Next Article in Journal
Reliability and Validity of the Multidimensional Locus of Control IPC Scale in a Sample of 3668 Greek Educators
Previous Article in Journal
An Appreciative View of the Brighter Side of Terror Management Processes
 
 
Font Type:
Arial Georgia Verdana
Font Size:
Aa Aa Aa
Line Spacing:
Column Width:
Background:
Article

A Cross-Level Exploratory Analysis of “Neighborhood Effects” on Urban Behavior: An Evolutionary Perspective

Geography Department, Texas State University, 601 University Drive, San Marcos, TX 78666, USA
Soc. Sci. 2015, 4(4), 1046-1066; https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci4041046
Submission received: 20 June 2015 / Revised: 22 October 2015 / Accepted: 30 October 2015 / Published: 4 November 2015

Abstract

:
It is now generally accepted that spatially-based neighborhood or contextual attributes influence individual behaviors. However, studies of contextual effects often operationalize “neighborhoods” as static, single-level administrative units that are chosen for data availability rather than theoretical reasons. This practice has led to new calls for sound conceptual models that guide data collection efforts and statistical analyses related to these phenomena. While many such models are in use or being proposed in the social sciences, this article argues that research in the field of evolutionary studies offers alternative and interesting ways of investigating neighborhood effects. Accordingly, the article pursues two objectives. First, it makes connections between neighborhood effects research in the social sciences and relevant literature in evolutionary game theory and evolutionary urban geography. Second, these interdisciplinary interactions guide the development of a cross-level conceptual model of neighborhood effects on urban social behavior. The conceptual model is then translated into an empirical model that tests whether and how property maintenance behavior in a selected U.S. study area changes as a function of neighborhood context. The findings reveal that neighborhood effects operate at multiple, interacting spatial levels in the study area, which suggests that conventional single-level administrative boundaries are not equipped to capture these effects. While they are proffered as exploratory, the results nonetheless imply that insights from evolutionary research can add depth and theoretical grounding to contextual effects studies in the social sciences.

1. Introduction

Urban social and behavioral scientists have long been interested in neighborhoods: what they are [1,2,3,4,5,6,7]; how they form [8,9]; the processes by which they change over time, and, in turn, how those changes play out at higher levels of aggregation [10,11,12,13,14,15]; their roles in strategic planning and governance [16,17]; and, among other things, how (or if) they affect the behaviors and life outcomes of their constituent actors [18,19,20,21,22,23]. Concerning the latter of these themes, which is the focus of the current article, the ways in which neighborhood contexts influence individuals have proven quite difficult to study empirically. For, such inquiries must attend to a host of theoretical and methodological issues [21,22,23,24,25,26,27].
Perhaps the most fundamental of these issues is what Kwan [28] refers to as the “uncertain geographic context problem”, or UGCoP. Briefly, the UGCoP—which is distinct from the technically addressable modifiable areal unit problem [28,29]—describes the set of challenges associated with not knowing the “true” spatiotemporal context(s) that influences individual behavior (assuming that individual behavior is in fact influenced by contextual factors). In the absence of knowledge about such “behaviorally meaningful” geographies [26], researchers are left to approximate neighborhood units in empirical analyses, frequently using areas delimited by straight line distances or administrative boundaries [30]. However, there are few a priori reasons to assume that these types of boundaries are causally relevant to an individual’s behavior ([28,29]; [31], p. 134). To the contrary, they tend to be chosen for convenience with respect to data availability [20,21]. This means that the analytical units that regularly feature in quantitative neighborhood effects studies might, and presumably do, differ from actual spatial contexts that affect individuals. Such circumstances can produce spurious statistical associations between (misspecified) geographical contexts and individual behavior; or, they can lead to false negatives whereby “causally relevant” contexts do in fact influence individual behavior, but these effects are not detected by the misspecified models [28,29].
None of this is to say that extant scholarship on neighborhood effects which relies on administrative boundaries is unsound. In fact, this stream of literature has created a strong base of circumstantial evidence to suggest that individuals’ behaviors are indeed influenced by their spatial environments [32,33]. Nevertheless, in the context of the UGCoP, incautious assumptions that administrative boundaries adequately double as neighborhoods can lead to inferential errors [28,29]. Thus, it is useful for neighborhood effects researchers to begin their investigations by constructing well-grounded “conceptual model[s] that clearly specif[y] the causal pathways among contextual and outcomes variables”. This practice will aid in identifying “appropriate methods that can be used to better approximate the true geographic context[s] for the individuals being studied” ([29], p. 249).
Toward these ends, this article argues that crossing relatively underexplored disciplinary boundaries can provide new insights for building the types of “sound conceptual models” that might currently be undersupplied in the prevailing neighborhood effects literature [29]. In particular, recent research from the field of evolutionary studies is drawn on for its instructive work on conceptualizing and modeling neighborhood effects as cross-level phenomena, whereby multiple, interacting spatial contexts influence individual behavior. These contributions guide the development of a statistical model that seeks to explain how individual property maintenance behavior in a selected U.S. study area changes as a function of neighborhood property conditions. Empirical tests of the model produce evidence suggestive of neighborhood effects operating at two interacting spatial levels that do not coincide with conventional administrative boundaries. While they are proffered as exploratory, these results nonetheless support the argument that interdisciplinary evolutionary research on social behavior can add value to studies of neighborhoods and neighborhood effects. That being said, to begin the investigation, it is necessary to briefly grapple with the idea of a “neighborhood” at a conceptual and operational level.

2. Conceptualizing and Operationalizing “Neighborhood”

In a special (neighborhood-themed) issue of Urban Studies, Galster offers a parsimonious definition of neighborhood: “a bundle of spatially based attributes associated with clusters of residences” ([26], p. 2112). To the degree that the “geographic scale across which an attribute varies…is wildly dissimilar among attributes”, this definition suggests that the extent, boundaries, or even existence of a neighborhood depend on what attribute is being considered ([26], pp. 2113–14). Put differently, the contextual or compositional dimension of interest (e.g., the amount of local demographic homogeneity; see [4]) is itself what determines where and when a neighborhood exists [26]. Interacting this observation with Galster’s [8] concept of a “neighborhood externality space”, which is an “area over which changes in one or more spatially based attributes initiated by others” alter the well-being of a given resident ([26], p. 2114, emphasis added), a neighborhood comes to be seen as a relation defined on a set of residences (see [34]).
Grannis [6] asserts that the specific relation of interest is “neighboring”. Neighboring, in turn, is a superposed relation that contains four levels, each of which necessarily follows from the one before (below) it. The foundational level of this relation—that on which all spatial neighborhoods are based—is geographic availability (“stage one neighboring”). Geographic availability is a function of relative, not absolute, proximity. When households are relatively proximate, actors are geographically available to experience passive contacts (“stage 2 neighboring”), passive contacts may then lead to intentional contacts (“stage 3 neighboring”), and intentional/active contacts can eventually produce mutual trust and a sense of community among neighbors (“stage 4 neighboring”) ([6], pp. 17–19).
On that backdrop, where relative proximity of residences behaviorally affects residents, the trappings of a neighborhood are in place [6]. Grannis argues that such situations very regularly manifest on one’s face block [6]. A face block “includes all of the dwellings that front…the same segment of the same street…between…two cross streets”. Within these spatial units, which terminate at street intersections, the probability of experiencing regular [at minimum] passive neighborly contacts is sufficiently high ([6], pp. 31–33). More than this high probability of social contact, however, residents of the same face block are joint claimants on a collective good—a “neighborhood commons” [35]. That is, while all residents of a face block enjoy the exclusive and rival use of the interiors of their homes, the visible exteriors of their homes, and the outdoor spaces and infrastructure that exist between them, are experienced and “used” collectively by all residents of the block. As a consequence, actions taken in this shared space—say, neglecting outdoor property maintenance and upkeep—affects the quality of the neighborhood commons for all residents of the block [36]. This observation implies that face blocks are likely to be “behaviorally meaningful” [26] and/or “causally relevant” [28,29] spatial contexts for a substantial fraction of the population.

