Hostname: page-component-76fb5796d-45l2p Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-04-26T07:21:20.074Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

THE HOMELESS OBSERVER: JOHN HARSANYI ON INTERPERSONAL UTILITY COMPARISONS AND BARGAINING, 1950–1964

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  11 May 2010

Abstract

This paper traces interpersonal utility comparisons and bargaining in the work of John Harsanyi from the 1950s to the mid-1960s. As his preoccupation with how theorists can obtain information about agents moved from an approach centered on empathetic understanding to the more distanced perspective associated with game theory, Harsanyi shifted emphasis from the social scientist’s lack of information vis-à-vis agents to agents’ lack of information about each other. In the process, he provided economists with an analytical framework they could use to study problems related to the distribution of information among agents while consolidating the perspective of a distant observer whose knowledge can replace that of real people.

Type
Research Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Arrow, Kenneth J. 1951a. Social Choice and Individual Values, 2nd edition. New Haven and London: Yale University Press, 1963.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1951b. “Alternative Approaches to the Theory of Choice in Risk-Taking Situations.” Econometrica 19 (4): 401–437.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 2001a. “In Memoriam: John C. Harsanyi.” Games and Economic Behavior 36 (1): 5–6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 2001b. “John C. Harsanyi, 1920–2000.” Economic Journal 111 (475): F747–F752.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bacharach, Michael. 1989. “The Role of ‘Verstehen’ in Economic Theory.” Ricerche economiche 43 (1–2): 129–150.Google Scholar
Black, Duncan. 1948. “On the Rationale of Group Decision-making.” Journal of Political Economy 56 (1): 23–34CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Black, Duncan. 1950. “The Unity of Political and Economic Science.” Economic Journal 60 (239): 506–514.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Borstelmann, Lloyd J. 1952. Review of An Introduction to Projective Techniques and Other Devices for Understanding the Dynamics of Human Behavior by H. H. Anderson and Gladys L. Anderson. Social Forces 31 (1): 87–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boulding, Kenneth E. 1949. “Is Economics Necessary?Scientific Monthly 68 (4): 235–40.Google Scholar
Cole, Tim and Smith, Graham. 1995. “Ghettoization and the Holocaust: Budapest 1944.” Journal of Historical Geography 22 (1): 300–316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Findlay, J. N. 1954. “The Justification of Attitudes.” Mind 63 (250): 145–161.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Finetti, Bruno de. 1937. “La prévision: ses lois logiques, ses sources subjectives.” Annales de l’I.H.P. 7 (1): 1–68.Google Scholar
Fontaine, Philippe. 1997. “Identification and Economic Behavior: Sympathy and Empathy in Historical Perspective.” Economics and Philosophy 13 (2): 261–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fontaine, Philippe. 2001. “The Changing Place of Empathy in Welfare Economics.” History of Political Economy 33 (3): 387–409.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fontaine, Philippe. 2007. “Harsanyi Before Economics: An Introduction.” Economics and Philosophy 23 (3): 343–348.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Milton and Savage, L. Jimmie 1948. “The Utility Analysis of Choices Involving Risk.” Journal of Political Economy 56 (4): 279–304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Milton and Savage, L. Jimmie 1952. “The Expected-Utility Hypothesis and the Measurability of Utility.” Journal of Political Economy 60 (6): 463–474.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giocoli, Nicola. 2004. “Savage vs. Wald: Was Bayesian Decision Theory the Only Available Alternative for Postwar Economics?” Working paper. Available at SSRN.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giocoli, Nicola. 2006. “Do Prudent Agents Play Lotteries? Von Neumann’s Contribution to the Theory of Rational Behavior.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 28 (1): 95–109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Giocoli, Nicola. 2009. “Three Alternative (?) Stories on the Late 20th-Century Rise of Game Theory.” Studi e Note di Economia 14 (2): 187–210.Google Scholar
Gul, Faruk. 1997. “A Nobel Prize for Game Theorists: The Contributions of Harsanyi, Nash and Selten.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 11 (3): 159–174.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gunther, John. 1947. Inside U.S.A. New York and London: Harper & Brothers.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1947. “A Filozófiai Tévedések Logikai Alkata.” Athenaeum 38: 33–39.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1953a. Inventions and Economic Growth, MA thesis, University of Sydney, January.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1953b. “Cardinal Utility in Welfare Economics and in the Theory of Risk-Taking.” Journal of Political Economy 61 (5): 434–435.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1953–54. “Welfare Economics of Variable Tastes.” Review of Economic Studies 21 (3): 203–213.