Elsevier

Research Policy

Volume 39, Issue 6, July 2010, Pages 776-789
Research Policy

Learning dynamics in research alliances: A panel data analysis

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.respol.2010.03.002Get rights and content

Abstract

The aim of this paper is to empirically test the determinants of Research Joint Ventures’ (RJVs) group dynamics. We develop a model based on learning and transaction cost theories, which represent the benefits and costs of RJV participation, respectively. According to our framework, firms at each period in time weigh the benefits against the costs of being an RJV member. RJV dynamics can then be interpreted as a consequence of this evolving trade-off over time. We look at entry, turbulence and exit in RJVs that have been set up under the US National Cooperative Research Act, which allows for certain antitrust exemptions in order to stimulate firms to co-operate in R&D. Accounting for unobserved project characteristics and controlling for inter-RJV interactions and industry effects, the Tobit panel regressions show the importance of group and time features for an RJVs evolution. We further identify an average RJVs long-term equilibrium size and assess its determining factors. Ours is a first attempt to produce robust stylized facts about co-operational short- and long-term dynamics, a neglected dimension in research co-operations, but an important element in understanding how collaborative learning works.

Introduction

Though being competitors in the product market, firms often co-operate in research and development (R&D). The US National Cooperative Research Act of 1984 (NCRA) was created precisely for this purpose. The NCRA stimulates firms to co-operate in R&D in non-equity ventures on a large scale, thereby aiming to provide a solution to perceived competitive threats to US high-tech industries (Link et al., 2005). As a natural consequence of the goal of promoting such broad and loose co-operations, one characteristic of the NCRA collaborations stands out: firms frequently enter and exit the NCRA research consortia after their initial formation.3 The aim of this study is to explore the drivers of these in-and-out movements, as a first step in deepening our understanding of the dynamics of research collaborations.

There is growing recognition that instabilities are a central feature of not only the NCRA research consortia, but of inter-firm co-operations in general. Indeed, several empirical studies have provided evidence that collaborative agreements are inherently unstable organizational forms (Barkema et al., 1997, Beamish, 1985, Dussauge et al., 2000, Franko, 1971, Gomes-Casseres, 1987, Killing, 1983, Kogut, 1989, Li, 1995, Park and Russo, 1996, Pennings et al., 1994). These movements, as Ariño and de la Torre (1998) and Doz and Hamel (1998) state, can be an important indicator of the learning processes inside alliances and of the net benefits that firms obtain from participating. According to this line of reasoning, firms enter research collaborations with the expectation of learning, but adapt over time and alter their commitments, which may ultimately lead to exit (Balakrishnan and Koza, 1993, Kogut, 1991, Hamel, 1991, Khanna et al., 1998, Koza and Lewin, 1998, Reuer and Zollo, 2005). Therefore, given the importance of collaborative learning for the NCRA program – and, of course, for research alliances in general – it seems key to identify the drivers of these dynamics, with the idea of giving initial insights on how firms co-operate and learn in research alliances.

Following Reuer and Zollo (2005), we draw upon two different streams of the institutional economics literature for our framework. On the one hand, based on evolutionary economics we argue that learning represents the benefits of alliance membership.4 On the other hand, through transaction cost theory and industrial economics reasoning, we identify the costs of its participation. Alliance dynamics can then be interpreted as an evolving interplay of these benefits and costs.

First, according to evolutionary economics, organisms evolve through the formation and marginal adjustment of behavioral patterns (Nelson and Winter, 1982). Adapted to organizations, evolutionary economics highlights the role of the tacit accumulation of knowledge through learning (Teece et al., 1997). Research co-operation is then considered a mechanism to facilitate the transfer of certain types of knowledge and to enhance a firm's learning processes (Teece, 1986, Hagedoorn, 1995). Therefore, this reasoning focuses on the benefits of alliance participation.

