Inflation targeting and the forward bias puzzle in emerging countries

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jimonfin.2018.09.003Get rights and content

Highlights

  • In emerging countries, inflation targeting leads to the appearance of the forward bias puzzle.

  • This reflects the performance of inflation targeting in lowering the level and volatility of inflation.

  • This result is robust to various specifications and estimation techniques.

Abstract

Based on quarterly data on 31 emerging countries (among which 16 are inflation targeting countries) from 1990Q1 to 2014Q3, we obtain a strong support for the conjecture that the implementation of inflation targeting weakens the Fisherian relation between expected depreciation and the interest rate differential (uncovered interest parity condition) and thus is conducive to the appearance of the forward bias puzzle in emerging countries. We show that this reflects the performance of inflation targeting regimes in lowering the level and volatility of inflation. Our finding holds when controlling for country-specific effects, time-specific effects, global disinflation, exchange rate management, crises, and using different econometric techniques.

Introduction

After being initiated by New Zealand in 1990, inflation targeting (hereafter IT)1 has been adopted by a large number of industrial and emerging countries as a strategy to conduct monetary policy. Several studies have found evidence that adopting an IT strategy has lead to overall economic performance (Bernanke and Mishkin, 1997, Svensson, 1997, Mishkin and Schmidt-Hebbel, 2007). More specifically, the adoption of IT by some emerging countries has helped to reduce the level and volatility of inflation in these countries (Gonçalves and Salles, 2008, Lin and Ye, 2009, De Mendonça and Guimaraes e Souza, 2012).

The contribution of this paper is to examine the impact of IT on the uncovered interest parity (hereafter UIP) condition in emerging countries through the reducing effect of IT on inflation uncertainty or a greater weight on the inflation in monetary policy rule during IT. The forward bias puzzle (hereafter FBP) referring to the failure of UIP to hold is well documented (Fama, 1984, Bansal and Dahlquist, 2000, Chinn and Meredith, 2004, Ito and Chinn, 2007, Frankel and Poonawala, 2010). Its corresponds to a slope coefficient less than 1 in the so-called Fama regression (regression of the expected currency depreciation and interest rate differential). The forward premium puzzle (hereafter FPP) (i.e. a negative slope coefficient in the Fama regression) which is an extreme form of the FBP occurs in developed economies but not in emerging countries. This feature is explained by the high level of inflation uncertainty in the latter ones (Bansal and Dahlquist, 2000, Frankel and Poonawala, 2010). More specifically, as noticed by Bansal and Dahlquist (2000), the absence of FPP in emerging countries is consistent with the reasoning developed in models incorporating non-Fisherian effects (Lucas, 1990, Fuerst, 1992). In these models, in presence of high inflation uncertainty or high expected inflation the Fisherian effects are overwhelming. However, in low inflation environments, the non-Fisherian fundamentals may be predominant. As emerging economies display large inflation uncertainty and/or high expected inflation the Fisherian relation between expected depreciation and the interest rate differential holds. As a result, the FPP is absent. On the contrary, as developed countries are generally low inflation economies, the non-Fisherian effects are important, leading to the FPP. Farhi and Gabaix (2016) theoretically rationalized the empirically evidence of Bansal and Dahlquist (2000) by developing a disaster-based tractable framework for the analysis of exchange rates. They show that the UIP tends to hold in countries with very variable inflation (typically countries with high average inflation) since these countries have a high risk of depreciating in bad states. Using a standard open macroeconomic model, Park and Park (2017) also theoretically rationalized the finding of Bansal and Dahlquist (2000) showing that the UIP is more likely to hold in low-inflation countries since their monetary rules likely put higher weight on inflation. Therefore, by lowering inflation or putting higher weight on inflation in policy rule, the adoption of IT in some emerging countries may lead to the appearance of the FBP in these countries, in contrast with the non-adopting IT emerging countries. We test this conjecture in this paper.

Compared with previous empirical studies on the influence of monetary policy on the UIP condition (Park and Park, 2017, Kim et al., 2017), we contribute to the literature on the FBP by investigating the link between the adoption of IT and FBP in emerging countries. Contrary to Park and Park (2017) which examine the FBP for inflation targeting and non-targeting countries, before and after the global financial crisis, we investigate the FBP in emerging countries by comparing inflation targeters before and after IT adoption and inflation targeters with non-targeters. Given its focus on inflation targeting in emerging countries, our study also differs from Kim et al. (2017) who, using data on 14 US-trading partners (advanced countries), find that UIP fails to hold during the Volker disinflation episode and tends to hold during the post-Volker era.

To test our conjecture, we conduct an empirical investigation using quarterly data on 31 emerging countries (among which 16 are IT countries) from 1990Q1 to 2014Q3. Our results are consistent with the conjecture that IT modifies the pattern of interest rates determination which reverberates on the behavior of exchange rates. Specifically, we find that the implementation of IT in emerging countries expands the FBP. We show that this reflects the fact that IT helps creating a low and stable inflation environment. This finding holds after controlling for country-specific effects, time-specific effects, global disinflation, exchange rate management, currency crises and global financial crisis. It still holds when we use alternative econometric techniques.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 provides the theoretical background on the link between inflation targeting and the FBP. Section 3 describes the data used in the empirical estimation. Section 4 presents the empirical analysis. Finally, Section 5 contains concluding comments.