Multiple Neighborhood Levels and Cross-Level Interactions

Importantly, face blocks rarely exist as islands that are closed off to other parts of human settlements. Thus, although face blocks constitute an intuitive and intimate spatial context that assumedly influences individual behavior [6], they are only one of many possible geographic environments that perform this function [28,29,33]. Acknowledging this point, many neighborhood effects studies in the social sciences have leveraged multilevel model specifications that classify observations into more than one (typically nested) group. For instance, persons might be grouped into households, with households grouped on face blocks, and face blocks grouped within, say, [clusters of] U.S. census tracts (e.g., [21,37]). Such model specifications allow researchers to “separately estimate the predictive effects of an individual predictor and its group-level mean”, where the latter are interpreted as contextual (i.e., neighborhood) effects ([38], p. 434). In this way, neighborhood effects can be detected at multiple levels in a spatial hierarchy [37].
There is tremendous value in conceptualizing neighborhoods as multilevel entities [39,40], and in detecting their effects at multiple geographic levels [21,33,37,41]. Yet, while these objectives have received ample attention from social scientists in recent decades [21], there has been comparably less effort aimed at detecting cross-level interactions in contextual effects research [41]. To articulate what is meant by “cross-level interactions”, this article adopts the definitions of the terms “level” and “scale” that are given in [42]. Specifically, scale refers to the “spatial, temporal, quantitative, or analytical dimensions used to measure and study any phenomenon”; and levels are the “units of analysis…located at different positions on a scale” ([42], p. 2). In other words, the spatial scale consists of a continuous range of levels including, for example, face blocks, cities, and regions [42]. With that in mind, cross-level interactions can be defined as “interactions among levels within a [spatial] scale” ([42], p. 2).
Consider a case of two geographic levels: (1) a face block and (2) the set of all face blocks connected to that face block by an intersection. The preceding section made the case that circumstances on one’s face block are likely to affect one’s behavior. Similarly, to the extent that “customary travel [is] one of the strongest influences” on an individual’s ability to mentally picture parts of a city ([43], pp. 49–50), the face blocks that are directly connected to one’s own block—insofar as one or more of these streets needs to be accessed each time one travels outside of one’s immediate vicinity—plausibly structure at least part of an individual’s cognitive image of his or her “neighborhood” [43]. Consequently, there is reason to believe that both of the aforementioned geographic levels are “behaviorally meaningful” [26] and “causally relevant” [28,29] for a given individual.
If one assumes that contextual effects are present at both levels of this two-level schema, then a given individual’s “neighborhood context” can take on one of two qualitative states. First, the two spatial levels of the individual’s neighborhood may exhibit congruence in the values of key contextual variables [41]. In other words, the contextual attributes of the face block are the same as, or sufficiently similar to, the contextual attributes of the wider spatial environment that also includes all connecting face blocks. Second, the two levels may be incongruent, or such that conditions on the given face block differ significantly from conditions on the surrounding face blocks [41]. Whether the contextual effects associated with two (in)congruent spatial levels have reinforcing or balancing influences depends on the precise effects and behaviors under investigation. Hence, the nature of these effects ought to be engaged with at a conceptual level, prior to empirical analysis. That being said, neighborhood effects studies that do consider the possibility of cross-level interactions have done so: (1) via empirical models that hypothesize significant cross-level interactions in contextual effects, but that do not anticipate ex ante the directions of these effects and (2) using administrative geographies, such as U.S. census block groups and municipal boundaries, as proxies for behaviorally meaningful spatial contextual levels [41]. In response to these openings for further research, the remainder of this article: (1) draws on literature from evolutionary studies to construct a conceptual model that leads to testable hypotheses about the direction and nature of cross-level neighborhood effects and (2) in such a way that it grapples with the UGCoP. Concerning the latter, the empirical analysis forgoes reliance on comparatively arbitrary administrative boundaries to proxy for behaviorally meaningful or causally relevant neighborhood contexts.

3. Conceptual Model

A review of scholarship on the evolution of social structure is beyond the scope of this article, and interested readers can obtain a deeper understanding of this work from other sources [44,45,46,47,48,49]. For present purposes, consider only that evolution is a dynamic process in which individual-level variations have population-level consequences [50,51]. When variation in individual characteristics makes some actors better adapted to a shared environment than others, the frequency with which the “fitter” individuals’ characteristics occur in the overall population will increase with time [47,50,51]. This observation sometimes leads to the misimpression that evolutionary processes disfavor cooperation among individuals—for, acting cooperatively tends to be costlier than free-riding on the efforts of others, which implies that non-cooperative strategies outcompete cooperative strategies in overall (randomly assorted) populations [48]. Such scenarios are frequently portrayed in the context of a prisoner’s dilemma, wherein “defecting” strictly dominates (for any given individual) the strategy of “cooperating”. The implication is that cooperation is an unlikely population-level outcome [45].
It is obvious, however, that cooperative social outcomes occur in the real world [48,50,51,52,53]. One way that evolutionists explain this seeming inconsistency is by recognizing the important role of positive correlation in individual interactions [44,45,49,50,51]. Namely, if cooperators are more likely to interact with other cooperators in a given environment than they are with defectors—i.e., if cooperative behavior exhibits positive correlation—then cooperative outcomes can be locally adaptive [45]. Moreover, if populations are positively assorted into spatial groups or neighborhoods, then the relative success of cooperative groups in these configurations can bring about population-wide cooperation [54,55,56]. An observable implication here is that non-cooperative behaviors make individuals relatively worse off when they live within a sufficiently high concentration of cooperators [44,46,48]. By the same token, being a cooperator in a neighborhood of all defectors puts the prosocial minority at a distinct (relative) disadvantage [54]. Accordingly, individuals tend to adjust their behaviors to make themselves at least as successful as other members in their reference groups—e.g., defectors living among all cooperators begin to cooperate [36]. In familiar terms, individuals in these evolutionary models are subject to “neighborhood effects” ([44], p. 24). Features from evolutionary models might therefore apply more generally to examinations of contextual influences in the social sciences.
To support this claim, insights from evolutionary studies are used here to create a conceptual model in which neighborhood effects are both multi- and cross-level. Explicitly, Skyrms [44] describes a model that features what he calls geographically nested “imitation” and “interaction” neighborhoods. In this two-level spatial environment, cooperation spreads via imitation in a given locale when non-cooperative agents interact with sufficiently many cooperators in their immediate neighbor networks. However, the strength of this imitation effect is conditioned by the (non-)cooperation norms that prevail in a wider spatial context that contains, and extends beyond, both the given individual and the nearest neighbors whose behavior that individual is inclined to imitate. More precisely, the norms that prevail in an individual’s comparatively inclusive “interaction neighborhood” modify the probability with which he or she copies the behavior(s) of actors living in his or her more intimate “imitation neighborhood” [44].
To help clarify these abstract concepts, consider that an imitation neighborhood might consist of the set of households on one’s face block, as argued above in Section 2. An interaction neighborhood might then extend beyond the face block to include, for instance, all of the households on one’s face block, plus all of the households on face blocks that share a street intersection with the given face block (refer to Section 2) [6]. In the interest of tractability, the remainder of this article refers to Skyrms’ [44] higher resolution imitation neighborhoods as a “level-1 neighborhoods”, and the lower resolution interaction neighborhoods as a “level-2 neighborhoods”. Hence, all that readers must remember is that, as one is smaller than two, level-1 neighborhoods are geographically smaller (more compact and localized) than level-2 neighborhoods.
With the preceding definitions in hand, Figure 1 proposes a general conceptual model of how individual-level defection (or cooperation), broadly defined, is influenced by local context in a two-level environment similar to the one described by Skyrms [44]. In any given time period, t, the probability that an individual engages in some antisocial or non-cooperative behavior depends on that individual’s behavior in an earlier time period, t-1. This is a straightforward expectation which acknowledges that individuals are likely to exhibit similar behavioral tendencies across time [57]. More interesting is the model’s hypothesized neighborhood effects. Namely, defection (or cooperation) is assumed to be directly influenced by one’s level-1 neighborhood context. That is, one is prone to conform to the behaviors of his or her nearest and most frequent interactants. However, the magnitude of this relationship is expected to change based on the wider geographic context in which one’s level-1 neighborhood is embedded, and in which one regularly observes local descriptive norms. Put another way, the influence that actions taken within one’s level-1 neighborhood have on one’s own behavior is moderated by the context of one’s level-2 neighborhood. The probability that an individual imitates the (non-)cooperative behavior(s) of his or her neighbors is therefore not a constant property of a spatial system—it varies with geographic variation in level-2 social norms. While other neighborhood “levels” are most certainly relevant to an individual’s behavior, only two are considered here for parsimony.
Figure 1. A two-level model of neighborhood effects with cross-level interactions.
Figure 1. A two-level model of neighborhood effects with cross-level interactions.
Socsci 04 01046 g001