Second, however, co-operative learning in an alliance is complex. The transaction cost view of Williamson (1992) applied to R&D collaborations highlights the particular characteristics of these ventures that give rise to various exchange hazards, such as free-riding or coordination costs among partners (Oxley, 1997, Veugelers, 1998). Thus, transaction cost theory focuses on the costs of the involvement in alliances.5

We combine these two dimensions – evolutionary economics and transaction cost theory – to analyze drivers of alliance dynamics. We focus on factors that influence the post-formation entry and exit-movements of firms into and out of an NCRA research alliance. The underlying rationale of our framework is that firms at each period of time weigh the (expected) benefits of learning against the (expected) costs of free-riding and coordination in these research collaborations. In particular, we use the following reasoning. If a firm considers the benefits to be higher than the costs, then it enters an alliance.6 Thereafter, given that firms alter their commitments, change investments and learn from other firms, they re-evaluate the costs and benefits of being in the research collaboration. Thus, if at one point in time the costs of participation are higher than the benefits, the firm exits. Our reasoning is thus reminiscent to Osborn and Hagedoorn's (1997, p273) proposal to study “evolutionary dynamics [of alliances] as a trade-off between transaction cost economies and technological development”.

The NCRA research consortia, being non-equity alliances, are a more effective environment for learning than equity forms such as research joint ventures (RJVs), which are more likely to stress control issues (Hagedoorn and Narula, 1996). The negative side of consortia, vis-à-vis equity ventures, however, is facing a higher uncertainty and having more diffuse goals for undertaking research (Aldrich and Sasaki, 1995). R&D consortia, therefore, have both potentially higher and more volatile costs/benefits than other types of R&D collaborations, which makes them particularly interesting to investigate alliance dynamics. As an aside, it must be noted that, though R&D consortia are different from RJVs because their members pool research resources into loose and relatively long-term projects, R&D consortia are normally labeled RJVs. From now on, we will stick to this terminology.

We focus on the two drivers of dynamics that we believe to be most relevant in our setup. First, evolutionary economics highlights the role of knowledge accumulation and development of routines over time. Therefore, we focus on how the age of the RJV influences its forces. Second, transaction cost analysis focuses on the organizational characteristics that give rise to various exchange hazards. In particular, several scholars have identified these costs as increasing with the number of agents that interact, due to suffering larger coordination costs or to opportunistic behavior becoming more severe (e.g. Holmström, 1982, Milgrom and Roberts, 1992). On the other hand, being a member in a larger RJV gives access to a larger pool of knowledge (Bloch, 1995, Veugelers, 1998), which may increase the benefits of learning. Therefore, we focus on how an alliance's group size, i.e. the number of participants (“insiders”), affects this trade-off and consequently influences its dynamics. We further investigate whether industry characteristics and interactions between different RJVs have an impact on an alliance's evolution.

We identify RJV movements on two levels. First, we analyze how group and time characteristics determine its short-run dynamics; i.e. we investigate how the number of insiders and the age of an RJV influence its entry and exit patterns. We find that the group-variables are robust drivers in a non-linear way. Especially the found U-shaped impact of the number of insiders on entry into an RJV may be of interest. This result indicates that the perception of transaction cost problems at first goes up with the number of insiders, i.e. entry initially decreases with size. This is indirect evidence for the classic theory of teams where moral hazard increases with the number of agents (Holmström, 1982), yet in a dynamic rather than a static context. However, those RJVs that are very large, experience more entry when they further increase in size. This hints at some RJVs having overcome the typical problems of large groups through an optimal design of their organizational variables. Firms perceive, therefore, entrance into these larger RJVs to be beneficial, given the larger pool of knowledge available. Further, the age of an RJV has a negative effect on both entry and exit, suggesting that RJVs become more stable over their lifespan, which may be due to divergent learning (Nakamura et al., 1996) – and hence firms become more complementary over time – or due to RJVs becoming more effective over time in dealing with transaction cost problems, because of the development of trust and more efficient routines (Chiles and McMackin, 1996, Parkhe, 1993).

Second, once short-run dynamics are analyzed, one can go a step further and investigate whether a long-term equilibrium size exists – i.e. if entry and exit evolve around a long-term stable group size. We find that this is indeed the case, which confirms – again in a dynamic rather than static context – RJV-group formation models such as Bloch (1995) that predict an optimal RJV size due to the trade-off between costs and benefits of participation. Moreover, some of the industry characteristics in which the RJV is embedded are found to have a determinant impact on this group size. In particular, factors which both increase the benefits of learning and the possibility of controlling other RJV members – as, for example, the concentration of an industry – lead to larger RJVs in the long-run.7

