Trade liberalization and unemployment: Theory and evidence from India

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jdeveco.2011.04.002Get rights and content

Abstract

A widely held view among the public is that trade liberalization increases unemployment. Using state and industry-level unemployment and trade protection data from India, we find no evidence of any unemployment increasing effect of trade reforms. In fact, our state-level analysis reveals that urban unemployment declines with trade liberalization in states with flexible labor markets and larger employment shares in net exporter industries. Moreover, our industry-level analysis indicates that workers in industries experiencing greater reductions in trade protection were less likely to become unemployed, especially in net export industries. Our results can be explained within a theoretical framework incorporating trade and search-generated unemployment and some institutional features of the Indian economy.

Introduction

There now exists a small but growing literature on the relationship between trade and unemployment.1 Much of this literature is theoretical, with a few exceptions.2 A recent contribution based on cross-country analysis and which incorporates developing country experience is Dutt et al. (2009). Using cross-country data on trade policy, unemployment, and various controls, and controlling for endogeneity and measurement-error problems, they find that unemployment and trade openness are negatively related. Using panel data, they find an unemployment-increasing short-run impact of trade liberalization, followed by an unemployment-reducing effect leading to the new steady state. While that paper finds interesting empirical regularities that can be explained using plausible models of trade and search unemployment, the standard criticisms of cross-country regressions apply to that study as well. Countries differ from each other in very important ways that cannot always be controlled for by variables we use in such regressions.

The key empirical studies that analyze the links between trade policy and unemployment for individual developing countries are Attanasio et al., 2004, Menezes-Filho and Muendler, 2007, Porto, 2008. These studies focus on the experiences of Columbia, Brazil, and Argentina, respectively. Using labor force survey data spanning the period before and after Colombia's trade liberalization in the early 1990s, and relying on information on the one digit industry in which unemployed individuals either worked previously or were looking for employment, Attanasio et al. (2004) find the following: while the overall probability of unemployment increased after liberalization, this increase was driven by nontraded sectors such as wholesale and retail trade rather than traded sectors such as manufacturing. On the other hand, based on a unique and very rich linked employer–employee data set which allows formally employed workers to be tracked over time and across production sectors, Menezes-Filho and Muendler (2007) find that Brazil's trade liberalization in the 1990s led to the displacement of formally employed workers from protected industries and that ‘comparative advantage’ industries or exporters did not absorb trade-displaced workers in full. Their complementary analysis of employment survey data reveals that many of these formally employed workers transitioned to informal work or self-employment. For others, trade liberalization was associated with transitions to unemployment.

Porto (2008) examines the links between trade liberalization and unemployment (and wages) in the case of Argentina. However, the focus of his study is a little different from the other two studies. More specifically, Porto investigates how world agricultural trade liberalization can be expected to affect unemployment (and wages) in Argentina using an empirical model of trade, unemployment, and labor supply. His estimates indicate that an increase in the price of Argentine agro-manufactured exports can be expected to lead to both a lower unemployment rate and an increase in labor market participation. Wages also increase given an increase in export prices.

In this paper, we contribute to the empirical trade and unemployment literature using labor force survey data from India, a developing country that has, in the last couple of decades, experienced major trade reforms and where a significant proportion of the population lives below the poverty line. This makes such a study useful for policy analysis.

We carry out our empirical analysis of trade and unemployment at two levels. In addition to an industry level analysis along the lines of Attanasio et al. (2004) (and close in spirit to Menezes-Filho and Muendler, 2007), we also carry out analysis at the state level. Importantly, constitutional arrangements which give India's states considerable regulatory power over economic matters and the large size of these states (larger than the vast majority of countries), with unique ethno-linguistic characteristics, make such an analysis meaningful. In particular, interstate variations in labor regulations (see Besley and Burgess, 2004) and low mobility across Indian states (see Dyson et al., 2004, Topalova, 2010) suggest that treating each state as an independent labor market is a reasonable approximation. Additionally, we adopt broadly the strategy of Topalova, 2007, Hasan et al., 2007b and exploit variations in industrial composition across Indian states (districts in the case of Topalova) around the time of the major trade liberalization of the early 1990s, and the variation in the degree of liberalization across industries over time to construct state-specific measures of protection. This allows us to determine whether states more exposed to reductions in protection experienced increases or decreases in unemployment rates.

We then complement our cross-state analysis of the relationship between unemployment and liberalization with a detailed analysis based purely on changes in industry-level variations in protection over time. More specifically, we examine whether workers in industries experiencing greater reductions in trade protection were more or less likely to become unemployed (relative to the average worker) using the two-stage approach used by Attanasio et al. (2004).

In so far as our state-level analysis is concerned, we find that overall (rural plus urban) unemployment on average does not have any relationship with average protection (weighted average with 1993 sectoral employment as weights) over time and across states. However, there are some conditional relationships between the two variables in certain types of states. In states with more flexible labor markets, there is evidence that on average overall and urban unemployment are positively related to protection. We also find that reductions in protection reduce unemployment in the urban sectors of states with large employment shares in net exporter industries.

Turning to our analysis based purely on industry-level protection, we find hardly any evidence that workers in industries that experienced larger reductions in protection were more likely to be unemployed. In fact, there is some evidence that such workers were less likely to become unemployed, a result that is stronger in states with flexible labor regulations and net exporter industries. There is also some weak evidence that the immediate short-run effect of a tariff reduction may be an increase in unemployment prior to reduction to a lower steady-state unemployment rate.