4. Hypotheses, Data, and Methods

Cross-level neighborhood effects models like the one proposed in Figure 1 are regularly tested in the evolutionary literature by simulating outcomes of hypothetical interactions on imaginary rectangular lattices [44,46,48]. In contrast, the model in Figure 1 is tested here for a real world case to explore the influences that substandard property conditions have on individual behavior in a selected city: Buffalo, NY, USA. Property conditions are of interest inasmuch as they are a decisive “spatially based attribute” (see Section 2) for demarcating residential neighborhoods or housing submarkets [11,12,14]. This is not to say that property conditions are the exclusive spatially based attribute for defining neighborhood contexts and studying neighborhood effects. The variable is merely one important attribute that can be measured, and thus it can be used to explore the implications of the conceptual model in Figure 1. On that note, property conditions in the selected study area are measured with parcel-level data on local property code compliance. Because property codes specify the minimum standards to which a built structure must legally be maintained, violation of these codes is an indicator of substandard conditions [58]. In this sense, property code violation is effectively a non-cooperative social behavior (defection), while compliance is a cooperative behavior. In what follows, therefore, “violation” and “defection” (refer to Figure 1) are used interchangeably, as are “compliance” and “cooperation”.
That being said, it is necessary to caution that code violations are an imperfect measure of defection of or cooperation with neighborhood property maintenance norms. Property inspections institutions tend to be complaint-driven, and they are embedded within local sociopolitical and cultural environments [58]. Both of these points suggest that patterns of property code violations are observable outcomes of complex processes that cannot be adequately modeled using readily available micro-level data. For instance, the Appendix shows that property code violations, when aggregated to the U.S. Census block group level (i.e., an administrative geographic unit for which data are readily accessible), appear to vary systematically with: (1) local median home value; (2) local conditions of poverty; (3) average education levels; and (4) racial diversity. The former three variables speak to the intuitive notions that property upkeep is likely to correlate with both higher residential property values and economic advantage [36]. The fourth variable supports Putnam’s [59] highly-cited finding that ethnic diversity erodes social cohesion and cooperation. The upshot is that, while these four, and potentially many other, variables are probably involved in the processes that generate patterns of property code violations, they are typically only observable at administrative geographic levels. And, as argued above, assuming that measures taken from administrative geographic units have “causal relevance” for micro-level behavior is problematic in the context of the UGCoP [28,29]. For that reason, the analyses presented in this article rely exclusively on variables that can be measured for the individual and neighborhood levels that follow from the article’s a priori engagements with the UGCoP (see Section 2, Section 2.1, and Section 4.2). Because this choice necessarily omits relevant (but unmeasurable) variables from consideration, both the forthcoming analyses and the results obtained therefrom are proffered as exploratory, and intended only to test the implications of the model in Figure 1 using real world data.
Minding these caveats, code violations are arguably one of the more relevant outcome variables that can be accessed with secondary data sources—at the resolution of an individual parcel—in pursuit of this article’s objectives. Indeed, the data obtained for this project were acquired at no financial cost through public information requests. Future studies with access to funding for primary data collection—in which more finely-tuned and customizable outcome and explanatory variables can be measured—will add significant value to this work.

4.1. Hypotheses

Prior to discussing the data available for this project in greater detail, it is necessary to convert the relationships from Figure 1 into testable hypotheses. At the simplest level for chosen the empirical application, the model claims that an individual’s likelihood of violating the city’s property code in time t is a function of (1) the individual’s property code violation behavior in t-1, and (2) the t-1 violation rate in the individual’s level-1 neighborhood. It is straightforward to hypothesize that these two explanatory variables will have direct relationships with the dependent variable, which is the probability that an individual defects in time t. To make things slightly more complicated, however, the latter relationship is expected to manifest differently in different level-2 neighborhood contexts. In order to construct an informed hypothesis about this effect, it is useful to once again consult the evolutionary literature which guided development of the underlying conceptual model.
Instructive evolutionary models of social structure imply that an individual is likely to imitate the behaviors of his or her neighbors when those neighbors are successful “mutants” or “invaders” in the local environment—that is, when their behavior deviates from local norms in ways that increase their adaptedness to the environment relative to the given individual [44,46,48]. This observation implicates a specific hypothesis about the moderated relationship shown in Figure 1. Namely, in highly cooperative level-2 neighborhoods, violating is essentially a “mutant” behavior: the extant descriptive norm in cooperative neighborhoods is property code compliance. Consequently, in cooperative settings, an increase in the violation/defection rate in one’s level-1 neighborhood is likely to amplify the degree to which a given property owner violates the property code. The rationale is that free-riding level-1 neighbors do not incur the costs of cooperation, but they still enjoy the benefits of living in a cooperative level-2 neighborhood. With this line of reasoning in place, one is left with three testable hypotheses. The probability that an individual in the selected study area violates property code regulations in time t:
(1)
is higher for individuals who violated the property code in time t-1;
(2)
increases as a direct function of the individual’s level-1 neighborhood violation rate; but such that;
(3)
this “neighborhood effect” is amplified in cooperative level-2 neighborhoods (and, by extension, is muted in non-cooperative level-2 neighborhoods).
Given the above, the outstanding task is to operationalize level-1 and level-2 neighborhoods in a way that engages with the UGCoP. To proceed in that direction, the next section introduces the data available for this project.

