Skip to main content
Log in

Is Time-Discounting Hyperbolic or Subadditive?

  • Published:
Journal of Risk and Uncertainty Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Subadditive time discounting means that discounting over a delay is greater when the delay is divided into subintervals than when it is left undivided. This may produce the most important result usually attributed to hyperbolic discounting: declining impatience, or the inverse relationship between the discount rate and the magnitude of the delay. Three choice experiments were conducted to test for subadditive discounting, and to determine whether it is sufficient to explain declining impatience. All three experiments showed strong evidence of subadditive discounting, but there was no evidence of declining impatience. I conclude by questioning whether hyperbolic discounting is a plausible account of time preference.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Ainslie, George. (1975). “Specious Reward: A Behavioral Theory of Impulsiveness and Impulse Control,” Psychological Bulletin 82, 463–469.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ainslie, George and Nick Haslam. (1992). “Hyperbolic Discounting.” In G. F. Loewenstein and J. Elster (eds.), Choice over Time. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ayton, Peter. (1997). “How to be Incoherent and Seductive: Bookmakers' Odds and Support Theory,” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 72, 99–115.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bateman, Ian, Alistair Munro, Bruce Rhodes, Chris Starmer, and Robert Sugden (1997). “Does Part-Whole Bias Exist? An Experimental Investigation,” The Economic Journal 107, 322–332.

    Google Scholar 

  • Becker, Gary S. and Casey B. Mulligan. (1997). “The Endogenous Determination of Time Preference,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112, 729–758.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benzion, Uri., Amnon Rapaport, and Joseph Yagil. (1989). “Discount Rates Inferred from Decisions: An Experimental Study,” Management Science 35, 270–284.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bjorkman, M. (1984). “Decision Making, Risk Taking, and Psychological Time: Review of Empirical Findings and Psychological Theory,” Scandinavian Journal of Psychology 25, 31–49.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bohm-Bawerk, Eugen. (1888/1930). The Positive Theory of Capital. New York: G. E. Stechert and Co.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chapman, Gretchen B. (1996). “Expectations and Preferences for Sequences of Health and Money,” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 67, 59–75.

    Google Scholar 

  • Chapman, Gretchen B., and Arthur S. Elstein. (1995). “Valuing the Future: Temporal Discounting of Health and Money,” Medical Decision Making 15, 373–386.

    Google Scholar 

  • Christensen-Szalanski, J. J. J. (1984). “Discount Functions and the Measurement of Patient's Values- Women's Decisions during Childbirth,” Medical Decision Making 4, 47–58.

    Google Scholar 

  • Cohen, John, E. J. Dearnaley, and C. E. M. Hansel. (1956). “The Addition of Subjective Probabilities: The Summation of Estimates of Success and Failure,” Acta Psychologica 12, 371–380.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fischhoff, Baruch, Paul Slovic, and Sarah Lichtenstein. (1978). “Fault Trees: Sensitivity of Estimated Failure Probabilities to Problem Representation,” Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance 4, 330–344.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fisher, Irving. (1930). The Theory of Interest. New York: Kelley and Millman.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fraisse, Paul. (1964). The Psychology of Time. London: Eyre and Spotiswoode.

    Google Scholar 

  • Fraisse, Paul. (1984). “Perception and Estimation of Time,” Annual Review of Psychology 35, 1–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frank, Robert H. (1988). Passions within Reason: The Strategic Role of the Emotions. New York: W. W. Norton.

    Google Scholar 

  • Frederick, Shane, and Baruch Fischhoff. (1997). “Scope Insensitivity at a Contingent Supermarket: Examining the Role of Familiarity in Scope Sensitivity,” Working Paper, Carnegie Mellon University.

  • Frederick, Shane, and Baruch Fischhoff. (1998). “Scope In sensitivity in Elicited Valuations,” Risk, Decision and Policy 3, 109–123.

    Google Scholar 

  • Green, Leonard, Astrid Fry, and Joel Myerson. (1994). “Discounting of Delayed Rewards: A Life-Span Comparison,” Psychological Science 5, 33–36.

