Elsevier

Ecological Economics

Volume 131, January 2017, Pages 533-537
Ecological Economics

Structured pluralism in ecological economics — A reply to Peter Söderbaum's commentary

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2016.08.022Get rights and content

Abstract

Peter Söderbaum argues in his commentary, concerning my article on sustainability economics (Remig 2015), for more open and radical ecological economics. I agree with that statement. However, I reject Söderbaum's interpretation that my arguments foster mainstreamed ecological economics or dictatorship. In my critique of sustainability economics, I raised several issues that have remained unspecified and that potentially lead to unsustainable development patterns, once put into practice. Söderbaum does not reply to these conceptual challenges of sustainability economics. In this commentary, I argue that “structured pluralism” (Dow, 2004) is a constituent element of ecological economics. I welcome Peter Söderbaum's proposal for a discussion about the definition of economics and suggest to rely on Ronald Coase's proposal to define economics as a science that studies the working of the economic system. I conclude that sustainability economics in its current form is closer to neoclassical than ecological economics.

Introduction

Ecological economics is, up to now, the relevant school of an economic analysis of sustainable development and socio-ecological systems. It has established a community, journals, societies, conferences, and chairs at universities. During the existence of the field for more than a quarter of a century – with roots that reach back far further (Martinez-Alier, 1990) – there have always been discussions where the academic discipline should evolve to. One of the most recent discussions is the one about sustainability economics proposed by Baumgärtner and Quaas, 2010a, Baumgärtner and Quaas, 2010b. Söderbaum (2015) replied to my survey article on sustainability economics (Remig, 2015). I welcome the opportunity to continue the discussion about sustainability and ecological economics. I agree with many points Peter Söderbaum raises in his article. Nevertheless, I disagree with some of his core ideas.

I strongly reject his claim that my argument leads to unified, “mainstreamed” ecological economics and dictatorship (Söderbaum, 2015, p. 423). In my critique of sustainability economics, I raised several conceptual issues that have remained unspecified and that potentially result in unsustainable development patterns, once put into practice. Therefore, we need to develop a strong and sound theoretical founding for ecological economics and for sustainability economics. Söderbaum (2015) does not contribute to unravel the veil of fuzziness around the concept of sustainability and unfortunately misreads my argument: “In this community [of ecological economists] we should, according to Remig, reduce all versions of ecological economics to one paradigm which is clearly specified and presented.” (p.420) On the contrary, my image of the “big tent” of ecological economics (Howarth, 2008, Spash and Ryan, 2012) illustrates the co-existence of varieties of ecological economics that have developed in contrast to the monolithic version of neoclassical economics. I fully agree with Söderbaum's (2015, p. 420) main argument “that it is natural and more constructive to expect ‘varieties of economics’ and also ‘varieties of ecological economics’.” Thus, I here argue for a “structured pluralism” (Dow, 2004) in ecological economics.

As I highlighted in my review paper (Remig, 2015), the relationship between sustainability economics and ecological economics is conceived differently by different authors in the debate. Diverse methodological and ontological foundations of sustainability economics thus co-exist. Söderbaum (2015) sees in the new concept a promising term: “I somehow felt that ‘sustainability economics’ was an appropriate term for more radical versions of ecological economics. I certainly accept that other ecological economists may use the term differently or may prefer to abandon it altogether.” (p.423) Even though Baumgärtner and Quaas (2010a) also see in sustainability economics an alternative to ecological economics, I doubt that they share Söderbaum's understanding about sustainability economics. Their idea is less critical and less radical than current ecological economics because they borrow much more from neoclassical resource and environmental economics (see Section 4).

In the following, I respond to several other points, Peter Söderbaum raised. I agree that a discussion about the definition of economics is necessary and propose to refer to Ronald Coase's systemic understanding of economics (Section 2). I also argue that structured pluralism is a core feature of ecological economics (Section 3). By comparing neoclassical, sustainability, and ecological economics, I conclude that Baumgärtner and Quaas' understanding of sustainability economics is closer to neoclassical than to ecological economics (Section 4).

Section snippets

Defining Economics

I agree with Peter Söderbaum that a discussion about the definition of economics is required. Baumgärtner and Quaas (2010a, pp. 446-447) build their idea of sustainability economics on Robbins' definition of economics, i.e. the economics' mainstream definition: economics “studies human behaviour as a relationship between [given] ends and scarce means which have alternative uses” (Robbins, 2007 [1932]).