4.2. Data

Data for the street addresses associated with all outstanding property code violations in Buffalo, NY were obtained through a public information request to the city’s Department of Management Information Systems. The request produced records for all unresolved property code violations through the end of the second quarter in 2009 [60]. These records were batch geocoded in Esri ArcGIS 10.2 with a success rate exceeding 95 percent. The matched records were then joined to their respective real property tax parcels in a Geographic Information System (GIS). By joining the micro-level property code data to a geographic parcel dataset acquired from the city’s Office of Strategic Planning, every parcel in the study area can be coded as either cooperative (i.e., not associated with a violation) or non-cooperative (i.e., associated with a violation) during a given year. The dependent variable is then operationalized using the most recent observations (2008–2009) from the dataset. In turn, it is possible to calculate the fraction of a property’s neighbors who were violators prior to the focal year (i.e., pre-2008–2009).
To facilitate this calculation, U.S. Census TIGER/Line shapefiles for 2010 were used to construct face blocks from the Census Bureau’s spatial data on all streets in Buffalo (refer to Section 2) [61]. Upon joining all parcels from the citywide parcel dataset to their respective face blocks in a GIS, the number of parcels on each face block was summed, and a minimum threshold of three “neighbors” was used to retain or exclude parcels from the sample. Parcels situated on face blocks with fewer than three total parcels were dropped from the sample. This step was taken to ensure that each parcel (owner) in the analysis was part of a social environment, where sociologists and network theorists claim that social networks, and societies more generally, require at least three agents to exist [62]. From there, the fraction of parcels with outstanding code violations was quantified for (1) each parcel’s face block, and (2) the total of the parcel’s face block and all of the face blocks with which the given block shares a street intersection. In this manner, each observation in the dataset is connected to parcel-specific level-1 and level-2 neighborhoods. Moreover, the particular geographies used to operationalize these parcel-specific level-1 and level-2 neighborhoods follow directly from the engagements with the UGCoP that can be found earlier in this article (Section 2).

4.3. Methods

The three hypotheses enumerated in Section 4.1 can be tested in a regression model with interaction effects [41,63]. Namely, if the hypotheses are suitable, then performing a regression of individual-level violation behavior in t on the (1) level-1 neighborhood violation rate in t-1, (2) level-2 neighborhood violation rate in t-1, and (3) product of (2) and (3), ought to produce statistically significant nonzero coefficients on all three of these terms [41,63]. This statement effectively describes a space-time regression model in which the dependent variable is explained by a time-lagged measure of itself at both neighborhood and individual levels [36,64]. Because violation behavior is binary coded, a limited dependent variable regression method, such as logit, is the appropriate modeling choice. The resulting empirical model takes the following form:
Y i , t = f ( Y i , t 1 , w Y i , t 1 l e v e l 1 , w Y i , t 1 l e v e l 2 , [ w Y i , t 1 l e v e l 1 * w Y i , t 1 l e v e l 2 ] , O w n e r s h i p )
where Y i , t is the observed dichotomous dependent variable that takes on a value of 1 if individual i defected in period t and a value of 0 otherwise, w Y i , t 1 l e v e l 1 is the fraction of violators observed for i’s face block in period t-1, w Y i , t 1 l e v e l 2 is the fraction of violators observed for i’s face block and connected face blocks during period t-1, and Ownership is a measure of housing tenure. More specifically with respect to the latter variable, in the context of O’Brien’s [65] finding that homeownership increases cooperative property maintenance behavior in cities, the Ownership variable takes on a value of 1 if a given parcel is estimated to be owner-occupied and a value of 0 otherwise. Values for this variable are estimated using the procedure described in [65], which entails identifying exact matches in Buffalo’s geospatial parcel dataset between a parcel’s physical address and its owner’s mailing address. This imputed ownership predictor is expected to take on a highly significant and negative relationship with the violation dependent variable [65,66].
Next, recall that the code violation dataset does not completely cover the most recent year of data (see [60]). As such, the dependent variable is measured for the partial year of 2009 plus the most recent full year of data. This choice has the added benefit of increasing variation in the dependent variable [67]. That being said, because the code violation dataset describes outstanding violations, t-1 is set to include all violations that were unresolved (still present) on 31 December 2007, regardless of the date on which they were first recorded. The distributions of these two measures are mapped in Figure 2, which depicts the density of outstanding pre-2008 violations relative to the locations of violations committed in 2008–2009.
Finally, consider that the number of property violations observed in 2008–2009 (q = 6130) is small relative to the total number of parcels included in the citywide GIS dataset (N = 90,614) (NB: N excludes parcels that are situated on face blocks with fewer than three total parcels). To compensate for this disparity, estimation of the statistical model is carried out with the prior correction rare events logit (relogit) model proposed by King and Zeng [68]. This method corrects for rare events bias in the model through its intercept, based on the population violation rate. Because the population rate in this case is known (q/N ≈ 7 percent), the relogit model allows the author to decrease the large number of non-violators (M = 84,484) in the dataset in order to increase efficiency in carrying out the analysis [68]. Accordingly, a random sample of m = 6130 non-violators was taken and combined with the q = 6130 violators to form an analytical sample of n = 12,260. The reduced number of observations decreases computing time and virtual memory requirements, while insuring against rare events bias by adjusting the intercept of the model to account for the known population violation rate of approximately seven percent [68]. Table 1 presents descriptive sample statistics for these data.
Figure 2. Distribution of violations in the study area.
Figure 2. Distribution of violations in the study area.
Socsci 04 01046 g002
Table 1. Characteristics of sample data.
Table 1. Characteristics of sample data.
VariableMeanStandard Deviation
Individual Violationt-1 *0.14n/a
Level-1 Neighborhood Violatorst-10.120.11
Level-2 Neighborhood Violatorst-10.120.07
Ownership (imputed) *0.47n/a
Number of parcels in Level-1 Neighborhood36.924.4
Number of parcels in Level-2 Neighborhood106.348.4
n12,260
* indicates dichotomous variable (i.e., mean = proportion in sample); Known population violation rate for relogit model calibration = 0.07.