    Google Scholar 

  • Green, Leonard, Joel Myerson, and E. McFadden. (1997). “Rate of Temporal Discounting Decreases with Amount of Reward,” Memory and Cognition 25, 715–723.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hammond, Paul J. (1976). “Changing Tastes and Coherent Dynamic Choice,” Review of Economic Studies 43, 159–173.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harvey, Charles M. (1994). “The Reasonableness of Non-Constant Discounting,” Journal of Public Economics 53, 31–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hoch, Stephen, and George Loewenstein. (1991). “Time-Inconsistent Preferences and Consumer Self-Control,” Journal of Consumer Research 17, 492–507.

    Google Scholar 

  • Holcomb, J. H., and P. S. Nelson. (1992). “Another Experimental Look at Individual Time Preference,” Rationality and Society 4, 199–220.

    Google Scholar 

  • Humphrey, Steven J. (1995). “Regret Aversion or Event-Splitting Effects? More Evidence under Risk and Uncertainty,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 11, 263–274.

    Google Scholar 

  • Humphrey, Steven J. (1996). “Do Anchoring Effects Underlie Event-Splitting Effects? An Experimental Test,” Economics Letters 51, 303–308.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, Daniel, and Jack Knetsch. (1992). “Valuing Public Goods: The Purchase of Moral Satisfaction,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 22, 57–70.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirby, Kris N. (1997). “Bidding on the Future: Evidence Against Normative Discounting of Delayed Rewards,” Journal of Experimental Psychology: General 126, 54–70.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirby, Kris N., and Richard J. Herrnstein. (1995). “Preference Reversals Due to Myopic Discounting of Delayed Reward,” Psychological Science 6, 83–89.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kirby, Kris. N., and Nina Marakovic. (1995). “Modeling Myopic Decisions: Evidence for Hyperbolic Delay-Discounting within Subjects and Amounts,” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 64, 22–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Koopmans, Tjalling, Peter A. Diamond, and Richard E. Williamson. (1964). “Stationary Utility and Time Perspective,” Econometrica 32, 82–100.

    Google Scholar 

  • Laibson, David. (1997). “Golden Eggs and Hyperbolic Discounting,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 112, 443–477.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, George. (1988). “Frames of Mind in Intertemporal Choice,” Management Science 34, 200–214.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, George. (1992). “The Fall and Rise of Psychological Explanations in the Economics of Intertemporal Choice.” In G. F. Loewenstein and J. Elster (eds.), Choice over Time. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, George. (1996). “Out of Control: Visceral Influences on Behavior,” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 65, 272–293.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, George, and Drazen Prelec. (1992). “Anomalies in Intertemporal Choice: Evidence and an Interpretation,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 107, 573–597.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, George, and Drazen Prelec. (1993). “Preferences for Sequences of Outcomes,” Psychological Review 100, 91–108.

    Google Scholar 

  • Loewenstein, George, and Richard Thaler. (1989). “Anomalies: Intertemporal Choice,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 3, 181–193.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mazur, James. E (1984). “Tests of an Equivalence Rule for Fixed and Variable Reinforcer Delays,” Journal of Experimental Psychology: Animal Behavior Processes 10, 426–436.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mazur, James E., and Richard J. Herrnstein. (1988). “On the Functions Relating Delay, Reinforcer Value, and Behavior,” Behavioral and Brain Sciences 11, 690–691.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mulford, Matthew, and Robyn M. Dawes. (1999). “Subadditivity in Memory for Personal Events,” Psychological Science 10, 47–51.

    Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, Joel, and Leonard Green. (1995). “Discounting of Delayed Rewards: Models of Individual Choice,” Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior 64, 263–276.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nesselroade, John R., Stephen M. Stigler, and Paul B. Baltes. (1980). “Regression Toward the Mean and the Study of Change,” Psychological Bulletin 88, 622–637.

    Google Scholar 

  • Nozick, Robert. (1993). The Nature of Rationality. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • O'Donoghue, Ted, and Matthew Rabin. (2000). “The Economics of Immediate Gratification,” Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 13, 233–250.

