Skip to main content
Log in

Financial Frictions and Trade Dynamics

  • Research Article
  • Published:
IMF Economic Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper demonstrates theoretically that a financial shock can have highly persistent effects on international trade. Motivation is taken from the aftermath of the dramatic trade collapse in 2008–2009, which, despite a substantial recovery, has left a persistently slower growth rate in trade. We find conditions under which a transitory financial shock significantly reduces the investment by firms in entering the export market, and that this can have long-lasting effects on the range of goods exported and hence overall trade. Important to our mechanism are endogenous capital structure decisions by firms in response to the financial shock, and firm entry investment that requires traded goods. This mechanism provides an example of how firm dynamics can serve as a potent propagation mechanism, generating very long-lasting effects of transitory macroeconomic shocks.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3
Fig. 4
Fig. 5
Fig. 6
Fig. 7
Fig. 8
Fig. 9
Fig. 10

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. While Paravisini et al. (2015) do not find evidence in firm-level data for a direct effect of financial shocks on the extensive margin of trade, this result is conditional on the use of instruments to control for indirect effects on the extensive margin coming from, as they state, changes in the level in export demand, and changes in input costs. They explicitly say that their result does not reject potential explanations where: “a deterioration in credit conditions lowers the equilibrium size and profitability of each export flow, which, in turn, may reduce the probability of entering new markets – as we find when the period of analysis is extended to 2 years (Table 8, Panel 5).” (p353) Consequently, the empirical evidence of Paravisini et al. (2015) does not bear on the mechanism we propose, since we do not specify a direct effect of credit shock on entry, but rather that the credit shock affects entry indirectly through the channels of a rise in input costs for the investment good used for entry, a reduction in expected future export sales and profits, and through capital restructuring.

  2. A well-known disadvantage of using a Cholesky decomposition on the reduced-form residuals is that results can be sensitive to the ordering of variables, calling into question the validity of the restrictions used for identification. In addition, ordering restrictions typically are not derived from a theoretical model. Robustness checks reported in section A of a Supplementary Online Appendix show that our conclusions are robust to alternative orderings.

  3. Appendix also reports results for a panel VAR exercise, in which we redefine the measure of extensive margin to track the number of products rather than the combination of products and country, so that the country dimension is available for use for cross-sectional information. The cross-sectional information does not narrow the confidence bands for the variables of interest, trade, and the extensive margin. See Fig. 15. Only when we reduce the number of estimated parameters in the VAR by reducing the number of variables to 3, are we able to find a statistically significant negative long-run effect of the shock on the extensive margin of trade. This specification also redefines the shock by interacting the Libor rate with a dummy indicating the crisis period after 2008. See Fig. 16.

  4. Given that we need a sunk cost of exporting, we did not want to also model domestic entry, as the presence of two sunk costs could introduce complex issues of option value of paying the domestic sunk in case it becomes optional under some future shock to pay the sunk export entry cost. This option value could greatly complicate the solution method, for reasons that have little bearing on the export entry decision we wish to focus on. Our specification of a constant mass of domestic firms while focusing on export entry follows that in Bergin and Lin (2012) and Ruhl (2008).

  5. We are not unique in studying firm entry when firms are symmetric; see for example Bilbiie et al. (2007, 2012) and Bergin and Corsetti (2008). In general, it is possible to determine the number of exporting firms, even if one cannot identify which of the identical firms is doing the exporting. In the absence of heterogeneity, this identification does not affect the equilibrium. Given the size of overall home country export revenue, only so many home firms can enter before the fraction allocated to each firm is small enough to just barely justify a given entry cost.

  6. Perri and Quadrini (2018) introduce international asset trade in equities in a two-country model with financial shocks and capital restructuring. However, our model differs in introducing non-traded goods, including some goods which are traded in some states and non-traded in others, which prevents us from using the standard modeling of equity trade used in Perri and Quadrini (2018). Further, introducing international financial integration in our model would not confer the benefit it does in their model, whereby it endogenously transmits financial shocks internationally, to make the tightness of the financial constraint co-move perfectly across countries. This is because collateral in our model is specified in terms of equity rather than capital, and the financial shock enters directly in the firm Euler equation.

  7. We assume that death shocks apply to both exporters and non-exporters, since we do not want the decision of whether to become an exporter to be driven by an exogenous and arbitrary distinction that exporters are at greater risk of death shocks. Our specification of death shocks and a constant mass of domestic firms follows Bergin and Lin (2012) and Ruhl (2008). In our context, it is assumed that newly born non-exporting firms inherit the debt position of the dying non-exporting firms they replace.

  8. The idea with financially constrained working capital needs is not new and can be widely seen in the literature, such as in Jermann and Quadrini (2009, 2012). The collateral constraint is not derived from an optimal credit contract. Instead, it may come from the limited enforcement that prevents lenders from collecting more than a certain fraction of the firm’s collateral asset value.

