Skip to main content
Log in

Expanding RTAs, trade flows, and the multinational enterprise

  • Article
  • Published:
Journal of International Business Studies Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We test the relationship between the size of regional trade agreements (RTAs) and openness by using a gravity equation with multilateral trade factors. Our sample includes 11 RTAs, seven with constant membership and four with expanding membership. Regional trade bias declines with the size of the club; three of the four expanding RTAs have already surpassed their “optimal” size. We also explore the link between openness of the RTA and the geographic strategy of the multinational enterprise. We find strong evidence in favor of the regionalization strategy, which has been enhanced by the presence of RTAs.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. It should be noted that some are bilateral and of little importance for trade flows (Pomfret, 2006: 42).

  2. The terminology of building and stumbling blocs was first introduced by Bhagwati (1991). For relevant literature on this topic, see Section 7 in Panagariya (2000).

  3. Many political economy models of RTAs emphasize trade diversion; see Panagariya (2000).

  4. With homothetic preferences, consumers with different incomes but facing the same prices demand goods in the same proportions.

  5. The restriction β1=β2 appears to be consistent with Viner's (1950: 43) definition of pure trade. For more details, see Magee (2008), especially his Eq. (7) and accompanying text on pages 353–354.

  6. The third dummy permits us to distinguish intra-bloc export increases from RTA-induced export increases occurring at the expense of exports to non-member countries. Welfare is better measured by non-members’ imports or bloc exports than by non-members’ exports or bloc imports: see Soloaga and Winters (2001: 5–6).

  7. The modern derivations of the GE equation embedding relative prices and relative trade costs, except in the limiting case of σ=1, solve Bikker's concern that the GE ignores price adjustments: see Deardorff (1998) and Anderson and van Wincoop (2003). At the empirical implementation, the identifying restrictions that need to be imposed on the allocation equations are likely to make the three-component model (i.e., Bikker's model) less general than the GE: see Merkies and van der Meer (1988: 16–17).

  8. It should be noted that country-pair fixed (random) effects and year fixed effects provide a more flexible error term structure (i.e., u ijt =h ij +z t +ɛ ijt ) than Bikker's (i.e., u ij =v i +w j +ɛ ij ; p 327, notations have been adjusted to compare two models.).

  9. Frankel (1997: 134–136) also reports no significant difference between the “exogenous” specification and a specification with the lagged dependent variable, which is the simplest way to control for possible endogeneity.

  10. Regression results are not shown, but are available upon request. Similar findings are reported by Baldwin and Taglioni (2007).

  11. The export trade diversion effect is not statistically significant at the 10% level.

  12. The export trade diversion effect is significant at the 10% level.

  13. The list of firms is available upon request.

  14. Note that the coefficient of ASEAN, which is dropped because of multicollinearity, is equal to the RTA coefficient.

References

  • Anderson, J. E. 1979. A theoretical foundation for the gravity equation. American Economic Review, 69 (1): 106–115.

    Google Scholar 

  • Anderson, J. E., & van Wincoop, E. 2003. Gravity with gravitas: A solution to the border puzzle. American Economic Review, 93 (1): 170–192.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Andriamananjara, S. 1999. On the size and number of regional integration arrangements: A political economy model, World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 2117.

  • Baier, S. L., & Bergstrand, J. H. 2002. On the endogeneity of international trade flows and free trade agreements. Working Paper, March.

  • Baier, S. L., & Bergstrand, J. H. 2007. Do free trade agreements actually increase members’ international trade? Journal of International Economics, 71 (1): 72–95.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baldwin, R., & Taglioni, D. 2007. Trade effects of the euro: A comparison of estimators. Journal of Economic Integration, 22 (4): 780–818.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bayoumi, T., & Eichengreen, B. 1997. Is regionalism simply a diversion? Evidence from the evolution of the EC and EFTA. In T. Ito & A. Krueger (Eds), Regionalism versus multilateral trade arrangements: 141–168. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrand, J. H. 1985. The gravity equation in international trade: Some microeconomic foundations and empirical evidence. Review of Economics and Statistics, 67 (3): 474–481.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergstrand, J. H. 1989. The generalized gravity equation, monopolistic competition, and the factor-proportions theory in international trade. Review of Economics and Statistics, 71 (1): 143–153.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bhagwati, J. 1991. The world trading system at risk. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Bikker, J. A. 1987. An international trade flow model with substitution: An extension of the gravity model. Kyklos, 40 (3): 315–337.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bond, E. W., & Syropoulos, C. 1996. The size of trading blocs, market power and world welfare effects. Journal of International Economics, 40 (3–4): 411–437.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brainard, S. L. 1997. An empirical assessment of the proximity-concentration trade-off between multinational sales and trade. American Economic Review, 87 (4): 520–544.