5. Results

The results from estimating the relogit model are presented in Table 2. The first column gives the output from estimating a base model that is evaluated to ensure that both the level-1 and level-2 neighborhood variables are significant predictors of individual violation behavior, holding the other (and all else) constant (see [63]). Because the base model does establish this condition, the second column proceeds to show the results from estimating the full model, which features a multiplicative interaction term between the two level-based neighborhood regressors. As hypothesized, the two neighborhood variables, and their cross-level interaction, are all significant predictors of individual violation behavior in the study area.
Table 2. Relogit estimation results, dependent variable = individual violation in period t.
Table 2. Relogit estimation results, dependent variable = individual violation in period t.
VariableWithout Product TermFull Model
Coefficient (Standard Error)Coefficient (Standard Error)
Individual Violationt-10.41 *** (0.05)0.41 *** (0.05)
Level-1 Neighborhood Violatorst-10.49 * (0.23)2.91 *** (0.39)
Level-2 Neighborhood Violatorst-12.46 *** (0.35)4.41 *** (0.43)
(Level-1 Neighborhood Violatorst-1 x Level-2 Neighborhood Violatorst-1)-−14.57 *** (1.85)
Ownership−0.57 *** (0.04)−0.56 *** (0.04)
Intercept−2.74 *** (0.04)−2.98 *** (0.05)
*** p < 0.001 * p < 0.05; Robust standard errors in parentheses; Estimation carried out with the relogit model for Zelig written by Imai et al. [69]; n = 12,260 observations.
Before discussing the apparent neighborhood effects in detail, observe that the two non-neighborhood predictors from the model are both statistically significant and have the expected relationships with the dependent variable. In the first place, one’s past violation behavior is predictive of his or her current violation behavior. Exponentiating the estimated logit coefficient on this variable shows that the odds of violating the property code in t are about 1.5 times greater for individuals who previously violated the property code, all else being equal. This result supports extant findings that individuals’ past property maintenance behaviors carry over to present situations [36,57]. Concerning the remaining variable, imputed homeownership is found to have a significant and negative effect on property code violation. Exponentiating the inverse of the Ownership coefficient suggests that the odds of committing a violation in the given time period are approximately 1.8 times greater for non-owners relative to owner-occupants, holding all else constant. This finding is consistent with existing empirical evidence of a positive relationship between homeownership and prosocial property maintenance behavior [65,66].
Crucially, controlling for the influences of owner-occupancy and past violation behavior does not eliminate the hypothesized neighborhood effects on one’s current behavior (Table 2). Rather, the observed violation rates in one’s level-1 and level-2 neighborhoods significantly affect one’s compliance with the study area’s property code. Further, the significance of the product term implies that the strength of the relationship between one’s behavior and the number of violators in one’s level-1 neighborhood is in fact moderated by the fraction of violators in one’s wider level-2 neighborhood (Figure 1). Note, though, that the presence of this product term means that the estimated logit coefficients represent conditional (simple), not general (main), effects [63]. Stated differently, each neighborhood-level coefficient represents the given variable’s marginal effect on the logged odds that an individual commits a property violation in t, holding the other variable at zero. Because these coefficients are not conveniently interpretable, it is useful to extend this analysis beyond Table 2.
One way of doing this is to set the explanatory variables to meaningful values and take simulation draws on the model to generate distributions (and expected values) for selected quantities of interest [70]. Continuing with the exploratory theme of this investigation, one might want to model the responsiveness of cooperative homeowners to their neighborhood contexts. Because both prior cooperative behavior and homeownership are estimated to decrease an individual’s probability of committing property code violations (Table 2), it is interesting to simulate the change in violation probability for such individuals in different multilevel neighborhood contexts. If the probability of violation remains constant across contexts, then the case for neighborhood effects is weakened. If, however, similar individuals show different propensities for violating in different contexts, then the circumstantial evidence produced to this point is strongly reinforced. Furthermore, the simulation exercise offers a case-based approach to considering the third hypothesis from the preceding section, as explained below.
To facilitate the simulation exercise, the Individual Violationt-1 predictor is set to 0, the Ownership predictor is set to 1, the Level-1 Neighborhood Violatorst-1 predictor is allowed to range from 0 to 1 in increments of 0.01, and the moderating Level-2 Neighborhood Violatorst-1 predictor is evaluated for three different scenarios: (1) the mean level of 0.12; (2) a “low” value of 0.00, or a 100% reduction in the number of level-2 violators relative to the mean; and (3) a “high” value of 0.24, or a 100% increase in the number of level-2 violators relative to the mean. For each of these three level-2 neighborhood contexts, 1000 simulation draws are taken from the estimated relogit model for every possible value in the above-specified range of the level-1 neighborhood variable. Doing this allows for calculation of the expected probability that a cooperative homeowner violates the property code in period t, given (1) the t-1 behavior of actors in his or her level-1 neighborhood and (2) his or her presence in a high-, mean-, or low-violation level-2 neighborhood as defined above. Because the expected value of the dependent variable is a simulation of the predicted probability of observing a violation (given a draw of the estimated coefficients from their sampling distributions), this process further allows for the construction of confidence intervals around all of the expected probabilities [70,71].
Figure 3 plots the expected probability of violating for cooperative owner occupants against the fraction of violators in one’s level-1 neighborhood. The three separate functions correspond to the three level-2 neighborhood contexts set forth above. Each function is graphed along with its 84% and 94% confidence intervals. These intervals are selected for empirical reasons. Explicitly, while non-overlap of traditional confidence intervals (e.g., 95%) indicates statistically significant differences at the specified level of confidence, the converse is not necessarily true [72]. Thus, plotting, say, the 95% confidence intervals in Figure 3 would not permit readers to visually assess whether differences observed in the expected probabilities of violating across the three neighborhood contexts are statistically significant when overlap is present. However, empirical research suggests that overlap in 84% confidence intervals approximates a test for statistically significant differences at a 95% level of confidence—that is, when 84% confidence intervals overlap, differences in expected values are not significant at a 95% confidence level [72,73,74]. Overlap in 94% confidence intervals has a similar interpretation for a 99% level of confidence [74]. Accordingly, the (non-)overlap in the confidence intervals plotted in Figure 3 facilitates visual assessment of the statistical significance of differences observed across the graph at two standard levels of confidence.
Figure 3. Simulating violation behavior for cooperative owner occupants in three level-2 neighborhood contexts.
Figure 3. Simulating violation behavior for cooperative owner occupants in three level-2 neighborhood contexts.
Socsci 04 01046 g003
Notice in Figure 3 that previously cooperative homeowners in low violation (high cooperation) level-2 neighborhoods are estimated to be more responsive to violation behavior within their level-1 neighborhoods than equivalent individuals in high violation (low cooperation) level-2 neighborhoods. In fact, the expected probability that cooperative homeowners violate the property code in highly non-cooperative level-2 neighborhoods remains relatively constant across the whole range of behavior in their level-1 neighborhoods. The reason that this finding might appear odd at first is that, one might expect a level-2 neighborhood norm of high violation to always make an individual more likely to violate compared to a neighborhood norm of low violation. However, this reasoning overlooks the evolutionary nature of the decision environment. Specifically, recall that Figure 3 corresponds to previously cooperative homeowners. Stated another way, all individuals of interest complied with the property code prior to 2008, even those living in the “high violation” level-2 neighborhoods where cooperation was low. Adopting the terminology used earlier to develop the three hypotheses tested by the statistical model, in “high violation” level-2 neighborhoods, violating is not a “mutant” behavior—it is the descriptive property maintenance norm. Hence, in such contexts, a given [compliant] property owner is plausibly what the evolutionary and experimental game theory literatures call an “unconditional cooperator” [75]. Such owners do not condition their behaviors on the actions of others, which, consistent with the relatively flat line in Figure 3, appears to be the case for cooperative homeowners who live in non-cooperative level-2 neighborhoods.
Extending this reasoning, the third hypothesis tested by the empirical model stated that behavioral copying in level-1 neighborhoods (i.e., level-1 neighborhood effects) will occur most frequently when level-1 neighbors are mutant violators living in relatively cooperative level-2 neighborhoods [44]. This expectation is borne out in Figure 3: the probability that cooperative homeowners who live in cooperative level-2 neighborhoods violate the property code increases at an increasing rate with the number of violators in their level-1 neighborhoods. Even though these owners are significantly less likely than their counterparts in average- or high-violation neighborhoods to behave non-cooperatively when their level-1 neighbors are mostly cooperators (in this case, their contexts are congruent), beyond a threshold, their increasingly incongruent neighborhood contexts make them significantly more likely to violate the property code than other, similar individuals. In this vein, level-1 neighborhood effects are seemingly present and strong in cooperative level-2 neighborhoods. Similar effects are present, though somewhat weaker, in level-2 neighborhoods with average levels of (non-)cooperation.
In that light, the negative coefficient on the product term in Table 2 can be interpreted to describe an urban environment with cross-level neighborhood effects. Cooperative owner occupants are extremely responsive to the behaviors of their non-cooperative neighbors when their broader geographic contexts are mostly cooperative. Likewise, they are relatively nonresponsive to these influences when the local norm is defection. Taken together, the results from Table 2 and Figure 3 offer convincing support for the three hypotheses that were derived from the conceptual model in Figure 1. Moreover, as argued in the preceding paragraph, these findings fit very well with the empirical and theoretical work of evolutionary game theorists [44,46,48]. As such, they seem to provide justification for making more and stronger connections between neighborhood effects research and evolutionary studies.

