Elsevier

Ecological Economics

Volume 154, December 2018, Pages 211-217
Ecological Economics

Analysis
The Endogenous Evolution of Common Property Management Systems

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2018.08.007Get rights and content

Highlights

  • Common pool resource regulations typically apply uniformly to all users.

  • An emerging alternative allows sub-groups of users to manage an allocation.

  • When a group selects individual property right, higher profits attract other users.

  • Taste for competition limits complete adoption of individual property rights.

  • A weak collective right with a self-governance pathway can facilitate efficiency.

Abstract

Traditional co-management of common property resources involves stakeholders contributing knowledge and ideas about rules for access and extraction, which are analyzed and implemented by the regulator. We examine an emerging alternative system, in which self-identifying clubs of users are allocated a share of a total allowable extraction, that they manage with considerable autonomy. When multiple clubs concurrently extract under different self-selected rules, users gravitate toward more profitable regulations in subsequent seasons, putting evolutionary pressure on less profitable systems. We show experimentally that strong individual property rights, and the efficiencies associated with them, emerge endogenously from this process. A taste for competition among some individuals limits realized efficiency, but not extensive adoption of individual rights. Thus, regulators need not directly implement strong individual rights to achieve their benefits; regulators may instead assign a collective property right and provide a self-governance pathway toward management that supports better outcomes.

Introduction

In order to leverage the local knowledge and legitimacy benefits of involving resource users in the governance process (McCay and Acheson, 1987; Ostrom, 1990; Ostrom et al., 1999), managers have worked to formally engage users in co-management processes that identify regulations that govern access to and exploitation of water, forests and fisheries. These processes allow regulations to incorporate the needs and preferences that dominate within user communities (Agrawal, 1994; Blomquist, 1994; Blomquist, 1992; Trawick, 2001). However, uniform regulations, by their nature, do not reflect heterogeneity in user preferences over management methods, which may impede implementation of effective community management.

An emerging approach to co-management seeks to reflect differences among users by allowing sub-groups to claim collective resource use allocations, which they can manage with considerable flexibility. For example, outcomes improved among Mexican forest ejidos when individual communities were allowed to self-determine configurations of private and collective rights systems (Barnes, 2009; Barsimantov et al., 2010). Fisheries that allocate target or non-target harvest quota to cooperatives experienced better bycatch management (e.g., Abbott et al., 2015; Stram and Ianelli, 2015) or improved safety (North Pacific Fishery Management Council, 2016; Pfeiffer and Gratz, 2016). Increased profitability was observed among subsets of users who manage a collective allocation, while others participate in a common pool (e.g., Georges Bank Cod Fixed Gear Sector, 2010; Knapp, 2008; Pinto Da Silva and Kitts, 2006; Scheld et al., 2012; Verani, 2006).

The Northeast (US) Multispecies Groundfish Fishery is extending this approach by encouraging the formation of multiple “sectors”, or new self-identifying clubs of users. Importantly, cooperative self-governance has not emerged in this fishery, and harvesters preferring a competitive fishery have politically blocked efforts by other harvesters to establish fishery-wide individual quota allocations (Scheld and Anderson, 2014; Scheld et al., 2012). Sectors, however, can manage their allocated shares—proportional to their joining members' historical share of catch—in different ways while pursuing the same resource. Thus, harvesters pursuing individual allocations can form a sector and subdivide their collective allocation, while those preferring competitive pursuit can do so with their allocation, allowing innovation without establishing a political consensus for any particular change (Jenkins et al., 2017). The Multispecies fishery has seen improvements in economic outcomes (Scheld and Anderson, 2014) and social capital (Holland et al., 2015), raising the general question of whether and how innovations can effectively diffuse among sectors exercising autonomy beyond the specific control of regulators. This diffusion does not require coordination within or among sectors; users can simply switch to a sector that uses a different system, taking their associated allocation with them. Effective management strategies can expand in two ways: when additional sectors adopt them, or when users switch into sectors using them.

