The Economic Stimulus Payments of 2008 and the aggregate demand for consumption

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jmoneco.2014.09.002Get rights and content

Highlights

  • A panel of households were surveyed about their 2008 Economic Stimulus Payments.

  • Randomization of policy identifies spending caused by the receipt of a Payment.

  • On average, a household׳s spending rose 10 percent the week of arrival and stayed elevated.

  • Aggregated effects imply higher aggregate demand for consumption in summer of 2008.

  • Measure aggregate marginal propensity to consume from tax stimulus for DSGE models.

Abstract

Households in the Nielsen Consumer Panel were surveyed about their 2008 Economic Stimulus Payment. In estimates identified by the randomized timing of disbursement, the average household׳s spending rose by 10 percent the week it received a Payment and remained high cumulating to 1.5–3.8 percent of spending over three months. These estimates imply partial-equilibrium increases in aggregate demand of 1.3 percent of consumption in the second quarter of 2008 and 0.6 percent in the third. Spending is concentrated among households with low wealth or low past income; a household׳s spending did not increase significantly when it learned about its Payment.

Introduction

The US government passed the Economic Stimulus Act of 2008 in February 2008 in response to the recession that started in December 2007. The main part of Act was a $100-billion program of Economic Stimulus Payments (ESPs) designed to raise consumer demand. The ESPs averaged $900 and were disbursed to US taxpayers in the spring and summer of 2008. Around the time of the stimulus program, measured aggregate consumption is relatively smooth while measured disposable income rises and falls sharply with the disbursement of the Payments, providing “no evidence that the stimulus has had any impact in raising consumption” (Taylor, 2010; see also Feldstein (2008)). On the other hand, previous research finds significant increases in expenditures in response to predictable, predetermined and plausibly-exogenous changes in household-level income.1 Most relevant, Johnson et al., 2006, Johnson et al., 2009 and Agarwal et al. (2007) all find significant spending responses to the receipt of previous Federal tax rebates.2

This paper measures the spending responses of households to the Economic Stimulus Payments of 2008 and quantifies the partial-equilibrium increase in aggregate demand for consumer goods and services caused by the Payments so as to provide quantitative discipline for model-based inferences about the general-equilibrium efficacy of such tax-based stimulus policies. The effect of the receipt of the ESPs of 2008 on the demand for consumption is estimated by first measuring changes in the timing of household spending caused by differences in the timing of the receipt of ESPs, and then aggregating these changes using the temporal distribution of ESPs as reported by the U.S. Treasury and several different extrapolations from the observed goods to a broader measure of spending. “Receipt” is emphasized because our main analysis measures only changes in spending correlated with the date of receipt, so does not include for example changes in spending on the date of announcement. “Demand” is emphasized because the calculation is partial equilibrium and omits any multiplier effects or crowding-out from the policy.

To measure the spending effects of the ESPs, we conducted a multi-wave survey of roughly 60,000 households in Nielsen׳s consumer panel (NCP, formerly Homescan consumer panel) during the spring and summer of 2008. The NCP contains annual information on household demographics and income, and weekly information on spending on a set of household goods. Participating households are given barcode scanners which they use to report spending on trips to purchase households goods and to answer occasional surveys designed by Nielsen and typically used to study the efficacy of marketing campaigns. Our supplemental survey, designed in conjunction with Nielsen, uses this existing survey technology to collect information on the date of arrival of the first Economic Stimulus Payment received by each household, as well as its amount, whether it arrived by check or direct deposit, and when the household learned about the Payment. In addition, this survey contains several additional questions useful for our analysis, such as about expectations, access to liquidity and the amount of the ESP spent on NCP and non-NCP items. The resulting dataset has several advantages relative to those used in previous research: the sample is larger, spending is observed weekly, and the ESP information is collected with a short recall window; the main disadvantage is the limited set of goods covered.

We identify the change in spending caused by the receipt of an ESP at the household level following the Johnson et al. (2006) methodology using the fact that the law randomized the disbursement of ESPs over time. Because it was not administratively possible for the IRS to mail all checks or letters accompanying direct deposits at once, Payments were mailed out to households during a nine-week period between mid-May and the end of July, or deposited into households׳ accounts in one of the first three weeks of May. Among mailed checks and among deposited funds, the particular week in which the funds were disbursed depended on the second-to-last digit of the taxpayer׳s Social Security number, a number that is effectively randomly assigned.3

