google Scholar

Hansen, G. D., and Prescott, E. C. (2002). Malthus to Solow. American Economic Review, 92(4): 1205–1217. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/aea/aecrev/v92y2002i4p1205-1217.html.Search in Google Scholar

Haruyama, T. (2009). Competitive Innovation with Codified and Tacit Knowledge. Scottish Journal of Political Economy, 56(s1): 390–414. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/bla/scotjp/v56y2009is1p390-414.html.Search in Google Scholar

Hazan, M., and Berdugo, B. (2002). Child Labour, Fertility, and Economic Growth. Economic Journal, 112(482): 810–828. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/ecj/econjl/v112y2002i482p810-828.html.Search in Google Scholar

Hazan, M., and Zoabi, H. (2006). Does Longevity Cause Growth? A Theoretical Critique. Journal of Economic Growth, 11(4): 363–376. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/kap/jecgro/v11y2006i4p363-376.html.Search in Google Scholar

Hellwig, M., and Irmen, A. (2001). Endogenous Technical Change in a Competitive Economy. Journal of Economic Theory, 101(1): 1–39. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/eee/jetheo/v101y2001i1p1-39.html.Search in Google Scholar

Howitt, P., and Mayer-Foulkes, D. (2005). R&D, Implementation, and Stagnation: A Schumpeterian Theory of Convergence Clubs. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 37(1): 147–77. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/mcb/jmoncb/v37y2005i1p147-77.html.Search in Google Scholar

Jacob, M. C. (1997). Scientific Culture and the Making of the Industrial West. New York: Oxford University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Jones, C. I. (2001). Was an Industrial Revolution Inevitable? Economic Growth over the Very Long Run. B.E. Journal of Macroeconomics, 1(2): 1–45. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/bpj/bejmac/vadvances.1y2001i2n1.html.Search in Google Scholar

Kelly, M. (2005). The Invention of Invention. Working Papers No: 200515, School of Economics, University College Dublin. URL http://ideas.repec.org/p/ucn/wpaper/200515.html.Search in Google Scholar

Klette, T. J., and Kortum, S. (2004). Innovating Firms and Aggregate Innovation. Journal of Political Economy, 112(5): 986–1018. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/ucp/jpolec/v112y2004i5p986-1018.html.Search in Google Scholar

Kögel, T., and Prskawetz, A. (2001). Agricultural Productivity Growth and Escape from the Malthusian Trap. Journal of Economic Growth, 6(4): 337–357. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/kap/jecgro/v6y2001i4p337-57.html.Search in Google Scholar

Lagerlöf, N.-P. (2003). From Malthus to Modern Growth: Can Epidemics Explain the Three Regimes? International Economic Review, 44(2): 755–777. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/ier/iecrev/v44y2003i2p755-777.html.Search in Google Scholar

Landes, D. S. (1969). The Unbound Prometheus: Technological Change and Industrial Development in Western Europe from 1750 to the Present. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Landes, D. S. (2006). Why Europe and the West? Why Not China? Journal of Economic Perspectives, 20(2): 3–22. URL http://www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi=10.1257/jep.20.2.3.Search in Google Scholar

Lucas, R. E., Jr. (1978). On the Size Distribution of Business Firms. Bell Journal of Economics, 9(2): 508–523. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/rje/bellje/v9y1978iautumnp508-523.html.Search in Google Scholar

Lucas, R. E., Jr. (2002). The Industrial Revolution: Past and Future. In Lectures on Economic Growth, chapter 5, pages 97–188. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Lucas, R. E., Jr. (2009). Ideas and Growth. Economica, 76(301): 1–19. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/bla/econom/v76y2009i301p1-19.html.Search in Google Scholar

Madsen, J., Ang, J., and Banerjee, R. (2010). Four Centuries of British Economic Growth: The Roles of Technology and Population. Journal of Economic Growth, 15(4): 263–290. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/kap/jecgro/v15y2010i4p263-290.html.Search in Google Scholar

Meisenzahl, R. R., and Mokyr, J. (2012). The Rate and Direction of Invention in the British Industrial Revolution: Incentives and Institutions. In J. Lerner, and S. Stern (Eds.), The Rate and Direction of Inventive Activity Revisited, chapter 9, pages 443–479. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. URL http://www.nber.org/chapters/c12364.pdf.Search in Google Scholar

Michelacci, C. (2003). Low Returns in R&D Due to the Lack of Entrepreneurial Skills. Economic Journal, 113(484): 207–225. URL http://EconPapers.repec.org/RePEc:ecj:econjl:v:113:y:2003:i:484:p:207-225.Search in Google Scholar

Milionis, P., and Klasing, M. (2011). Innovation-Based Growth & Long-Run Economic Development. URL http://www.rug.nl/staff/p.milionis/milionis_klasing2011.pdf. Unpublished manuscript.Search in Google Scholar

Mokyr, J. (1998). Editor’s Introduction: The New Economic History and the Industrial Revolution. In J. Mokyr (Ed.), The British Industrial Revolution: An Economic Perspective, pages 1–127. Boulder: Westview Press.Search in Google Scholar