  9. The model implicitly assumes that the debt of exiting non-exporters is inherited by newly born non-exporters. But Eq. (44) implies that the additional debt of exiting exporters relative to non-exporters disappears. The online appendix describes an alternative specification where the extra debt of exporters is passed exogenously on to newly entering exporters. As shown in appendix, our results are almost the same as for the benchmark specification.

  10. See also Bergin and Lin (2012) and Lewis (2009) for discussions of this model feature. Our functional specification of entry costs more closely resembles that in Lewis (2009) in specifying the rise in entry cost as a function of the number of new entrants, motivated in terms of an imperfectly elastic supply of a factor specific to product entry such as advertising. Bergin and Lin (2012) also allow for the possibility of a congestion externality in entry but specifying the rise in entry cost as a function of total number of active firms. Their specification is in line with Berentsen and Waller (2009), which was motivated using a matching externality found in Rocheteau and Wright (2005) and common in monetary search models.

  11. Although the model of Perri and Quadrini (2018) introduces financial integration which links the Lagrange multipliers on the collateral constraint of firms in both counties, they nevertheless need to assume financial shocks that are exogenously perfectly correlated across countries in order to generate international co-movement in financial flows.

  12. In principle, when comparing model predictions to data, it is preferable to use data-consistent variable definitions of model variables, which do not adjust price indexes for availability of new products. See Ghironi and Melitz (2005). While the theoretical impulse responses reported in the main text are utility-consistent definitions from the model section, the corresponding impulse responses for data-consistent definitions are extremely similar, and our conclusions are unaffected. See Supplementary Online Appendix E for details of variable definitions and results.

  13. See Boileau (1999), Eaton and Kortum (2001), Engel and Wang (2011), and Alessandria et al. (2010).

  14. Supplementary Online Appendix D reports results for an extension of the model that includes an internationally traded bond. Results indicate that a home financial shock has very similar effects on trade volume as in the benchmark model. Some international transmission takes place, as the home financial shock lowers foreign as well as home output, and generates a home current account deficit as home agents try to borrow from the foreign country.

  15. The empirical VAR uses all fluctuations in the Libor rate to help identify financial shocks, not just the large shock of the 2008 crisis.

  16. A slightly different calibration of parameters is needed in this case in order to ensure the existence of a steady state.

References

  • Alessandria, George, and Horag Choi. 2007. Do sunk costs of exporting matter for net export dynamics? The Quarterly Journal of Economics 122 (1): 289–336.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alessandria, George, Joseph Kaboski, and Virgiliu Midrigan. 2010. The great trade collapse of 2008–09: An inventory adjustment? IMF Economic Review 58: 254–294.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arellano, Cristina, Yan Bai, and Patrick J. Kehoe. 2012. Financing frictions and fluctuations in volatility. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Research Department Staff Report 466.

  • Aslam, Aqib, Emine Boz, Eugenio Cerutti, Marcos Poplawski-Ribeiro, and Petia Topalova. 2017. The slowdown in global trade: A symptom of a weak recovery. IMF Working Paper 17/242.

  • Behrens, Kristian, Gregory Corcos, and Giordano Mion. 2013. Trade crisis? What trade crisis? The Review of Economics and Statistics 95 (2): 702–709.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Berentsen, Aleksander and Christopher Waller. 2009. Optimal stabilization policy with endogenous firm entry. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis working paper 2009-032.