This randomization is used to identify the causal effect of the receipt of a Payment by comparing over time the spending of households that received their ESPs earlier relative to the spending of households that received their ESPs later, within each method of disbursement. This approach identifies the causal effect of the receipt of a Payment because the variation in the timing of receipt is unrelated to differential characteristics of households receiving the ESPs at different times and that might affect household spending differentially, such as differences in seasonal spending patterns, contemporaneous changes in wealth, information about future income, or monetary policy. To be clear, households may have adjusted their spending due to the Act and to the macroeconomic effects of the Act. Our methodology measures the extent to which – in this new world with the Act in place and each household׳s budget constraint fixed at its new level – the temporal pattern of spending differs for households that received their ESPs at different times but are otherwise (in expectation) identical. Differences in the temporal pattern of spending are thus due to differences in the timing of receipt (and factors uncorrelated with this timing) and measure the household-level impulse response of spending to the receipt of an ESP.

The average household׳s spending rises on receipt of a Payment and remains elevated for some time. A household raises its spending on NCP-measured household goods in the week of receipt by roughly 14 dollars, 10 percent of average weekly spending, or 1.5 percent of the average ESP. This spending effect decays over the following weeks, so that during the four weeks starting with the week of receipt, spending on NCP-measured goods is higher by 30 to 50 dollars, 5 to 7 percent of average weekly spending, or 3.5–5.5 percent of the ESP, with ranges reflecting different point estimates across specifications. Finally, over the quarter starting with receipt, spending rises by 60–90 dollars, 2–4 percent of spending (but statistically insignificant), and 7–12 percent of the ESP. In most specifications, there is no pre-treatment effect, that is, no economically or statistically significant change in spending prior to receipt.

Do households also adjust their spending when they learn about the stimulus program, as predicted by standard models of consumer behavior? Because the time of announcement is common across households and so uncorrelated with the timing of receipt, our estimates omit any such spending response at announcement. However, we investigate whether households adjusted their spending at the different dates at which they each learned about their EPSs. While not ruling out small effects consistent with the textbook lifecycle theory, there is no economically or statistically significant change in spending in the month in which the household learns that it will receive an ESP, even among households with significant liquid wealth.4

Because the NCP only measures a small slice of consumer spending, the spending effects estimated in this paper need to be scaled in order to make them comparable to those in other studies and to moments from structural models. This scaling is done in three different ways: (i) scaling NCP spending per capita to match National Income and Product Account (NIPA) spending per capita, (ii) scaling the change in spending on NCP goods by the average reported ESP spending on all goods relative to that on NCP goods alone, (iii) and scaling the change in spending on NCP goods by a factor based on the relative share of spending and relative responsiveness across subcategories of goods as measured in Consumer Expenditure (CE) Survey by Parker et al. (2013). These calculations imply that in a quarterly model, the propensity to consume at the individual level from an equivalent tax rebate in a quarter is between 50 percent and 75 percent. In a more realistic continuous-time or higher-frequency model, if tax rebates were uniformly distributed during a quarter, the average partial-equilibrium spending response would be 30–45 percent of the rebate amount during the quarter of disbursement and 20–30 percent during the following quarter.

Turning to the actual effects in 2008, the increase in demand for goods during and shortly after the program caused by the receipt of the Payments in 2008 is estimated by applying the household-level impulse responses to the observed aggregate disbursements of the ESPs over time as reported by the US Treasury Department (2008). Fig. 1 shows the results of subtracting the estimated effects from the actual PCE series observed in the U.S. The disbursement of the ESPs directly raised the demand for consumption by between 1.3 percent and 1.8 percent in the second quarter of 2008 and by 0.6–0.9 percent in the third quarter of 2008, with ranges reflecting differences across scaling factors. Again, these are partial-equilibrium accounting exercises and the ultimate effect on consumption may have been more or less.

It is important to note that these aggregation exercises are not atheoretical, but rely on assumptions about household behavior. In particular, as discussed in Section 4, the receipt of an ESP is assumed not to cause households to reduce spending in a common way in calendar time that is unrelated to the timing of their ESP receipt (event time). Such as assumption is consistent with all the models of consumer behavior of which we are aware.

Finally, to inform both the macroeconomic modeling of household behavior and the targeting of future rebate programs, we investigate how income levels and liquidity are related to the propensity to consume. Households in the bottom third of the 2007 income distribution had larger propensities to spend out of their EPS׳s in the month of arrival than households in the top third. This difference narrows over time and becomes indistinguishable by the end of the quarter. There is statistically weak evidence that households in the middle third of the income distribution spend less than those above or below them.