6. Discussion and Conclusions

Empirical research on neighborhood effects in the social and behavioral sciences faces a number of analytical challenges, not least of which is the uncertain geographic context problem (UGCoP). The UGCoP refers to the observation that when modeled contextual units differ from “causally relevant” geographic contexts, empirical results from neighborhood effects studies are at risk of being spurious and unreliable ([28,29]; [31], p. 134). In this sense, the UGCoP not only implicates the need to “operationalize neighborhoods better” ([27], p. 2791); it also emphasizes the need to conceptualize the pathways by which neighborhoods affect individuals [23,28,29]. As it stands, much of the literature on neighborhood effects fails to engage with these issues in a sufficiently careful manner. Rather, data limitations regularly lead researchers to assume that single-level, data-rich administrative units such as census geographies are causally relevant “neighborhoods” for studied individuals—even though this assumption is unlikely to hold [6,20,21,22,30].
The first part of this paper tackled the above challenges by joining a behaviorally meaningful conceptualization of neighborhoods from the social sciences [4,5,6] to formal, cross-level models of neighborhood effects from the evolutionary literature on social behavior. This synthesis led to a general conceptual model of how contextual influences operate on individual-level behavior in a two-level geographic environment with cross-level interactions. From there, the second part of the paper shifted to application. Drawing on the aforementioned conceptual model, a statistical model was set up to test three hypotheses using parcel-level data on property code violations in Buffalo, NY, USA. It was argued that “neighborhood” code violation (non-cooperative) behavior influences individual behavior at (at least) two interacting geographic levels. Testing the model supported this assertion by revealing a moderated relationship: most property owners exhibit a disposition toward imitating the behavior of other owners in their level-1 neighborhoods, but such that the magnitude of this relationship changes according to the descriptive social norms that are present in their level-2 neighborhoods (Figure 1). Simulations then offered a detailed look at these influences for the specific case of cooperative homeowners. The findings showed that neighborhood contexts matter (Figure 3). Precisely, when the level-1 neighborhood of a cooperative owner occupant who lives in a cooperative level-2 neighborhood is “invaded” by non-compliant behavior, the probability that such an owner commits a violation increases at an increasing rate. Alternatively, ostensibly “unconditionally cooperative” owners who live in non-cooperative level-2 neighborhoods are unresponsive to violations in their level-1 neighborhoods.
Arguably, these results show that there are gains to be made from connecting neighborhood effects research in the social sciences to literature in evolutionary studies. Still, it is important to caution that the results of this article are preliminary and exploratory, and are not without limitations. First, the behavior of interest—violation of or compliance with property codes—is presumably appropriate for studying (non-)cooperative property upkeep at the individual level [58]. However, it is necessary to point out once more that this outcome variable is an imperfect proxy variable (see Section 4 and Appendix).
Second, future tests of multilevel contextual effects on individual behavior with cross-level interactions must work to identify and operationalize additional individual-level controls. The inclusion of estimated homeownership in the article’s statistical model is a step in this direction. Nonetheless, it is necessary to ensure that evidence of cross-level neighborhood effects is robust to models that contain more comprehensive information on attributes of the individual (e.g., ethnicity, age, socioeconomic status). Not only can these variables act as controls in the model, but they can also be used to aggregate individual data to custom “neighborhood” geographies. Limited access to or availability of individual-level data suggests that this will be a difficult challenge for researchers to address, but it is one that needs to be taken up. Supplementing large public datasets similar to the ones used above with survey data is a potential path forward [65,66]. Applying the conceptual and empirical strategies from this paper to other cases—at various levels, in different national and political settings, and for alternative spatially based behaviors—will presumably uncover many others.
Ultimately, the complex and mostly obscured nature of neighborhoods and neighborhood effects implies that no single theoretical, methodological, or empirical approach is sufficient for understanding the types of phenomena described in this paper. For that reason, new ways of combining efforts, especially through crossing relatively underexplored disciplinary boundaries, are vital for advancing the field of neighborhood effects research. The preceding connections to evolutionary studies appear to have some value in this regard, and the author encourages extensions of this work, in both exploratory and confirmatory settings, to investigate how these linkages can be strengthened.

Appendix

One of the main reasons for framing this research as “exploratory” is the lack of micro-level data on important predictor variables. As mentioned in the main text, patterns of property code violations will likely vary systematically with patterns of wealth and economic advantage, among other attributes of the urban environment [36]. In this Appendix, U.S. Census data for the smallest administrative geographic unit at which socioeconomic variables are reported, the census block group, lend some circumstantial support to this claim. Explicitly, census data on median owner occupied home value, poverty (fraction of the population with income below the federal poverty level), and low educational attainment (fraction of the population 25 and older without a high school diploma) are adopted as indicators of economic (dis)advantage. Further, to explore the possibility that diversity erodes social cooperation [59], rough measures of diversity are considered in two dimensions. First, racial diversity is measured in the following way. The total population of each block group is divided into two subgroups: (1) white non-Hispanic (“white”) and (2) non-white. Then, the fraction of the total block group population that is white is computed. This fraction is compared to the value of 0.5—the value representing the maximum diversity possible in any given spatial unit under a two-group classification scheme—to create a unitless (rough) indicator of racial diversity. This variable was chosen over standard indices of segregation and diversity (e.g., the dissimilarity index) for simplicity. The precise calculation of the measure is given by:
R a c i a l   D i v e r s i t y = 1 | W h i t e 0.5 | 0.5
where White is the fraction of the block group population that is white. When White equals 0 or 1, the racial composition of the given block group is perfectly homogeneous in terms of the two-group classification scheme. Consequently, the index takes on a value of 0. Similarly, then White equals 0.5, the two racial groups account for equal shares of the total block group population, and the Racial Diversity index takes on a value of 1. Hence, larger values of the index indicate greater diversity. An analogous index can be created for housing tenure by subdividing occupied housing units into (1) owner occupied and (2) renter occupied subgroups. Allowing Own to be the fraction of a block group’s total occupied housing units that are owner occupied, Tenure Diversity is computed as:
T e n u r e   D i v e r s i t y = 1 | O w n 0.5 | 0.5
All of the data described above come from the 2006–2010 U.S. Census American Community Survey (ACS). The variables are used as predictors in a regression where the response is the fraction of parcels in a block group that committed property code violations in 2008–2009. Parcel-level data were aggregated to block groups in a GIS. An ordinary least squares (OLS) regression of block group-level code violations on the Census predictor variables suggests that patterns of property violations do indeed vary systematically with economic disadvantage and racial diversity (tenure diversity is not significant). Re-estimating the model to control for spatial dependence revealed in diagnostic tests reaffirms all variable-specific hypothesis tests from the OLS model, with the exception of educational attainment (Table A1). The upshot is that information on a parcel owner’s race and economic status, as well as data on the racial composition and economic conditions in that owner’s “neighborhood”, are probably needed to explain patterns of variation in code violations in a more realistic manner. Because such data are unavailable for the present study, it is necessary to position this research as but one initial step in the quantitative analysis of cross-level neighborhood effects in multilevel “behaviorally meaningful” neighborhood geographies.
Table A1. Regression estimation results, dependent variable = fraction of parcels committing new code violations in 2008–2009.
Table A1. Regression estimation results, dependent variable = fraction of parcels committing new code violations in 2008–2009.
VariableOLSSpatial Lag
Coefficient (Standard Error)Coefficient (Standard Error)
Median Owner Occupied Home Value (in $000s)−0.0001 ** (3.9 × 10−5)−7.0× 10−5* (3.4× 10−5)
Poverty Rate0.0384 ** (0.015)0.0314 * (0.013)
Fraction of Population (25 and Older) without a High School Diploma0.0497 * (0.020)0.0300 (0.017)
Racial Diversity0.0249 ** (0.007)0.0159 ** (0.006)
Tenure Diversity0.0157 (0.008)0.0091 (0.007)
Fraction of Parcels with Violations (Spatial Lag)-0.5290 *** (0.063)
Intercept0.0341 ** (0.010)0.009 (0.009)
R-squared0.2290.401 a
Robust LM (Lag)7.004 **-
Robust LM (Error)0.538-
*** p < 0.001 ** p < 0.01 * p < 0.05; a Indicates pseudo-R2 value; LM = Lagrange Multiplier; Estimation carried out with in GeoDa [64]; n = 284 census block groups (3 of 287 total census block groups were dropped due to missing data).