Section snippets

The Fama regression

Given open international bond markets, the no-arbitrage condition of covered interest parity (hereafter CIP) requiresftk-st=itk-iUS,tkwhere st is the logarithm of the spot exchange rate at time t expressed as the price of domestic currency per unit of the foreign currency (the US dollar), ftk represents the logarithm of the corresponding forward rate set at time t, payable at t+k;itk and iUS,tk denote the nominal interest rates observed at time t on k-period maturity risk-free bonds in domestic

Data

We use quarterly data from 31 emerging countries (see Table 1 for the list of countries). These countries are selected according to data availability. The sample period goes from 1990Q1 to 2014Q3. Among these countries, 16 have implemented inflation targeting. For each of these targeters, the adoption dates are reported in Table 1. As in Bansal and Dahlquist (2000), so as to assess the forward premium interest rate differentials are obtained by subtracting the interest rate for each country

Empirical analysis and results

We adopt a panel data approach since, as evidenced by Baillie and Bollerslev (2000), univariate time series would lead to inconsistent results. Indeed, the interest rate differential being very persistent, the standard asymptotic distribution for the slope coefficient is a very poor approximation for small samples. Hence using panel data mitigates this inference problem (Bansal and Dahlquist, 2000). Moreover the panel data approach tackles the data limitation problem that is important for

Conclusion

Many empirical studies provide evidence of the violation of the uncovered interest parity condition known as the forward bias puzzle. There is evidence of the forward premium puzzle (an extreme form of forward bias puzzle in which the forward discount points in the wrong direction) in developed countries. On the opposite, for emerging market countries, the forward premium puzzle is absent and on average the forward discount rate points in the right direction.

In this paper, we examine whether

References (42)

  • E. Levy Yeyati et al.

    Classifying exchange rate regimes: deeds vs. words

    Eur. Econ. Rev.

    (2005)
  • S. Lin et al.

    Does inflation targeting really make a difference? Evaluating the treatment effect of inflation targeting in seven industrial countries

    J. Monet. Econ.

    (2007)
  • S. Lin et al.

    Does inflation targeting make a difference in developing countries?

    J. Dev. Econ.

    (2009)
  • R.E. Lucas

    Liquidity and interest rates

    J. Econ. Theory

    (1990)
  • B.T. McCallum

    A reconsideration of the uncovered interest parity relationship

    J. Monet. Econ.

    (1994)
  • C. Park et al.

    Can monetary policy cause the uncovered interest parity puzzle?

    Japan World Econ.

    (2017)
  • A.K. Rose

    A stable international monetary system emerges: inflation targeting is Bretton Woods, reversed

    J. Int. Money Finan.

    (2007)
  • Ball, L., Sheridan, N., 2006. Does inflation targeting matter? In: Bernanke, Ben S., Woodford, Michael (Eds.) The...
  • R. Bansal

    An exploration of the forward premium puzzle in currency markets

    Rev. Finan. Stud.

    (1997)
  • B. Bernanke et al.

    Inflation targeting: a new framework of monetary policy?

    J. Econ. Perspect.

    (1997)
  • Backus, D.K., Gavazzoni, F., Telmer, C., Zin, S.E., 2010. Monetary policy and the uncovered interest parity puzzle....
  • Cited by (14)

    • Does domestic investment respond to inflation targeting? A synthetic control investigation

      2022, International Economics
      Citation Excerpt :

      Indeed, our IT-induced price effects give credence to existing studies that find IT reduces inflation and inflation volatility in developing countries (see, e.g., Lin and Ye, 2009; Gonçalves and Salles, 2008; de Mendonça & de Guimarães e Souza, 2012). Recently, through the lens of the uncovered interest parity condition, Coulibaly and Kempf (2019) show that an IT regime is effective at lowering inflation and inflation volatility. Above and beyond inflation, Gonçalves and Salles (2008) find that IT engender reduced growth volatility in emerging market economies.

    • How puzzling is the forward premium puzzle? A meta-analysis

      2021, European Economic Review
      Citation Excerpt :

      Yet still no clear-cut consensus emerges on whether the puzzle really exists or whether it represents a statistical artifact, how large the departure from the null hypothesis is, and how material the implications are in practice. Important prospective solutions to the forward premium puzzle put forward in the last decade include infrequent portfolio decisions (Bacchetta and van Wincoop, 2010), investor overconfidence (Burnside et al., 2011), omitted variables (Pippenger, 2011), sentiment (Yu, 2013), sovereign default risk (Coudert and Mignon, 2013), order flow (Breedon et al., 2016), rare disasters (Farhi and Gabaix, 2016), and monetary policy changes (Kim et al., 2017; Park and Park, 2017; Coulibaly and Kempf, 2019), a string of efforts that highlights persistent research activity in the field. What the literature lacks is a quantitative synthesis, or meta-analysis, that would take stock of the enormous body of work and shed light on potential biases and patterns that are impossible to detect in individual studies considered separately.

    • Does risk premium help uncover the uncovered interest parity failure?

      2019, Journal of International Financial Markets, Institutions and Money
      Citation Excerpt :

      This is the UIP failure, a condition when the exchange rate change is negatively related to interest rate differential (or forward rate is not an unbiased predictor of the future spot rate), popularly known as forward premium puzzle (Fama, 1984). This puzzle has now become a stylized fact and has been reported in many studies (see, for example, Fama, 1984; Kaminsky and Peruga, 1990; Backus et al., 1995; Li et al., 2012; Kumar and Trück, 2014; Kumar, 2018, Bussiere et al., 2018; Coulibaly and Kempf, 2019, etc.). A number of studies have attempted to provide a rationale for the UIP failure through different arguments1; they however, fall in two main categories.

    • PROSPECTS FOR JOINING THE EURO AREA: NEW EVIDENCE THROUGH THE LENS OF THE UNCOVERED INTEREST PARITY APPROACH

      2023, Economic Computation and Economic Cybernetics Studies and Research
    View all citing articles on Scopus

    We thank seminar participants at CREST and Centre d’économie de la Sorbonne for their remarks on a preliminary version. We are grateful to Valérie Mignon for helpful comments. The usual disclaimer applies.

    View full text