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1954. “The Research Policy of the Firm.” Economic Record 30 (58): 48–60.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1955. “Cardinal Welfare, Individualistic Ethics, and Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility.” Journal of Political Economy 63 (4): 309–21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1956a. “Economic Science: Achievements and Prospects.” The University of Queensland Gazette (May): 12–13.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1956b. “Approaches to the Bargaining Problem Before and After the Theory of Games: A Critical Discussion of Zeuthen’s, Hicks’, and Nash’s Theories.” Econometrica 24 (2): 144–157.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1957. “Bargaining in Ignorance of the Opponent’s Utility Function.” Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper No. 46, 11 December: 1–16.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1958. “Ethics in Terms of Hypothetical Imperatives.” Mind, NS 67 (267): 305–316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1959. “A Bargaining Model for the Cooperative n-Person Game.” In Tucker, A. W. and Luce, R. D., eds., Contributions to the Theory of Games, vol. 4. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, pp. 325–55.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1960a. “Explanation and Comparative Dynamics in Social Science.” Behavioral Science 5 (2): 136–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1960b. “Popper’s Improbability Criterion for the Choice of Scientific Hypotheses.” Philosophy 35 (135): 1–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1961a. “On the Rationality Postulates Underlying the Theory of Cooperative Games.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 5 (2): 179–96.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1961b. “Theoretical Analysis in Social Science and the Model of Rational Behaviour.” Australian Journal of Politics and History 7 (1): 60–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1962a. “Measurement of Social Power, Opportunity Costs, and the Theory of Two-Person Bargaining Games.” Behavioral Science 7 (1): 67–80.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Harsanyi, John C. 1962b. “Measurement of Social Power in n-Person Reciprocal Power Situations.” Behavioral Science 7 (1): 81–91.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Harsanyi, John C. 1962c. “Models for the Analysis of the Balance of Power in Society.” In Nagel, E., Suppes, P., and Tarski, A., eds., Logic, Methodology and Philosophy of Science: Proceedings of the 1960 International Congress. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press, pp. 442–62.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1962d. “Bargaining in Ignorance of the Opponent’s Utility Function.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 6 (1): 29–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1962e. “Rationality Postulates for Bargaining Solutions in Cooperative and in Non-cooperative Games.” Management Science 9 (1): 141–153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1962f. “Mathematical Models for the Genesis of War" (A review article on Lewis F. Richardson’s work). World Politics 14 (4): 687–699.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1977a. “Morality and the Theory of Rational Behavior.” Social Research 44 (4): 623–56.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1977b. Rational Behavior and Bargaining Equilibrium in Games and Social Situations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1997. “Utilities, Preferences, and Substantive Goods.” Social Choice and Welfare 14 (1): 129–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Innocenti, Alessandro. 2008. “Linking Strategic Interaction and Bargaining Theory: The Harsanyi-Schelling Debate on the Axiom of Symmetry.” History of Political Economy 40 (1): 111–132.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klopfer, Walter G. 1973. “The Short History of Projective Techniques.” Journal of the History of the Behavioral Sciences 9 (1): 60–65.3.0.CO;2-H>CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Leonard, Robert J. 1992. “Creating a Context for Game Theory.” In Weintraub, E. Roy, ed., Toward a History of Game Theory, HOPE 24 (supplement), pp. 29–76.Google Scholar
Leonard, Robert J. 1994. “Reading Cournot, Reading Nash: The Creation and Stabilisation of the Nash Equilibrium.” Economic Journal 104 (424): 492–511.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leonard, Robert J. 2008. “New Light on von Neumann: Politics, Psychology and the Creation of Game Theory.” Working Paper, UQAM.Google Scholar
Markowitz, H. 1952. “The Utility of Wealth.” Journal of Political Economy 60 (2): 151–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marschak, Jacob. 1954. “Probability in the Social Sciences.” In Lazarsfeld, P. F., ed., Mathematical Thinking in the Social Sciences. Glencoe, IL: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Marx, George. 1994. The Voice of the Martians, 2nd edition. Budapest: Akadémiai Kiadó, 1997.Google Scholar