This policy experiment is unfolding in the absence of a framework for predicting the properties of the management that will emerge. There is no general theory of institutional selection, and previous experimental work has focused on the emergence of market institutions (Crockett et al., 2009; Jaworski and Wilson, 2013; Kimbrough et al., 2008). As such collective catch share programs expand, it is necessary to predict the evolution of self-management, to support biological and social evaluation mandated through the Regulatory Impact Review process. Given the range of alternative institutions, and potential mechanisms through which they might emerge and transform, addressing this need comprehensively requires a broad research program.

As a first step, we investigate individual resource users' choice of a management system under a certain circumstance, which mirrors a number of recent catch share programs in US (Scheld and Anderson, 2014; cf., Georges Bank Cod Fixed Gear Sector, 2010; Pinto Da Silva and Kitts, 2006; Scheld et al., 2012; Verani, 2006). Specifically, the role of expected profitability is highlighted, when resource users are presented with a choice between an institution that provides a secure individual extraction right, and an institution with competitive extraction. The Rhode Island Fluke Sector Pilot Program is a representative example (Scheld and Anderson, 2014), featuring a club managed by individual quota, and a limited entry derby for other harvesters. We design a controlled economic experiment in which harvesters are allowed to choose whether to join the individual quota club before each season, drawing on their experiences from previous seasons. Communication within and between clubs is not allowed, reflecting the historic failure of New England fishermen—and stakeholders in many other fisheries—to coordinate collective action around improved management. We test the hypothesis that the individual quota system, which supports the efficient harvesting strategy as a Nash equilibrium (cf., Gürerk et al., 2006), yields higher profits and attracts more participants than the less restrictive common pool institution (e.g., Agrawal, 2002). If true, this would imply the eventual efficiency and distributional outcomes of decentralized, club-based management will be well predicted by models of an individual quota system. We then associate individual variation in the rate of moving to the individual quota system with individual social preferences, risk preferences, and a taste for competition.

Section snippets

Continuous Fishing Game

A two-stage sequential game is repeated for 20 “seasons.” In the first stage, all players simultaneously choose to join one of two clubs: an individual quota (IQ) club—where each player receives their quota share as individual allocation—or a common pool (CP) club—where the quota associated with each player is placed in a pool to be competitively harvested by all players choosing CP. Players then learn how many others are in each club, and in the second stage, earn money fishing under the rules

Results

Fig. 1 shows the frequency of subjects' choosing IQ rises from 51.9% (SE = 3.4%) in the first two seasons to over 80% of subjects in the last two seasons (mean = 83.3%; SE = 2.5%). 43.5% (SE = 4.8%) of the subjects consistently chose IQ during the last ten seasons. A small portion of the subjects, 4.6% (SE = 2.0%), never tried CP management and remained in IQ throughout the session. Only 13.9% (SE = 3.3%) of subjects persistently—twice or more in the last five seasons—chose CP after they had

Discussion

The first year of collective rights allocation in the Northeast Multispecies Groundfish fishery saw 17 self-governing sectors form, along with the common pool of fishermen who chose to compete for landings (Kitts et al., 2011). Most sectors used some form of individual transferable quota, despite the fact that fishery-wide individual transferable quotas were considered politically infeasible. In our experiment, an overwhelming majority of subjects moved systematically toward the institution

Acknowledgments

This work was funded by the Policy Simulation Laboratory at the University of Rhode Island. M.W. acknowledges a scholarship from the Joint Japan/World Bank Graduate Scholarship Program (JJ/WBGSP).

References (44)

  • J.K. Abbott et al.

    Hidden flexibility: institutions, incentives, and the margins of selectivity in fishing

    Land Econ.

    (2015)
  • A. Agrawal

    Rules, rule making, and rule breaking: examining the fit between rule systems and resource use

  • A. Agrawal

    Common resources and institutional sustainability

  • C.M. Anderson et al.

    An experimental examination of fisheries with concurrent common pool and individual quota management

    Econ. Inq.