Our study is novel in several aspects. First, although recent theoretical studies have indicated the importance of organizational changes in existing partnerships, very little empirical research has been conducted on these ideas.8 This small empirical literature takes into account how alliance termination is influenced by either host country characteristics (Contractor, 1990, Franko, 1989, Barkema et al., 1997), degrees of partner rivalry (Kogut, 1989, Kogut, 1991, Park and Russo, 1996) or partners’ previous experiences (Barkema et al., 1997, Reuer and Zollo, 2005).9 But, although relatively varied, these studies exclusively focus on the ending of collaboration.10 Our study adds to the empirical literature on collaborative dynamics by studying the development of still operating research ventures. This approach offers two main advantages. First, it allows a far more complete picture of an alliance's evolution over time and hence of its learning processes. Second and related, from a statistical point of view our analysis adds true time-variation to the econometric analysis by using panel data methodologies (Wooldridge, 2002). Given the focus of previous work on termination, dissolution has only been analyzed in either cross-sectional studies (e.g. Reuer et al., 2002, Reuer and Zollo, 2005) or hazard rate models (e.g. Barkema et al., 1997, Park and Russo, 1996).

Further, the size and heterogeneity of the NCRA-RJVs allow us to add a novel element to empirical studies that link transaction costs theory to alliance instabilities.11 Existing empirical works focus mainly on cultural differences (e.g. Contractor, 1990), firms’ previous alliance experience (e.g. Reuer and Zollo, 2005) or firms being direct competitors in the product market (e.g. Kogut, 1989) as a source of potential problems. However, seminal papers on transaction costs, such as Holmström (1982) and Milgrom and Roberts (1992), have shown that a key factor in explaining organizational difficulties is the number of cooperating actors. Indeed, problems of coordination and opportunistic behavior typically become more problematic with more interacting agents, as e.g. Holmström and Tirole (1989) and Oxley (1997) argue. At the same time, learning benefits may be higher when the “pool of knowledge” is larger, which makes bigger alliances more attractive (Veugelers, 1998). To our knowledge, this study is the first attempt to link alliance dynamics to the size of RJVs, which should help in understanding how the number of participants impacts the learning versus transaction cost trade-off.

Finally, our focus on group dynamics allows us to determine the long-term stable RJV size, and its dependence on the elements of the industry in which it operates. This serves as a reality check for theory models on RJV formation, such as Bloch (1995) and Cassiman and Greenlee (1999). More importantly, it gives us further insights in exactly how the costs and the benefits of collaborating balance each other out at a certain alliance size. Our approach allows us to identify an “ideal” long-term alliance size in function of these costs/benefits via the characteristics of the industry in which the co-operation is established.

The structure of the paper is as follows. The second section, building on our general architecture, explains our hypotheses. The third section presents the data, while the fourth explains the estimation strategy and the chosen variables. The fifth section shows the econometric results and some robustness checks. The sixth section offers a discussion of the results and possible implications for firms and policy-makers. The seventh section concludes.

Section snippets

Theory and hypotheses

Our outline explicitly incorporates costs and benefits for participating firms, and identifies factors that may influence the incidence of each type. This section provides first a general discussion and then focuses on specific hypotheses.

The data

Our data comes from merging two data sources: the NCRA-RJV database with information on RJVs and its participants under the NCRA (1985–1999), and the Compustat North America database containing firm-specific information on about 22,000 public US firms (1986–1999).19 Although the NCRA-RJV data are explained in detail in Link (1996) and Vonortas (1997), we give here a short overview of the main

Estimation and choice of variables

Two main methodological features differentiate our study from previous ones, as discussed in the introduction. Most notably, we look at dynamics in terms of variation over time by using a panel data approach. Further, we choose the RJV as the unit of observation rather than the single firm.

This approach, we believe, has several advantages. First, it allows us to better capture dynamics, i.e. how the alliance as a group evolves and transforms over time. If we took the single firm as a unit of

Results

We first discuss how the RJV characteristics determine short-run dynamics and then report the impact of the other explanatory variables. Next, we investigate whether a long-term equilibrium exists and which industry factors influence this equilibrium.