    Google Scholar 

  • Breusch, T., & Pagan, A. 1980. The Lagrange multiplier test and its applications to model specification in econometrics. Review of Economic Studies, 47 (1): 239–254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buckley, P. J., Clegg, J., Forsans, N., & Reilly, K. T. 2001. Increasing the size of the “country”: Regional economic integration and foreign direct investment in a globalised world economy. Management International Review, 41 (3): 251–274.

    Google Scholar 

  • Carrère, C. 2006. Revisiting the effects of regional trade agreements on trade flows with proper specification of the gravity model. European Economics Review, 50 (2): 223–247.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Christophe, S. E. 1997. Hysteresis and the value of the US multinational corporation. Journal of Business, 70 (3): 435–462.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Coeurderoy, R., & Murray, G. 2008. Regulatory environments and the location decision: Evidence from the early foreign market entries of new-technology-based firms. Journal of International Business Studies, 39 (4): 670–687.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crawford, J., & Fiorentino, R. 2005. The changing landscape of regional trade agreements, WTO Discussion Paper No. 8, World Trade Organization, Geneva.

  • Crawford, J., & Laird, S. 2001. Regional trade agreements and the WTO. North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 12 (2): 193–211.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Deardorff, A. V. 1998. Determinants of bilateral trade: Does gravity work in a Neoclassical world? In J. A. Frankel (Ed.), The regionalization of the world economy: 7–32. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • DiMaggio, P. J., & Powell, W. W. 1983. The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields. American Sociological Review, 48 (2): 147–160.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Donnenfeld, S. 2003. Regional blocs and foreign direct investment. Review of International Economics, 11 (5): 770–788.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dunning, J. H. 1981. International production and the multinational enterprise. London: George Allen & Unwin.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dunning, J. H., Fujita, M., & Yakova, N. 2007. Some macro-data on the regionalisation/globalisation debate: A comment on the Rugman/Verbeke analysis. Journal of International Business Studies, 38 (1): 177–199.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Erramilli, M. K. 1991. The experience factor in foreign market entry behavior of service firms. Journal of International Business Studies, 22 (3): 479–501.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra, R. C. 2003. Advanced international trade. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Feenstra, R. C., Markusen, R., & Rose, A. K. 2001. Using the gravity equation to differentiate among alternative theories of trade. Canadian Journal of Economics, 34 (2): 430–447.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, J. A. 1997. Regional trading blocs in the world economic system. Washington, DC: Institute of International Economics.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Frankel, J. A., Stein, E., & Wei, S.-J. 1996. Regional trading arrangements: Natural or supernatural? American Economic Review, 86 (2): 52–56.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fratianni, M., & Pattison, J. 2001. International organisations in a world of regional trade agreements: Lessons from club theory. World Economy, 24 (3): 333–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghemawat, P. J. 2007. Redefining global strategy. Boston, MA: Harvard Business School Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hausman, J. 1978. Specification tests in econometrics. Econometrica, 46 (6): 1251–1271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haveman, J., & Hummels, D. 2004. Alternative hypotheses and the volume of trade: The gravity equation and the extent of specialization. Canadian Journal of Economics, 37 (1): 199–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Helpman, E. 1987. Imperfect competition and international trade: Evidence from fourteen industrial countries. Journal of the Japanese and International Economies, 1 (1): 62–81.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hutzschenreuter, T., & Voll, J. C. 2008. Performance effects of “added cultural distance” in the path of international expansion: The case of German multinational enterprises. Journal of International Business Studies, 39 (1): 53–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kim, W. S., & Lyn, E. O. 1986. Excess market value, the multinational corporation, and Tobin's q-ratio. Journal of International Business Studies, 17 (1): 119–125.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kogut, B., & Singh, H. 1988. The effect of national culture on the choice of entry mode. Journal of International Business Studies, 19 (3): 411–432.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krishna, P. 1998. Regionalism and multilateralism: A political economy approach. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 113 (1): 227–251.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krugman, P. 1991. Is bilateralism bad? In E. Helpman & A. Razin (Eds), International trade and trade policy: 9–23. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leamer, E. E., & Levinsohn, J. 1995. International trade theory: The evidence. In G. M. Grossman & K. Rogoff (Eds), Handbook of international economics: 1339–1394. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lu, J. W., & Beamish, P. W. 2004. International diversification and firm performance: The S-curve hypothesis. Academy of Management Journal, 47 (4): 598–609.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Magee, C. S. P. 2008. New measures of trade creation and trade diversion. Journal of International Economics, 75 (2): 349–362.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Markusen, J. R., & Venables, A. J. 2000. The theory of endowment, intra-industry and multi-national trade. Journal of International Economics, 52 (2): 209–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merkies, A. H. Q. M., & van der Meer, T. 1988. Theoretical foundations for the 3-C model, 002, Free University, Amsterdam.