We show how our empirical results are consistent with the impact of trade liberalization in a two sector model, with labor being the only factor of production and where unemployment arises due to search frictions. We discuss two extreme cases: (a) perfect labor mobility (the Ricardian case), where comparative advantage is exclusively productivity-driven and (b) no intersectoral labor mobility (where labor becomes sector-specific), where comparative advantage, while still dependent on productivity, is also driven by relative sectoral labor force size. Our empirical results fall in between the two extremes, depending on the flexibility of labor markets.3

Section snippets

Production structure

Consider an economy that produces a single final good and two intermediate goods. The final good is non-tradable, while the intermediate goods are tradable. The final good denoted by Z is the numeraire and the two intermediate goods are denoted by X and Y, their prices being px and py, respectively. The production function for the final good is as follows:Z=AX1αYααα(1α)1α;0<α<1.

Given the prices px and py, of inputs, the unit cost for producing Z is given as follows:c(px,py)=(px)1α(py)αA.

The Indian policy and institutional framework

There are two features of the Indian policy and institutional landscape that have an important bearing on the strategy we adopt for estimating the impact of trade protection on unemployment rates. First, notwithstanding some earlier efforts, India undertook a dramatic liberalization of trade policies in 1991. Thus, for example, mean tariffs, which were 128% before July 1991, had fallen to roughly 35% by 1997–98 and the standard deviation of tariffs during this period went down from 41

State-level analysis

Our strategy for estimating the impact of trade protection on state unemployment is along the lines of Topalova, 2007, Hasan et al., 2007b, both of which examine the relationship between trade liberalization and poverty. In particular, we estimate variants of the following basic regression specification:lnyitj=αj+β1jprotectionit1j+β2jprotectionit1j*regulationi+δij+μtj+εitjwhere yjit is the natural logarithm of the unemployment rate in state i and sector j (i.e., for the state as a whole or a

State-level unemployment

State- and sector-specific unemployment rates – i.e., unemployment rates for the state as a whole as well as its rural and urban subcomponents – were computed using data from the “employment–unemployment” surveys carried out by India's National Sample Survey Organisation (NSSO). We utilize the four most recent quinquennial rounds of the surveys covering the years 1987–88, 1993–94, 1999–2000, and 2004–05 — years which enable our analysis to span a period that starts approximately three years

State unemployment

In Table 2, we present results using the natural logarithm of the state unemployment rates as the dependent variable. In all our regressions presented in this table and all subsequent state-level ones, we use state-level fixed effects and year dummies. The primary state-level protection measure used is tariffs. The results in columns 1–5 in Table 2 indicate that there is no evidence of any effect of protection on unemployment for the overall sample. The coefficient of tariffs is mostly positive

Concluding remarks

In this paper, we have empirically examined the relationship between trade protection and unemployment using labor force survey data from India. We find that trade liberalization has an unemployment reducing effect in states with flexible labor markets, and in states with a high employment share in the net export sectors. In addition to the state-level findings, we also find that workers in industries experiencing greater trade liberalization were less likely to become unemployed, especially in

References (31)

  • Das, D. (2008). “Trade Barriers Measurement: A Methodological Overview." Mimeo (available from Hasan/Mitra/Ranjan upon...
  • C. Davidson et al.

    International Trade and Labor Markets: Theory, Evidence, and Policy Implications

    (2004)
  • C. Davidson et al.

    Trade and turnover: theory and evidence

    Review of International Economics

    (2005)
  • T. Dyson et al.

    Twenty-first Century India: Population, Economy, Human Development, and the Environment

    (2004)
  • G. Felbermayr et al.

    Globalization and Labor Market Outcomes: Wage Bargaining, Search Frictions, and Firm Heterogeneity

  • Cited by (115)

    • Optimal Infrastructure after Trade Reform in India

      2024, Journal of Development Economics
    • The effects of IMF conditional programs on the unemployment rate

      2023, European Journal of Political Economy
      Citation Excerpt :

      On the other hand, trade liberalization entails the danger of job destruction for the import-competing sector of an economy and low-skilled individuals, particularly through increased imports. In addition, large-N cross-country empirical studies have not found a consistent answer (e.g. Autor et al., 2013; Hasan et al., 2012; Moore and Ranjan, 2005). Trade liberalization has been a high priority through adjustment lending by the IFIs and project lending by the World Bank.

    View all citing articles on Scopus

    We are indebted to two anonymous referees and the co-editor, Gordon Hanson for detailed and very constructive comments on earlier versions of this paper. We also thank seminar participants at the University of Adelaide, the University of Auckland, the University of Melbourne, the University of New South Wales, the University of Otago, the University of Sydney and the 6th Growth and Development Conference at the Indian Statistical Institute, Delhi for very useful comments and suggestions. J. Salcedo Cain provided excellent research assistance on this project. We also thank Deb Kusum Das for developing some of the data on trade protection used by us. The work of both was supported by an ADB technical assistance project (RETA 6364: Measurement and Policy Analysis for Poverty Reduction). The paper represents the views of the authors and does not necessarily represent those of the Asian Development Bank, its Executive Directors, or the countries that they represent. The standard disclaimer applies.

    View full text