Conflicts of Interest

The author declares no conflict of interest.

References and Notes

  1. Gerald Suttles. The Social Construction of Communities. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1972. [Google Scholar]
  2. Albert Hunter. “The urban neighborhood: Its analytical and social contexts.” Urban Affairs Quarterly 14 (1979): 267–88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  3. Robert J. Chaskin. “Perspectives on neighborhood and community: A review of the literature.” Social Service Review 71 (1997): 521–47. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  4. Rick Grannis. “The importance of trivial streets: Pedestrian street networks and geographic patterns of residential segregation.” American Journal of Sociology 103 (1998): 1530–64. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  5. Rick Grannis. “T-communities: Pedestrian street networks and residential segregation in Chicago, Los Angeles, and New York.” City & Community 4 (2005): 295–321. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  6. Rick Grannis. From the Ground up: Translating Geography into Community through Neighbor Networks. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2008. [Google Scholar]
  7. Deborah G. Martin. “Enacting neighborhood.” Urban Geography 24 (2003): 361–85. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  8. George C. Galster. “What is neighborhood? An externality-space approach.” International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 10 (1986): 243–61. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  9. Deborah G. Martin. “‘Place-framing’ as place-making: Constituting a neighborhood for organizing and activism.” Annals of the Association of American Geographers 93 (2003): 730–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  10. Robert E. Park. “The urban community as a spatial pattern and a moral order.” In The Urban Community. Edited by Ernest W. Burgess. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1926, pp. 21–31. [Google Scholar]
  11. William Grigsby, Morton Baratz, and Duncan Maclennan. The Dynamics of Neighborhood Change and Decline. Oxford: Pergamon, 1987. [Google Scholar]
  12. Jerome Rothenberg, George C. Galster, Richard V. Butler, and John R. Pitkin. The Maze of Urban Housing Markets: Theory, Evidence, and Policy. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press, 1991. [Google Scholar]
  13. Kenneth Temkin, and William M. Rohe. “Social capital and neighborhood stability: An empirical investigation.” Housing Policy Debate 9 (1998): 61–88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  14. George C. Galster, Jackie M. Cutsinger, and Ron Malega. The Social Costs of Concentrated Poverty: Externalities to Neighboring Households and Property Owners and the Dynamics of Decline. Washington: National Poverty Center, 2006. [Google Scholar]
  15. Peter Kitchen, and Allison M. Williams. “Measuring neighborhood social change in Saskatoon, Canada: A geographic analysis.” Urban Geography 30 (2009): 261–88. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  16. Hendrik Wagenaar. “Governance, complexity, and democratic participation: How citizens and public officials harness the complexities of neighborhood decline.” The American Review of Public Administration 37 (2007): 17–50. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  17. Peter Somerville, Ellen van Beckhoven, and Ronald van Kempen. “The decline and rise of neighborhoods: The importance of neighborhood governance.” European Journal of Housing Policy 9 (2009): 25–44. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [Green Version]
  18. Christopher Jencks, and Susan E. Mayer. “The social consequences of growing up in a poor neighborhood.” In Inner-City Poverty in the United States. Edited by Laurence E. Lynn and Michael G.H. McGeary. Washington: National Academies Press, 1990, pp. 111–86. [Google Scholar]
  19. Ingrid Gould Ellen, and Margery Austin Turner. “Does neighborhood matter? Assessing recent evidence.” Housing Policy Debate 8 (1997): 833–66. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  20. Robert D. Dietz. “The estimation of neighborhood effects in the social sciences: An interdisciplinary approach.” Social Science Research 31 (2002): 539–75. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  21. Robert J. Sampson, Jeffrey D. Morenoff, and Thomas Gannon-Rowley. “Assessing ‘neighborhood effects’: Social processes and new directions in research.” Annual Review of Sociology 28 (2002): 443–78. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  22. Ruth Lupton. 'Neighborhood Effects': Can We Measure them and Does It Matter? London: Centre for Analysis and Social Exclusion, London School of Economics, 2003. [Google Scholar]
  23. George C. Galster. “The mechanism(s) of neighborhood effects: Theory, evidence, and policy implications.” In Neighborhood Effects Research: New Perspectives. Edited by Maarten van Ham, David Manley, Nick Bailey, Ludi Simpson and Duncan Maclennan. Dordrecht: Springer, 2012, pp. 23–56. [Google Scholar]
  24. Charles F. Manski. “Identification of endogenous social effects: The reflection problem.” The Review of Economic Studies 60 (1993): 531–42. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  25. Charles F. Manski. “Economic analysis of social interactions.” The Journal of Economic Perspectives 14 (2000): 115–36. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  26. George C. Galster. “On the nature of neighborhood.” Urban Studies 38 (2001): 2111–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  27. Maarten van Ham, David Manley, Nick Bailey, Ludi Simpson, and Duncan Maclennan. Neighbourhood Effects Research: New Perspectives. Houten: Springer Netherlands, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  28. Mei-Po Kwan. “The uncertain geographic context problem.” The Annals of the Association of American Geographers 102 (2012): 958–68. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  29. Mei-Po Kwan. “How GIS can help address the uncertain geographic context problem in social science research? ” Annals of GIS 18 (2012): 245–55. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  30. John M. Clapp, and Yazhen Wang. “Defining neighborhood boundaries: Are census tracts obsolete? ” Journal of Urban Economics 59 (2006): 259–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  31. Ana V. Diez Roux, and Christina Mair. “Neighborhood and health.” Annals of the New York Academy of Sciences 1168 (2010): 125–45. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  32. Ron Johnston, Carol Propper, Rebecca Sarker, Kelvyn Jones, Anne Bolster, and Simon Burgess. “Neighbourhood social capital and neighbourhood effects.” Environment and Planning A 37 (2005): 1443–59. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  33. Ron Johnston, Kelvyn Jones, Carol Propper, and Simon Burgess. “Region, local context, and voting at the 1997 General Election in England.” American Journal of Political Science 51 (2007): 640–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  34. Anthony C. Gatrell. “Concepts of space and geographical data.” In Geographic Information Systems: Principles and Applications. Edited by David J. Maguire, Michael F. Goodchild and David W. Rhind. London: Taylor & Francis, 1991, pp. 119–34. [Google Scholar]
  35. Sheila R. Foster. “Collective action and the urban commons.” Notre Dame Law Review 87 (2011): 57–134. [Google Scholar]