McGuire, C. Bart. 2001. “Achievement Against Odds.” Games and Economic Behavior 36 (1): 15–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Merton, Robert K. 1949. Social Theory and Social Structure. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Mirowski, Philip. 1991. “When Games Grow Deadly Serious: The Influence on the Evolution of Game Theory.” In Goodwin, Craufurd D., ed., Economics and National Security: A History of Their Interaction, HOPE 23 (supplement), pp. 227–55.Google Scholar
Mirowski, Philip. 2002. Machine Dreams: Economics Becomes a Cyborg Science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mirowski, Philip and Hands, D. Wade 1998. “A Paradox of Budgets: The Postwar Stabilization of American Neoclassical Demand Theory.” In Morgan, Mary S. and Rutherford, Malcolm, eds., From Interwar Pluralism to Postwar Neoclassicism, HOPE 30 (supplement), pp. 260–92.Google Scholar
Mongin, Philippe. 2001. “The Impartial Observer Theorem of Social Ethics.” Economics and Philosophy 17 (2): 147–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myerson, Roger B. 1999. “Nash Equilibrium and the History of Economic Theory.” Journal of Economic Literature 37 (3): 1067–1082.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myerson, Roger B. 2001. “Learning Game Theory from John Harsanyi.” Games and Economic Behavior 36 (1): 20–25.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myerson, Roger B. 2004. “Harsanyi’s Games with Incomplete Information.” Management Science 50 (12): 1818–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nash, John F. 1950. “The Bargaining Problem.” Econometrica 18 (2): 155–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
von Neumann, John and Morgenstern, Oskar. 1944. The Theory of Games and Economic Behavior, 2nd edition. Princeton: Princeton University Press, 1947.Google Scholar
Platt, Jennifer. 1985. “Weber’s Verstehen and the History of Qualitative Research: The Missing Link.” British Journal of Sociology 36 (3): 448–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Polsby, Nelson W. 2001. “A Friend and Colleague.” Games and Economic Behavior 36 (1): 26–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pradier, Pierre-Charles and Jallais, Sophie. 2005. “The Allais Paradox and Its Immediate Consequences for Expected Utility Theory.” In Fontaine, P. and Leonard, R., eds., The Experiment in the History of Economics. London: Routledge, pp. 25–49.Google Scholar
Raiffa, Howard. 1992. “Game Theory at the University of Michigan, 1948–1952.” In Weintraub, E. Roy, ed., Toward a History of Game Theory, HOPE 24 (supplement), pp. 165–75.Google Scholar
Rogers, Everett M. and Beal, George M. 1959. “Projective Techniques: Potential Tools for Agricultural Economists?Journal of Farm Economics 41 (3): 644–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rose, Alvin W. 1949. “Projective Techniques in Sociological Research.” Social Forces 28 (2): 175–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ross, Marion (interviews conducted by). 2000. Nobel Laureate John Harsanyi: From Budapest to Berkeley. 1920–2000. With an Introduction by Arrow, Kenneth J.Berkeley, CA: The Regents of the University of California.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1948. Economics. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 2001. “A Personal Tribute to John Harsanyi.” Games and Economic Behavior" 36 (1): 28–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Savage, L. Jimmie. 1951. “Notes on the Foundations of Statistics.” Mimeographed, University of Chicago Lectures.Google Scholar
Savage, L. Jimmie. 1954. The Foundations of Statistics. New York: Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Schoeffler, Sydney. 1952. “Note on Modern Welfare Economics.” American Economic Review 62 (5): 880–887.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph A. 1942. Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, 3rd edition. New York: Harper and Row, 1950.Google Scholar
Scitovsky, Tibor. 1976. The Joyless Economy: The Psychology of Human Satisfaction. New York and Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1992.Google Scholar
Sent, Esther Mirjam. 1998. “Sargent and the Unbearable Lightness of Symmetry.” Journal of Economic Methodology 5 (1): 93–114.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sent, Esther Mirjam. 2004. “The Legacy of Herbert Simon in Game Theory.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 53 (3): 303–317.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sent, Esther Mirjam. 2005. “Simplifying Herbert Simon.” History of Political Economy 37 (2): 227–232.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shubik, Martin. 1992. “Game Theory at Princeton, 1949–1955: A Personal Reminiscence.” In Weintraub, E. Roy, ed., Toward a History of Game Theory, HOPE 24 (supplement), pp. 151–63.Google Scholar
Simon, Herbert A. 1955. “A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 69 (1): 99–118.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vickrey, William. 1945. “Measuring Marginal Utility by Reactions to Risk.” Econometrica 13 (4): 319–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wagnleitner, Reinhold. 1994. Coca-Colonization and the Cold War: The Cultural Mission of the United States in Austria after the Second World War, translated by Wolf, Diana M.. Chapel Hill and London: The University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Weymark, John A. 1995. “Jon Harsanyi’s Contributions to Social Choice and Welfare Economics.” Social Choice and Welfare 12 (4): 313–8.CrossRefGoogle Scholar