    Google Scholar 

  • Peterson, Dane K., and Gordon F. Pitz. (1988). “Confidence, Uncertainty and the Use of Information,” Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory and Cognition 14, 85–92.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poulton, E. C. (1989). Bias in Quantifying Judgments. Hove and London: Lawrence Erlbaum Associates.

    Google Scholar 

  • Prelec, Drazen, and George Loewenstein. (1991). “Decision Making over Time and under Uncertainty: A Common Approach,” Management Science 37, 770–776.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rachlin, Howard, and Leonard Green. (1972). “Commitment, Choice and Self-Control,” Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior 17, 15–22.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rachlin, Howard, and Andres Raineri. (1992). “Irrationality, Impulsiveness, and Selfishness as Discount Reversal Effects.” In G. F. Loewenstein and J. Elster (eds.), Choice over Time. New York: Russell Sage Foundation.

    Google Scholar 

  • Raineri, Andres, and Howard Rachlin. (1993). “The Effect of Temporal Constraints on the Value of Money and Other Commodities,” Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 6, 77–94.

    Google Scholar 

  • Read, Daniel, George Loewenstein, and Shobana Kalyanaraman. (1999). “Mixing Virtue and Vice: Combining the Immediacy Effect and the Diversification Heuristic,” Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 12, 257–273.

    Google Scholar 

  • Read, Daniel and Barbara van Leeuwen. (1998). “Predicting Hunger: The Effects of Appetite and Delay on Choice,” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes 76, 189–205.

    Google Scholar 

  • Richards, Jerry B., Lan Zhang, Suzanne H. Mitchell, and Harriet de Wit. (1999). “Delay or Probability Discounting in a Model of Impulsive Behavior: Effect of Alcohol,” Journal of the Experimental Analysis of Behavior 71, 121–143.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roelofsma, Peter H. M. P. and Daniel Read. (2000). “Subadditive Intertemporal Choice,” Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 13, 161–177.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rottenstreich, Yuval, and Amos Tversky. (1997). “Unpacking, Repacking and Anchoring: Advances in Support Theory,” Psychological Review 104, 406–415.

    Google Scholar 

  • Samuelson, Paul. (1937). “A Note on the Measurement of Utility,” Review of Economic Studies 4, 155–161.

    Google Scholar 

  • Starmer, Chris V., and Robert Sugden. (1993). “Testing for Juxtaposition and Event-Splitting Effects,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 6, 235–254.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stevens, S. S., and Hilda B. Greenbaum. (1966). “Regression Effects in Psychophysical Judgment,” Perception and Psychophysics 1, 439–446.

    Google Scholar 

  • Strotz, R. H. (1955). “Myopia and Inconsistency in Dynamic Utility Maximization,” Review of Economic Studies 23, 165–180.

    Google Scholar 

  • Thaler, Richard H. (1981). “Some Empirical Evidence on Dynamic Inconsistency,” Economic Letters 8, 201–207.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tversky, Amos, and Derek J. Koehler. (1994). “Support Theory: A Nonextensional Representation of Subjective Probability,” Psychological Review 101, 547–567.

    Google Scholar 

  • Varey, Carol A., Barbara A. Mellers, and Michael H. Birnbaum. (1990). “Judgments of Proportions,” Journal of Experimental Psychology: Human Perception and Performance 16, 613–625.

    Google Scholar 

  • Weber, Martin, Franz Eisenfuhr, and Detlof von Winterfeldt. (1988). “The Effects of Splitting ¨ Attributes on Weights in Multiattribute Utility Measurement,” Management Science 34, 431–445.

    Google Scholar 

  • Woodworth, Robert S., and Harold Schlosberg. (1954). Experimental Psychology, Revised Edition. London: Methuen.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wright, George, and Peter Whalley. (1983). “The Supra-Additivity of Subjective Probability.” In B. P. Stigum, and F. Wenstø p (eds.), Foundations of Utility and Risk Theory with Applications. Dordrecht: D. Reidel Publishing Company.

    Google Scholar 

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Read, D. Is Time-Discounting Hyperbolic or Subadditive?. Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 23, 5–32 (2001). https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1011198414683

Download citation

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1023/A:1011198414683

Navigation