Discussion and implications

In this section we shortly discuss the implications of our findings and provide some prescriptions for firms and public policy on R&D. From our short-run dynamics analysis we learn that small and very large RJVs attract relatively more new entrants. One may thus tentatively deduce that both small RJVs and very large RJVs are ex ante perceived by potential entrants as successful learning environments. Small RJVs subsequently lead to less exit, due to divergent learning and/or lower transaction

Conclusions

This paper aims to test the determinants of the NCRA-RJVs’ group dynamics after their initial setup. The underlying rationale of our analysis is that firms, at each period of time, weigh the benefits of learning against the costs of free-riding and coordination in these research collaborations. Alliance dynamics can then be interpreted as an evolving interplay of these benefits and costs. Given the importance of collaborative learning, our study, therefore, addresses two significant but

Acknowledgements

We would like to thank Jordi Jaumandreu, Tobias Kretschmer, Vicente Salas and two anonymous referees for helpful discussions and comments; participants of seminars at the WZB, University of Linz, LMU Munich, and at the ASSET Conference (Lisbon), DRUID Conference (Copenhagen), SFB Conference (Mannheim), DEMO Workshop (Barcelona), Summer Workshop on Innovation (Santander) and EARIE Conference (Valencia) for their helpful comments. Kemal Azun, Jennifer Rontganger, Constanze Quade, Falko Tabbert,

References (89)

  • C. Snyder et al.

    Multiproject contact in research joint ventures: evidence and theory

    Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization

    (2005)
  • D. Teece

    Profiting from technological innovation: implications for integration, collaboration, licensing and public policy

    Research Policy

    (1986)
  • D. Teece

    Competition, cooperation and innovation

    Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization

    (1992)
  • N.S. Vonortas

    Research joint ventures in the U.S.

    Research Policy

    (1997)
  • O. Williamson

    Markets, hierarchies, and the modern corporation: an unfolding perspective

    Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization

    (1992)
  • H. Aldrich et al.

    R&D Consortia in the United States and Japan

    Research Policy

    (1995)
  • A. Ariño et al.

    Learning from failure: towards an evolutionary model of collaborative ventures

    Organization Science

    (1998)
  • U. Backes-Gellner et al.

    On the explanation of horizontal, vertical and cross-sector R&D partnerships—evidence for the German Industrial Sector

    International Journal of Entrepreneurship and Innovation Management

    (2005)
  • H.G. Barkema et al.

    Working abroad, working with others: how firms learn to operate international joint ventures

    Academy of Management Journal

    (1997)
  • G. Barlevy

    On the cyclicality of research and development

    American Economic Review

    (2007)
  • P.W. Beamish

    The characteristics of joint ventures in developed and developing countries

    Columbia Journal of World Business

    (1985)
  • F. Bloch

    Endogenous structures of association in oligopolies

    The RAND Journal of Economics

    (1995)
  • Y. Caloghirou et al.

    Research joint ventures

    Journal of Economic Surveys

    (2003)
  • B. Cassiman et al.

    Product market objectives and the formation of research joint ventures

    Managerial and Decision Economics

    (1999)
  • B. Cassiman et al.

    R&D cooperation and spillovers: some empirical evidence from Belgium

    American Economic Review

    (2002)
  • T.H. Chiles et al.

    Integrating variable risk preferences, trust, and transaction cost economics

    The Academy of Management Review

    (1996)
  • R. Coase

    The nature of the firm

    Economica

    (1937)
  • F. Contractor

    Ownership patterns of US joint ventures abroad and the liberalization of foreign government regulations in the 1980s: evidence from the benchmark surveys

    Journal of International Business Studies

    (1990)
  • D’Aspremont et al.

    Cooperative and non-cooperative R&D in duopoly with spillovers

    The American Economic Review

    (1988)
  • Y. Doz et al.

    Alliance Advantage: The Art of Creating Advantage through Partnering

    (1998)
  • Y. Doz et al.

    Formation processes of R&D consortia: which path to take? Where does it lead?

    Strategic Management Journal

    (2000)
  • P. Dussauge et al.

    Learning from competing partners: outcomes and durations of scale and link alliances in Europe, North America, and Asia

    Strategic Management Journal

    (2000)
  • L.G. Franko

    Joint Venture Survival in Multinational Corporations

    (1971)
  • L.G. Franko

    Global corporate competition: who's winning, who's losing, and the R&D factor as one reason why

    Strategic Management Journal

    (1989)
  • N. Foss

    Theories of the firm: contractual and competence perspectives

    Journal of Evolutionary Economics

    (1993)
  • B. Gomes-Casseres

    Joint venture instability: is it a problem?