More significantly, households in the bottom 40 percent of the distribution of liquid wealth spend at roughly triple the rate of the rest of the households during the month of receipt, and at roughly double the rate during the three months starting with receipt, so that households with low liquid wealth account for the majority of the estimated spending response.

This paper is most closely related to the contemporaneous paper, Parker et al. (2013) (PSJM), which studies the increased aggregate demand caused by the receipt of the 2008 ESPs in the CE survey. In similar specifications, PSJM finds quite similar effects to those in the present paper: a 3.6–4.5 percent increases in household nondurable spending in response to the receipt of a rebate during the three months of receipt, and an increase in aggregate demand of 1.3–2.3 percent in the second quarter of 2008 and 0.6–1.0 percent in the third. Due to a larger sample size and better measurement, the present study is able to measure more precisely, using only random variation, as the average spending effect as well as differences in spending by relative income and liquid assets.

Several other papers exploit the same random variation to show how the receipt of a Payment affects other economic outcomes. The arrival of an ESP also causes lower usage of payday loans by households using loans before receipt (Bertrand and Morse, 2009), a higher rate of bankruptcy (Gross et al., 2014), and a higher rate of death (Evans and Moore, 2011). Finally Bureau of Labor Statistics (2009), Shapiro and Slemrod (2009), and Sahm et al. (2010) report that 20–30 percent of households report that they mainly spent their ESPs, numbers that are broadly consistent with the present paper׳s findings.

This paper is structured as follows. Section 2 describes the ESP program, Section 3 describes the Nielsen Consumer Panel data and our supplemental survey, and Section 4 presents the estimation methodology. Section 5 contains the main results about household level spending and Section 6 aggregates these to give increases in aggregate demand designed for use in models. 7 The average response of spending to learning about an ESP, 8 Heterogeneity in the response of spending across households present estimates of spending changes caused by learning about the ESPs and how the response to receipt differs with liquidity and previous income. Section 9 concludes and an online Supplementary appendix contains additional details on data and replication.5

Section snippets

The 2008 Economic Stimulus Payments

The Economic Stimulus Act of 2008, passed by Congress in January and signed into law on February 13, 2008, authorized the distribution of stimulus Payments consisting of a basic payment and – conditional on eligibility for the basic payment – a supplemental payment of $300 per child that qualified for the child tax credit.6 The basic payment was generally the maximum of $300 ($600 for couples filing jointly) and a

NCP household-level data on expenditures and ESP receipt

The relation between ESPs and expenditures is measured using information from Nielsen׳s Consumer Panel (NCP) for 2008 (formerly Nielsen׳s Homescan Consumer Panel), a survey of U.S. households that tracks spending mainly on household goods with Universal Product Codes (UPCs, referred to as “barcodes”).11

Estimation methodology

Our analysis uses the following regression equation to estimate the average impact of the receipt of an ESP on spending for household i in week t receiving a Payment by method mCi,t=µi+β(L)ESPi,t+τm,t+ηi,twhere Ci,t is either the dollar amount of spending in week t for household i or the ratio of that level of spending to the average weekly spending of that household during 2008 prior to the ESP disbursements (the first 12 weeks of the year). µi is a household-specific intercept that captures

The average response of spending to the receipt of an ESP

This section begins by identifying the average effect of the receipt of an ESP on weekly spending in the sample of all households from all available variation in timing, including that due to different method of disbursement, so τm,t=τt in Eq. (1). The first three columns of Table 3 display estimates of β(.) – the coefficient on the one included lead, the contemporaneous ESP variable, and the first three lags (of the complete set of included lags).

First, on average, there is a highly

The partial-equilibrium, aggregate effect of the stimulus Payments

What do these household-level estimates imply for macroeconomic models of fiscal policy and for the efficacy of the actual policy in 2008? This section presents calculations of the change in aggregate consumption demand associated with a given disbursement of stimulus Payments. This calculation involves two steps: first scaling the increase in demand for NCP goods to a broad measure of spending on goods and services, and then second aggregating these responses to moments useful for matching by

The average response of spending to learning about an ESP

This section investigates whether households increased their spending on NCP-measured goods at the different times at which they learned about their ESPs. After households reported receiving an ESP, the ESP survey asked “Was this about the amount your household was expecting?” Households could respond, “no and we were surprised to get any rebate at all,” “no and it was less than we were expecting,” or “no and it was more than we were expecting.” They could also respond “yes, and we have known

Heterogeneity in the response of spending across households

This section investigates the differential spending response of households across 2007 income levels and across different levels of liquid wealth. Temporarily low income may indicate low liquidity and a high propensity to consume. Alternatively, low income may indicate greater impatience or other characteristics of people who are more (or less) likely to spend income when it arrives. Similarly, low liquidity when combined with sufficiently high impatience or expected increases in income may

Conclusion

In normal times, monetary policy is the main instrument of stabilization policy arguably because the effects of monetary policy are reasonably well understood and because central banks can react rapidly to the possibility of a recession. But monetary policy has limitations – lags in its effect, increases in inflation, and reduced efficacy when financial institutions are capital-poor or when the zero lower bound on nominal interest rates binds. At such times, fiscal policy in the form of tax

References (34)

  • W.N. Evans et al.