  • Bergin, Paul R., and Giancarlo Corsetti. 2008. The extensive margin and monetary policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 55 (7): 1222–1237.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergin, Paul R., Ling Feng, and Ching-Yi Lin. 2018. Firm entry and financial shocks. The Economic Journal 128 (609): 510–540.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergin, Paul R., and Ching-Yi Lin. 2012. The dynamics effects of currency union on trade. Journal of International Economics 87 (2): 191–204.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernanke, Ben S., and Ilian Mihov. 1998. Measuring monetary policy. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 113 (3): 869–902.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernard, Andrew B., J. Jonathan Eaton, Bradford Jensen, and Samuel Kortum. 2003. Plants and productivity in international trade. American Economic Review 93: 1268–1290.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernard, Andrew B., Stephen Redding, and Peter K. Schott. 2010. Multi-product Firms and Product Switching. American Economic Review 100 (1): 70–97.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bilbiie, Florin O., Fabio Ghironi, and Marc J. Melitz. 2007. Monetary policy and business cycles with endogenous entry and product variety. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 22: 299–379.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bilbiie, Florin O., Fabio Ghironi, and Marc J. Melitz. 2012. Endogenous entry, product variety, and business cycles. Journal of Political Economy 120 (2): 304–345.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Boileau, Martin. 1999. Trade in capital goods and the volatility of net exports and the terms of trade. Journal of International Economics 48 (2): 347–365.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bricongne, Jean-Charles, Lionel Fontagne, Guillaume Gaulier, Daria Taglioni, and Vincent Vicard. 2012. Firms and the global crisis: French exports in the turmoil. Journal of International Economics 87 (1): 134–146.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bussière, Matthieu, Giovanni Callegari, Fabio Ghironi, Giulia Sestieri, and Norihiko Yamano. 2013. Estimating trade elasticities: Demand composition and the trade collapse of 2008–09. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 5 (3): 118–151.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cavallari, Lilia. 2013. Firms’ entry, monetary policy and the international business cycle. Journal of International Economics 91: 263–274.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chor, Davin, and Kalina Manova. 2012. Off the cliff and back? Credit conditions and international trade during the global financial crisis. Journal of International Economics 87: 117–133.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eaton, Jonathan, and Samuel Kortum. 2001. Trade in capital goods. European Economic Review 45 (7): 1195–1235.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Eichenbaum, Martin, and Charles L. Evans. 1995. Some empirical evidence on the effects of shocks to monetary policy on exchange rates. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (4): 975–1009.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Engel, Charles, and Jian Wang. 2011. International trade in durable goods: Understanding volatility, cyclicality, and elasticities. Journal of International Economics 83: 37–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ghironi, Fabio, and Marc J. Melitz. 2005. international trade and macroeconomic dynamics with heterogeneous firms. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 120: 865–915.

    Google Scholar 

  • Jermann, Urban, and Vincenzo Quadrini. 2009. Macroeconomic effects of financial shocks. NBER Working Paper 15338.

  • Jermann, Urban, and Vincenzo Quadrini. 2012. Macroeconomic effects of financial shocks. American Economic Review 102 (1): 238–271.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis, Vivien. 2009. Business cycle evidence on firm entry. Macroeconomic Dynamics 13 (5): 605–624.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Paravisini, Daniel, Veronica Rappoport, Philipp Schnabl, and Daniel Wolfenzon. 2015. Dissecting the effect of credit supply on trade: Evidence from matched credit-export data. Review of Economic Studies 82 (1): 333–359.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Perri, Fabrizio, and Vincenzo Quadrini. 2018. International recessions. American Economic Review 108 (4–5): 935–984.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rocheteau, Guilluame, and Randall Wright. 2005. Money in search equilibrium, in competitive equilibrium, and in competitive search equilibrium. Econometrica 73: 175–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rogerson, Richard, and Johanna Wallenius. 2009. Micro and macro elasticities in a life cycle model with taxes. Journal of Economic Theory 144 (6): 2277–2292.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ruhl, Kim J. 2008. The international elasticity puzzle. Mimeo, University of Texas Austin. https://static1.squarespace.com/static/562636cfe4b043d43a7492bf/t/5792348829687f7eedd56a8c/1469199496414/ElasticityMarch08.pdf. Accessed 26 July 2018.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Paul Bergin.

Electronic supplementary material

Appendix

Appendix

See Figs. 11, 12, 13, 14, 15, 16 and Table 4.

Fig. 11
figure 11

Impulse responses to national financial conditions index: trade. Note: data are at monthly frequency, based on 6-digit HS disaggregate US export and import flows, running from 2002:1 to 2016:11

Fig. 12
figure 12

Impulse responses to national financial conditions index: exports. Note: data are at monthly frequency, based on 6-digit HS disaggregate US export flows, running from 2002:1 to 2016:11

Fig. 13
figure 13

Impulse responses to national financial conditions index: imports. Note: data are at monthly frequency, based on 6-digit HS disaggregate US import flows, running from 2002:1 to 2016:11

Fig. 14
figure 14

Impulse responses to interbank rate: real effective exchange rate included in the VAR. Note: we order the real effective exchange rate after monetary policy and the interbank rate, indicating that the real effective exchange rate responds contemporaneously to the shock. Our results are robust to alternative orderings. Data are at monthly frequency, based on 6-digit HS disaggregate US export and import flows, running from 2002:1 to 2016:11

Fig. 15
figure 15

Panel VAR with 7 variables. Note: data are at monthly frequency, based on 6-digit HS disaggregate US export and import flows, running from 2002:1 to 2016:11

Fig. 16
figure 16

Panel VAR with 3 variables. Note: data are at monthly frequency, based on 6-digit HS disaggregate US export and import flows, running from 2002:1 to 2016:11

Table 4 Equilibrium conditions

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Bergin, P., Feng, L. & Lin, CY. Financial Frictions and Trade Dynamics. IMF Econ Rev 66, 480–526 (2018). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41308-018-0060-x

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1057/s41308-018-0060-x

JEL Classification

Navigation