  36. Russell Weaver. “Evolutionary theory and neighborhood quality: A multilevel selection-inspired approach to studying urban property conditions.” Applied Research in Quality of Life, 2014. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  37. Robert J. Sampson, Stephen W. Raudenbush, and Felton Earls. “Neighborhoods and violent crime: A multilevel study of collective efficacy.” Science 277 (1997): 918–24. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  38. Andrew Gelman. “Multilevel (hierarchical) modeling: What it can and cannot do.” Technometrics 48 (2006): 432–35. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  39. Seth E. Spielman, and John R. Logan. “Using high-resolution population data to identify neighborhoods and establish their boundaries.” Annals of the Association of the American Geographers 103 (2013): 67–84. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  40. Christopher S. Fowler. “Segregation as a multiscalar phenomenon and its implications for neighborhood-scale research: The case of south Seattle 1990–2010.” Urban Geography, 2015. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  41. Brady Baybeck. “Sorting out the competing effects of racial context.” The Journal of Politics 68 (2006): 386–96. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  42. David W. Cash, W. Neil Adger, Fikret Berkes, Po Garden, Louis Lebel, Per Olsson, Lowell Pritchard, and Oran Young. “Scale and cross-scale dynamics: Governance and information in a multilevel world.” Ecology and Society 11 Article 8. (2006). Available online: http://www.ecologyandsociety.org/vol11/iss2/art8/ (accessed on 2 November 2015). [Google Scholar]
  43. Kevin Lynch. The Image of the City. Cambridge: The MIT Press, 1960. [Google Scholar]
  44. Brian Skyrms. The Stag Hunt and Social Structure. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2004. [Google Scholar]
  45. Brian Skyrms. The Evolution of Social Contract, 2nd ed. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  46. Martin A. Nowak. Evolutionary Dynamics: Exploring the Equations of Life. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2006. [Google Scholar]
  47. Richard McElreath, and Robert Boyd. Mathematical Models of Social Evolution: A Guide for the Perplexed. Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  48. Philipp Langer, Martin A. Nowak, and Christoph Hauert. “Spatial invasion of cooperation.” Journal of Theoretical Biology 250 (2008): 634–41. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  49. Martin A. Nowak, and Sarah Coakley, eds. Evolution, Games, and God: The Principle of Cooperation. Cambridge: Harvard University Press, 2012.
  50. David Sloan Wilson. Evolution for Everyone: How Darwin’s Theory Can Change the Way We Think about Our Lives. New York: Delta, 2007. [Google Scholar]
  51. David Sloan Wilson. The Neighborhood Project: Using Evolution to Improve My City, One Block at a Time. New York: Little, Brown and Company, 2011. [Google Scholar]
  52. Samuel Bowles, and Herbert Gintis. A Cooperative Species: Human Reciprocity and Its Evolution. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2013. [Google Scholar]
  53. Herbert Gintis. The Bounds of Reason: Game Theory and the Unification of the Behavioral Sciences, rev. ed. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  54. David Sloan Wilson, and Edward O. Wilson. “Rethinking the theoretical foundation of sociobiology.” The Quarterly Review of Biology 82 (2007): 327–48. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  55. Samir Okasha. Evolution and the Levels of Selection. Oxford: Clarendon, 2006. [Google Scholar]
  56. Brian Skyrms. Social Dynamics. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2014. [Google Scholar]
  57. Russell Weaver, and Sharmistha Bagchi-Sen. “Evolutionary analysis of neighborhood decline using multilevel selection theory.” Annals of the Association of American Geographers 104 (2014): 765–86. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  58. Russell Weaver. “Re-framing the urban blight problem with trans-disciplinary insights from ecological economics.” Ecological Economics 90 (2013): 168–76. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  59. Robert D. Putnam. “E pluribus unum: Diversity and community in the twenty-first century.” Scandinavian Political Studies 30 (2007): 137–74. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  60. Violations for the final two quarters of 2009 were not available in the database at the time of the data request.
  61. U.S. Census Bureau. “TIGER Geodatabases.” 2015. Available online: https://www.census.gov/geo/maps-data/data/tiger-geodatabases.html (accessed on 2 November 2015). [Google Scholar]
  62. Charles Kadushin. Understanding Social Networks. Oxford: Oxford University Press, 2012. [Google Scholar]
  63. James Jaccard, and Robert Turrisi. Interaction Effects in Multiple Regression, 2nd ed. Thousand Oaks: Sage, 2003. [Google Scholar]
  64. Luc Anselin. Exploring Spatial Data with GeoDa: A Workbook. Urbana: Center for Spatially Integrated Social Science, 2005. [Google Scholar]
  65. Dan O’Brien. “Managing the urban commons: The relative influence of individual and social incentives on the treatment of public space.” Human Nature 23 (2012): 467–89. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  66. Dan O’Brien. “Custodians and custodianship in urban neighborhoods: A methodology using reports of public issues received by a city’s 311 hotline.” Environment and Behavior 24 (2003): 304–27. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  67. Gary King, Robert O. Keohane, and Sidney Verba. Designing Social Inquiry: Scientific Inference in Qualitative Research. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1994. [Google Scholar]
  68. Gary King, and Langche Zeng. “Logistic regression in rare events data.” Political Analysis 9 (2001): 137–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  69. Kosuke Imai, Gary King, and Olivia Lau. “Relogit: Rare events logistic regression for dichotomous dependent variables.” 2010. Available online: http://gking.harvard.edu/zelig (accessed on 23 May 2013).
  70. Gary King, Michael Tomz, and Jason Wittenberg. “Making the most of statistical analyses: Improving interpretation and presentation.” American Journal of Political Science 44 (2000): 347–63. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  71. Kosuke Imai, Gary King, and Olivia Lau. “Zelig: Everyone’s Statistical Software.” 2010. Available online: http://projects.iq.harvard.edu/zelig/documentation (accessed on 23 May 2013).
  72. Steven A. Julious. “Using confidence intervals around individual means to assess statistical significance between two means.” Pharmaceutical Statistics 3 (2004): 217–22. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef]
  73. Mirjam J. Knol, Wiebe Pestman, and Diederick Grobbee. “The (mis)use of overlap of confidence intervals to assess effect modification.” European Journal of Epidemieology 26 (2011): 253–54. [Google Scholar] [CrossRef] [PubMed]
  74. Ian MacGregor-Fors, and Mark E. Payton. “Contrasting diversity values: Statistical inferences based on overlapping confidence intervals.” PLoS ONE 8 (2013): 1–4. [Google Scholar]
  75. Ernst Fehr, and Urs Fischbacher. “The economics of strong reciprocity.” In Moral Sentiments and Material Interests: The Foundations of Cooperation in Economic Life. Edited by Herbert Gintis, Samuel Bowles, Robert Boyd and Ernst Fehr. Cambridge: MIT Press, 2005, pp. 151–92. [Google Scholar]

Share and Cite

MDPI and ACS Style

Weaver, R. A Cross-Level Exploratory Analysis of “Neighborhood Effects” on Urban Behavior: An Evolutionary Perspective. Soc. Sci. 2015, 4, 1046-1066. https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci4041046

AMA Style

Weaver R. A Cross-Level Exploratory Analysis of “Neighborhood Effects” on Urban Behavior: An Evolutionary Perspective. Social Sciences. 2015; 4(4):1046-1066. https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci4041046

Chicago/Turabian Style

Weaver, Russell. 2015. "A Cross-Level Exploratory Analysis of “Neighborhood Effects” on Urban Behavior: An Evolutionary Perspective" Social Sciences 4, no. 4: 1046-1066. https://doi.org/10.3390/socsci4041046

Article Metrics

Back to TopTop