    (2014)
  • G. Barnes

    The evolution and resilience of community-based land tenure in rural Mexico

    Land Use Policy

    (2009)
  • J.A. Barsimantov et al.

    Tenure, tourism and timber in Quintana Roo, Mexico: land tenure changes in forest Ejidos after agrarian reforms

    Int. J. Commons

    (2010)
  • A.M. Birkenbach et al.

    Catch shares slow the race to fish

    Nature

    (2017)
  • W.A. Blomquist

    Dividing the Waters: Governing Groundwater in Southern California

    (1992)
  • W. Blomquist

    Changing rules, changing games: evidence from groundwater systems in southern California

  • C. Camerer et al.

    Anomalies: ultimatums, dictators and manners

    J. Econ. Perspect.

    (1995)
  • C. Costello et al.

    Global fishery prospects under contrasting management regimes

    Proc. Natl. Acad. Sci.

    (2016)
  • S. Crockett et al.

    Exchange and specialisation as a discovery process*

    Econ. J.

    (2009)
  • E. Fehr et al.

    A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation

    Q. J. Econ.

    (1999)
  • H. Fell

    Ex-vessel pricing and IFQs: a strategic approach

    Mar. Resour. Econ.

    (2009)
  • R. Gardner et al.

    Probabilistic destruction of common-pool resources: experimental evidence

    Econ. J.

    (1992)
  • R. Gardner et al.

    Governing a groundwater commons: a strategic and laboratory analysis of western water law

    Econ. Inq.

    (1997)
  • Georges Bank Cod Fixed Gear Sector

    Georges Bank Cod Fixed Gear Sector: A Final Environmental Assessment

  • Ö. Gürerk et al.

    The competitive advantage of sanctioning institutions

    Science

    (2006)
  • R.L. Helmreich et al.

    Work and family orientation questionnaire: an objective instrument to assess components of achievement motivation and attitudes toward family and career

    JSAS Cat. Sel. Doc. Psychol.

    (1978)
  • D.S. Holland et al.

    Evolution of social capital and economic performance in New England harvest cooperatives

    Mar. Resour. Econ.

    (2015)
  • C.A. Holt et al.

    Risk aversion and incentive effects

    Am. Econ. Rev.

    (2002)
  • J. Houston et al.

    Revising the competitiveness index using factor analysis

    Psychol. Rep.

    (2002)
  • Cited by (3)

    • A bargaining experiment under weak property rights, with implications for indigenous title claims

      2022, Ecological Economics
      Citation Excerpt :

      Given power disparities and the lack of clear rules, newcomers' activities imposed negative externalities on others, including indigenous peoples. Strong property rights tend to emerge as the result of an evolutionary process (Alston et al., 2012; Wakamatsu and Anderson, 2018), but institutional changes take time, especially given the unique relationship between indigenous tribes and governments (Nemoto, 2002). Without the guardrail of private property rights, Aboriginals lacked the ability to shape or reject the development process and to be compensated for the loss of traditional land and resources.

    • Who's onboard? A predictive analysis of cooperative formation in commercial fisheries

      2021, Journal of Environmental Management
      Citation Excerpt :

      Many other fisheries, including the New England Sector fleets and U.K. Producers Organizations, manage allocations in ways that increase the profitability of individual fishing operations, but do not collectively improve the profitability and sustainability of the fishery—an important distinction for co-management performance (Acheson and Gardner 2014). Wakamatsu and Anderson (2018) showed that even incomplete participation in sector allocations (operators may opt to participate in an unallocated, competitive portion of the fishery) may spread effort and increase incomes for all participants, but they note that “cooperative self-governance has not emerged”. The New England and U.K. examples highlight that beyond a simple legal definition, there are significant differences between both organizations and regions in levels of coordination and co-management, ranging from proactive efforts to coordinate fishing effort to increase fleet-wide profitability at one extreme, to roughly business as usual under new regulatory constraints at the other.

    • Seasonal Harvest Patterns in Multispecies Fisheries

      2020, Environmental and Resource Economics
    View full text