  • Morck, R., & Yeung, B. 1991. Why investors value multinationality. Journal of Business, 64 (2): 165–187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Neary, J. P. 2006. Trade costs and foreign direct investment, CEPR Discussion Paper No. 5933, November.

  • Neary, J. P. 2007. Cross-border mergers as instruments of comparative advantage. Review of Economic Studies, 74 (4): 1229–1257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Panagariya, A. 2000. Preferential trade liberalization: The traditional theory and new developments. Journal of Economic Literature, 38 (2): 287–331.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persson, T. 2001. Currency unions and trade: How large is the treatment effect? Economic Policy, 16 (33): 433–448.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pomfret, R. 2006. Regional trade agreements. In M. Fratianni (Ed.), Regional economic integration: 39–54. Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Qian, L., & Delios, A. 2008. Internalization and experience: Japanese banks’ international expansion, 1980–1998. Journal of International Business Studies, 39 (2): 231–248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose, A. K. 2000. One money, one market: The effect of common currencies on trade. Economic Policy, 15 (30): 7–46.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose, A. K. 2005. Which international institutions promote international trade? Review of International Economics, 13 (4): 682–698.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rose, A. K., & van Wincoop, E. 2001. National money as a barrier to international trade: The real case or currency union. American Economic Review, 91 (2): 386–390.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rugman, A. M. 1981. Inside the multinationals: The economics of internal markets. New York: Columbia University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rugman, A. M., & Oh, C. H. 2007. Multinationality and regional performance, 2001–2005. In A. M. Rugman (Ed.), Regional aspects of multinationality and performance: 31–43. Oxford: Elsevier.

    Chapter  Google Scholar 

  • Rugman, A. M., & Verbeke, A. 2004. A perspective on regional and global strategies of multinational enterprises. Journal of International Business Studies, 35 (1): 3–19.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Soloaga, I., & Winters, A. 2001. Regionalism in the nineties: What effect on trade? North American Journal of Economics and Finance, 12 (1): 1–29.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Viner, J. 1950. The customs union issue. New York: Carnegie Endowment for International Peace.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yi, S.-S. 1996. Endogenous formation of customs unions under imperfect competition: Open regionalism is good. Journal of International Economics, 41 (1–2): 153–177.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We thank, for comments and suggestions, the participants at a seminar at the Bank of Greece, at the Academy of International Business Annual Conference 2008 in Milan, Francesco Marchionne, Journal of International Business Studies Editor Arjen van Witteloostuijn, and three anonymous reviewers of the same journal.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Chang Hoon Oh.

Additional information

Accepted by Arjen van Witteloostuijn, Area Editor, 14 September 2008. This paper has been with the authors for three revisions.

Appendices

APPENDIX A

See Table A1.

Table a1 Macro-level data description

APPENDIX B

See Table B1.

Table b1 Country list

APPENDIX C

See Table C1.

Table c1 Eleven regional trade agreements in the sample

APPENDIX D

See Table D1.

Table d1 Firm-level data description

APPENDIX E

See Table E1.

Table e1 Summary statistics and correlation matrix of firm-level data

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Fratianni, M., Oh, C. Expanding RTAs, trade flows, and the multinational enterprise. J Int Bus Stud 40, 1206–1227 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1057/jibs.2009.8

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Revised:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/jibs.2009.8

Keywords

Navigation