Elsevier

Games and Economic Behavior

Volume 90, March 2015, Pages 119-127
Games and Economic Behavior

Size versus fairness in the assignment problem

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.geb.2014.11.006Get rights and content

Abstract

When not all objects are acceptable to all agents, maximizing the number of objects actually assigned is an important design concern. We compute the guaranteed size ratio of the Probabilistic Serial mechanism, i.e., the worst ratio of the actual expected size to the maximal feasible size. It converges decreasingly to 11e63.2% as the maximal size increases. It is the best ratio of any Envy-Free assignment mechanism.

Section snippets

The problem and the punchline

Lotteries are commonly used to allocate indivisible resources (objects), especially so when monetary transfers are ruled out. Examples include the assignment of jobs to time-slots, of workers to tasks or offices, the allocation of seats in overdemanded public schools (Abdulkadiroğlu and Sonmez, 2003, Kojima and Unver, 2014), of students to dormitory rooms or courses, etc. An excellent survey is the work of Sonmez and Unver (2011). Using cash transfers and prices in such problems skews the

Related literature

1) The first random assignment mechanism in Hylland and Zeckhauser (1979) is a competitive equilibrium with fiat money to buy lotteries, and relies on cardinal (von Neuman Morgenstern) individual utilities over objects. Such individual reports are too complex in practice, so attention turned to the more realistic ordinal mechanisms where a report is simply a ranking of the acceptable objects. The most natural ordinal mechanism is the time honored Random Priority (RP), a.k.a. serial

Random assignment with outside options

Fix N the set of agents and A of objects, with respective cardinalities n and q. A preference Ri of agent iN is a possibly empty ordered subset of A, written Ri=(a1,a2,,ak) where a1 is the best object for i and ak her least preferred acceptable object. We write Ri= if no object is acceptable to i, and aRi means that a is an acceptable object for i. The set of individual preferences is R(A).

A profile of preferences RR(A) defines a compatibility bipartite graph EN×A: iaE(R)aRi,

Efficiency and guaranteed size

Given a problem Δ and two deterministic assignments P,PPd(E(Δ)), we say that P Pareto dominates P if PP and for all a,b{pia=1andpib=1}aRib{pia=0for alla}{pia=0for alla} An efficient (Pareto optimal) deterministic assignment is one that is not Pareto dominated.

In any problem ΔAm there is at least one efficient deterministic assignment of size m (i.e., the maximum possible size). This follows because if an assignment PPd(E) is Pareto dominated by P, then s(P)s(P). On the other hand

Three axioms and two mechanisms

Given a problem Δ, agent i compares two feasible assignments P,PP(E(Δ)) by means of her own allocations p(i)=(pia)aA and p(i), the i-th rows of P and P respectively. We define a critical incomplete preference relation for agent i with preferences Ri=(a1,,ak), 1kq. We say that p(i) is sd-preferred to p(i) (where sd stands for stochastic dominance) if1tpiat1tpiatfor allt,1tk and we write p(i)sdip(i) (this relation is empty if Ri=). Note that sd-indifference is just equality. We

The result

For any two integers k,m such that 1k<m we defineS(m,k)=1k+1+1k+2++1m Noticing that S(m,k) decreases in k, we define for any m2 the integer km by the inequalitiesS(m,km)1<S(m,km1) Finally we set rm=1kmmS(m,km).

For large k,m we have S(m,k)ln(mk) hence for large m: ln(mkm)1km1em, and finally rm11e. We can say more:

Lemma 1

The sequence rm is decreasing and converges to 11e=0.632 at the speed O(1n). For instance r2=0.750, r3=0.722, r4=0.708, r5=0.687, r10=0.662, r20=0.648. (proof in

Concluding comments

1. There are inefficient Envy-Free mechanisms with a worse performance than PS, that are still better than throwing away all objects all the time. For instance we can draw objects uniformly and offer them sequentially, uniformly among all the still unmatched agents, throwing the winner and the object away if she does not accept it. This is clearly an envy-free mechanism because once an object is drawn, it is lost to agents other than the winner, therefore the distribution of objects a given

References (26)

  • Bogomolnaia, A. Random assignment: redefining the serial rule. Glasgow University....
  • A. Bogomolnaia et al.

    A simple random assignment problem with a unique solution

    Econ. Theory

    (2002)
  • E. Budish et al.

    Designing random allocation mechanisms: theory and applications

    Amer. Econ. Rev.

    (2013)
  • Cited by (25)

    • Bounded incentives in manipulating the probabilistic serial rule

      2024, Journal of Computer and System Sciences
    • Strategy-proof and envy-free random assignment

      2023, Journal of Economic Theory
    • A pessimist's approach to one-sided matching

      2023, European Journal of Operational Research
    • Minimal envy and popular matchings

      2022, European Journal of Operational Research
      Citation Excerpt :

      Frequent non-existence of popular matchings is a major problem of this otherwise desirable and natural concept. Provided existence, popularity stands in same row with Pareto efficiency and its other refinements such as the maximal-size matchings (Afacan, Bó, & Turhan, 2018; Afacan & Dur, 2018; Bogomolnaia & Moulin, 2004; 2015), the rank-efficient matchings (Abdulkadiroğlu & Sönmez, 2003; Featherstone, 2015) and welfare-maximizing matchings (Biró & Gudmundsson, 2020). We propose a constructive extension of popular matchings that always exists.

    View all citing articles on Scopus

    We are especially grateful to our colleagues David Manlove and Baharak Rastegari for introducing us to their research project EPSRC Grant# EP/K010042/1, and sharing the results already obtained with their colleagues at the University of Liverpool. Special thanks also to Jay Sethuraman for guiding us through the literature on online matching, and to Bettina Klaus, Tadashi Hashimoto, and seminar participants in Warwick, Manchester and Toulouse, for stimulating conversations. The comments of three anonymous referees have been very helpful.

    View full text