    Columbia Journal of World Business

    (1987)
  • B. Gomes-Casseres

    Alliance strategies of small firms

    Small Business Economics

    (1997)
  • P. Greenlee

    Endogenous formation of competitive research sharing joint ventures

    The Journal of Industrial Economics

    (2005)
  • G. Grossman et al.

    Research joint ventures: an antitrust analysis

    Journal of Law, Economics and Organization

    (1986)
  • R. Gulati

    Does familiarity breed trust? The implications of repeated ties for contractual choice in alliances

    The Academy of Management Journal

    (1995)
  • J. Hagedoorn et al.

    Choosing organizational modes of strategic technology partnering: international and sectoral differences

    Journal of International Business Studies

    (1996)
  • G. Hamel

    Competition for competence and inter-partner learning within international strategic alliances

    Strategic Management Journal

    (1991)
  • G. Hamel et al.

    Collaborate with your competitors and win

    Harvard Business Review

    (1989)
  • G. Hamel et al.

    The core competence of the corporation

    Harvard Business Review

    (1990)
  • Cited by (24)

    • R&D spillovers through RJV cooperation

      2022, Research Policy
      Citation Excerpt :

      For example, Fritsch and Lukas (2001), Tether (2002) and Colombo and Garrone (1996) find that a firm’s R&D intensity has indeed a positive and significant impact on the firm’s decision to cooperate formally. On the other hand, Miotti and Sachwald (2003), Cassiman and Veugelers (2002) and Duso et al. (2010) find no evidence that in-house R&D is influencing firms’ propensity to cooperate formally with other firms. Focusing on the cost of doing R&D, Feldman and Kelley (2006) find that R&D subsidies might lead firms to pool resources in an RJV and hence increase RJV participation.

    • Safety crises and R&D outsourcing alliances: Which governance mode minimizes negative spillovers?

      2018, Research Policy
      Citation Excerpt :

      While in joint ventures a new legal entity is created which is jointly owned by both organizations, norms of interaction in contractual agreements are defined in a contract (Kogut, 1988; Oxley, 1997; Oxley and Wada, 2009). One critical difference between joint ventures and contractual agreements is the ease with which knowledge flows across firm boundaries (Duso et al., 2010; García-Canal et al., 2008; Jiang and Li, 2009). Joint ventures, on the one hand, provide a tighter, richer, and more trustworthy interaction between allies (Hennart, 1988; Oxley and Sampson, 2004).

    • NPD collaboration in an asymmetrical investment context: A relational view

      2017, Journal of Engineering and Technology Management - JET-M
      Citation Excerpt :

      These intangible assets, such as technical knowledge and R&D (Duso et al., 2010), are difficult to coordinate across firms since they tend to be embedded in the routines and culture of the originating firm, composed largely of tacit (hard to articulate) knowledge and couched in the firm's specialized technical language (Sampson, 2004; Hoetker and Mellewigt, 2009). This is another cause for incomplete contracts, i.e. contracts that cannot fully specify the actions of each party in every contingency (Duso et al., 2010) and that make it difficult to define the optimal means of combining the alliance partners’ knowledge-based assets in advance (Hoetker and Mellewigt, 2009). Such assets are also difficult to control across boundaries (Duso et al., 2010) since it is difficult to ascertain whether each party is performing as agreed.

    • Knowledge acquisition and complementary specialization in alliances: The impact of technological overlap and alliance experience

      2016, Research Policy
      Citation Excerpt :

      Alliances can substantially contribute to firms’ technological capability development by providing them with opportunities to access and utilize new technological knowledge (Berchicci, 2013; Hagedoorn and Wang, 2012; Sampson, 2007). Numerous studies suggested that firms can leverage these opportunities by acquiring their alliance partners‘ technological knowledge and analyzed the determinants of knowledge acquisition (KA) across partnering firms in alliances (e.g. Duso et al., 2009; Hamel, 1991; Schildt et al., 2012). However, research has also noted the existence of alliances whose primary benefit to partnering firms is to foster complementary specialization1 (CS) rather than KA (e.g. Grant and Baden-Fuller, 2004; Mowery et al., 1996, 2002; Nakamura et al., 1996).

    • Management of alliance post-formation dynamics: an integrated model

      2023, Journal of Organizational Change Management
    View all citing articles on Scopus
    1

    Tel.: +49 30 2549 1403.

    2

    Tel.: +31 10 40 82166.

    View full text