    The short-term mortality consequences of income receipt

    J. Public Econ.

    (2011)
  • R. Reis

    Inattentive Consumers

    J. Monet. Econ.

    (2006)
  • N.S. Souleles

    Consumer response to the Reagan tax cuts

    J. Public Econ.

    (2002)
  • S. Agarwal et al.

    The response of consumer spending and debt to tax rebates – evidence from consumer credit data

    J. Polit. Econ.

    (2007)
  • A.J. Auerbach et al.

    Activist fiscal policy to stabilize economic activity

    Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City, Financial Stability and Macroeconomic Policy: A Symposium

    (2010)
  • M. Bertrand et al.

    What do high-interest borrowers do with their tax rebate?

    Am. Econ. Rev.

    (2009)
  • A.S. Blinder

    Temporary income taxes and consumer spending

    J. Polit. Econ.

    (1981)
  • Broda, C., Parker, J.A., 2008. The Impact of the 2008 Tax Rebates on Consumer Spending: Preliminary Evidence. Kellogg...
  • C. Broda et al.

    Product creation and destruction: evidence and price implications

    Am. Econ. Rev.

    (2008)
  • M. Browning et al.

    Household saving: micro theories and macro facts

    J. Econ. Lit.

    (1996)
  • Bureau of Labor Statistics, U.S. Department of Labor, 2009. Consumer Expenditure Survey Results on the 2008 Economic...
  • Coronado, J.L., Lupton, J.P., Sheiner, L.M., 2005. The Household Spending Response to the 2003 Tax Cut: Evidence from...
  • A. Deaton

    Understanding Consumption

    (1992)
  • Department of the Treasury

    Daily Treasury Statement

    (2008)
  • M. Feldstein

    The tax rebate was a flop. Obama׳s stimulus plan won׳t work either

    Wall Street J

    (2008)
  • M. Flavin

    The adjustment of consumption to changing expectations about future income

    J. Polit. Econ.

    (1981)
  • T. Gross et al.

    Liquidity Constraints and consumer bankruptcy: evidence from tax rebates

    Rev. Econ. Stat.

    (2014)
  • Cited by (149)

    • Stimulus payments and private transfers

      2023, Economics Letters
      Citation Excerpt :

      Knowing the propensity for individuals to spend out of extra resources is crucial for determining when stimulus measures should be deployed and how they should be targeted to achieve maximum impact. Studies of how households respond to income windfalls typically focus on the extent to which households use funds to increase spending, increasing savings, or pay down debt (see for example the responses allowed in questions of how individuals responded or would respond to income windfalls in Shapiro and Slemrod (1995, 2003, 2009), Jappelli and Pistaferri (2020), Fuster et al. (2021), Broda and Parker (2014) and others). However, private transfers between households can be significant in times of economic distress (McGarry, 2016; Crossley et al., 2021a), and a non-trivial proportion of households report that they would use income windfalls to either increase the funds they give others or reduce the amount of financial assistance they receive from elsewhere (Crossley et al., 2021b).

    View all citing articles on Scopus

    We thank the Sloan School of Management at MIT, the Kellogg School of Management at Northwestern University, the Initiative for Global Markets at the University of Chicago, and the Zell Center at the Kellogg School of Management for funding for the survey and data. Parker thanks the Laboratory for Applied Economics and Policy at Harvard for funding. For helpful comments on our research, we thank Jordi Gali, Daniel Green, Greg Kaplan, Ricardo Reis, Sam Schulhofer-Wohl, Nicholas Souleles, anonymous referees on our grant application and at the JME, and participants in numerous seminars and conferences. We would also like to thank Ed Grove, Matt Knain and Molly Hagen at ACNielsen. All results are calculated based on data from the Nielsen Company (US), LLC and provided by the Marketing Data Center at The University of Chicago Booth School of Business. This paper updates and replaces the earlier analysis in Broda and Parker (2008).

    View full text