Mokyr, J. (2002). The Gifts of Athena: Historical Origins of the Knowledge Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Mokyr, J. (2004). Accounting for the Industrial Revolution. In R. Floud, and P. Johnson (Eds.), The Cambridge Economic History of Modern Britain, volume 1, chapter 1, pages 1–27. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Mokyr, J. (2010). Entrepreneurship and the Industrial Revolution in Britain. In D. S. Landes, J. Mokyr, and W. J. Baumol (Eds.), The Invention of Enterprise: Entrepreneurship from Ancient Mesopotamia to Modern Times, chapter 7, pages 183–210. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Search in Google Scholar

Murphy, K. M., Shleifer, A., and Vishny, R. W. (1991). The Allocation of Talent: Implications for Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 106(2): 503–530. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/tpr/qjecon/v106y1991i2p503-30.html.Search in Google Scholar

Nelson, R. R. (1982). The Role of Knowledge in R&D Efficiency. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 97(3): 453–470. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/tpr/qjecon/v97y1982i3p453-70.html.Search in Google Scholar

O’Rourke, K., Rahman, A., and Taylor, A. (2013). Luddites, the Industrial Revolution, and the Demographic Transition. Journal of Economic Growth, 18(4): 373–409. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/kap/jecgro/v18y2013i4p373-409.html.Search in Google Scholar

Pereira, A. S. (2004). Localized or Generalized Growth? Structural Breaks and the Two Views of the Industrial Revolution. Historical Social Research, 35(1): 323–339. URL http://www.jstor.org/stable/20762440.Search in Google Scholar

Peretto, P. F. (1998). Technological Change, Market Rivalry, and the Evolution of the Capitalist Engine of Growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 3(1): 53–80. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/kap/jecgro/v3y1998i1p53-80.html.Search in Google Scholar

Peretto, P. F. (2013). From Smith to Schumpeter: A Theory of Take-Off and Convergence to Sustained Growth. Working Papers 13-10, Duke University, Department of Economics. URL http://ideas.repec.org/p/duk/dukeec/13-10.html.Search in Google Scholar

Pomeranz, K. (2000). The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Making of the Modern World Economy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.10.1515/9781400823499Search in Google Scholar

Rodríguez-Pose, A. (1999). Innovation Prone and Innovation Averse Societies: Economic Performance in Europe. Growth and Change, 30(1): 75–105. URL http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/0017-4815.00105.10.1111/0017-4815.00105Search in Google Scholar

Rosenberg, N. (1974). Science, Invention and Economic Growth. Economic Journal, 84(333): 90–108. URL http://EconPapers.repec.org/RePEc:ecj:econjl:v:84:y:1974:i:333:p:90-108.Search in Google Scholar

Schumpeter, J. A. (1934). The Theory of Economic Development. Cambridge: Harvard University Press. (First German Edition in 1912.).Search in Google Scholar

Solo, C. S. (1951). Innovation in the Capitalist Process: A Critique of the Schumpeterian Theory. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 65(3): 417–428. URL http://qje.oxfordjournals.org/content/65/3/417.short.Search in Google Scholar

Strulik, H. (2014). Knowledge and Growth in the Very Long Run. International Economic Review, 55(2): 459–482. URL http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/iere.12057.10.1111/iere.12057Search in Google Scholar

Strulik, H., Prettner, K., and Prskawetz, A. (2013). The Past and Future of Knowledge-Based Growth. Journal of Economic Growth, 18(4): 411–437. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/kap/jecgro/v18y2013i4p411-437.html.Search in Google Scholar

Strulik, H., and Weisdorf, J. (2008). Population, Food, and Knowledge: A Simple Unified Growth Theory. Journal of Economic Growth, 13(3): 195–216. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/kap/jecgro/v13y2008i3p195-216.html.Search in Google Scholar

Strulik, H., and Weisdorf, J. (2014). How Child Costs and Survival Shaped the Industrial Revolution and the Demographic Transition. Macroeconomic Dynamics, 18(1): 114–144. URL http://journals.cambridge.org/article_S1365100512000302.Search in Google Scholar

Sullivan, R. J. (1989). England’s Age of Invention: The Acceleration of Patents and Patentable Invention during the Industrial Revolution. Explorations in Economic History, 26(4): 424–452. URL http://EconPapers.repec.org/RePEc:eee:exehis:v:26:y:1989:i:4:p:424-452.Search in Google Scholar

Tamura, R. (2002). Human Capital and the Switch from Agriculture to Industry. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 27(2): 207–242. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/eee/dyncon/v27y2002i2p207-242.html.Search in Google Scholar

United Nations (2012). World Population Prospects: The 2012 Revision. United Nations Population Division. URL http://esa.un.org/unpd/wpp/index.htm. Accessed on June 20, 2014.Search in Google Scholar

Voigtländer, N., and Voth, H.-J. (2006). Why England? Demographic Factors, Structural Change and Physical Capital Accumulation during the Industrial Revolution. Journal of Economic Growth, 11(4): 319–361. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/kap/jecgro/v11y2006i4p319-361.html.Search in Google Scholar

Weitzman, M. L. (1998). Recombinant Growth. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113(2): 331–360. URL http://ideas.repec.org/a/tpr/qjecon/v113y1998i2p331-360.html.Search in Google Scholar

Received: 2014-08-22
Revised: 2015-01-26
Accepted: 2015-01-28
Published Online: 2015-01-29
Published in Print: 2015-12-01

© 2015 M. Aykut Attar, published by Sciendo

This work is licensed under the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License.

Downloaded on 19.4.2024 from https://www.degruyter.com/document/doi/10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2015-3/html
Scroll to top button