Yet, this definition is not without caveats: ¨The methodology of neoclassical economics

Structured Pluralism in Ecological Economics

I very much welcome pluralism in ecological economics. We know to value diversity not least because of our interest in resilient social-ecological systems. Norgaard (1989) provides a very convincing argument why pluralism is required: “ecological economics will more likely evolve into a useful discipline if it maintains the breadth of the methodological base of economics and ecology and reaches out to the methodologies of other disciplines as well.” (p.53) To Peter Söderbaum's question whether

Why Sustainability Economics Has More in Common With Neoclassical Than Ecological Economics

To Peter Söderbaum, sustainability economics is a term more radical than ecological economics. Different definitions of the term coexist. I take this opportunity to further develop my argument by comparing neoclassical, sustainability, and ecological economics. When I refer in the following to sustainability economics, I use the term as specified by Baumgärtner and Quaas. Whether you are a neoclassical, a sustainability or an ecological economist changes the way in which you proceed your

Conclusion

The debate about sustainability economics, triggered by Baumgärtner and Quaas (2010a), has led to a number of publications that discuss various aspects of sustainable development and ecological economics. Söderbaum (2015) has written a commentary to my review paper (Remig, 2015). I agree with many of his arguments and join his call that we need more radical ecological economics. I also agree that a discussion about the definition of economics is relevant for ecological economics. To Peter

References (65)

  • T. Kronenberg

    Finding common ground between ecological economics and post-Keynesian economics

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2010)
  • R.M. M'Gonigle

    Ecological economics and political ecology: towards a necessary synthesis

    Ecol. Econ.

    (1999)
  • A. Müller

    A flower in full blossom? Ecological economics at the crossroads between normal and post-normal science

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2003)
  • R.B. Norgaard

    The case for methodological pluralism

    Ecol. Econ.

    (1989)
  • J. Paavola et al.

    Institutional ecological economics

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2005)
  • M.C. Remig

    Unraveling the veil of fuzziness: a thick description of sustainability economics

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2015)
  • I. Røpke

    The early history of modern ecological economics

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2004)
  • I. Røpke

    Trends in the development of ecological economics from the late 1980s to the early 2000s

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2005)
  • P. Söderbaum

    Varieties of ecological economics: do we need a more open and radical version of ecological economics?

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2015)
  • C.L. Spash

    New foundations for ecological economics

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2012)
  • S.W.F. Van der Ploeg et al.

    Integration of resource economics and ecology

    Ecol. Model.

    (1987)
  • A. Voinov et al.

    Reconciling sustainability, systems theory and discounting

    Ecol. Econ.

    (2007)
  • R.E. Backhouse et al.

    Defining economics: the long road to acceptance of the Robbins definition

    Economica

    (2009)
  • D. Barkin et al.

    La significación de una Economía Ecológica radical

    Rev. Iberoam. Econ. Ecol.

    (2012)
  • F. Beckenbach

    Beschränkte Rationalität und Systemkomplexität: Ein Beitrag zur Ökologischen Ökonomik

    (2001)
  • M. Bonaiuti

    Introduction: Georgescu-Roegen, the man and scientist

  • R.H. Coase

    The problem of social cost

    J. Law Econ.

    (1960)
  • R.H. Coase

    The coase theorem and the empty core: a comment

    J. Law Econ.

    (1981)
  • R.H. Coase

    The Firm, the Market, and the Law

    (1988)
  • R.H. Coase

    Essays on Economics and Economists: University of Chicago Press

    (1995)
  • R. Coase

    The new institutional economics

    Am. Econ. Rev.

    (1998)
  • D. Colander

    What was it that Robbins was defining?

    J. Hist. Econ. Thought

    (2009)
  • Cited by (3)

    • Can social ecological economics of water reinforce the “big tent”?

      2020, Ecological Economics
      Citation Excerpt :

      Indeed, some members of the community claim for ecological economics as a post-normal science (Funtowicz and Ravetz, 1994; Müller, 2003), whereas others promote “institutional ecological economics” (Paavola and Adger, 2005; Vatn, 2009), a “deliberative ecological economics” (Howarth and Zografos, 2008), a “coevolutionary ecological economics” (Kallis and Norgaard, 2010) or an “ecological economics from below” based on heterodox and Marxian approaches (Burkett, 2006; Fuente Carrasco et al., 2019), among many other options (Remig, 2017). The pluralism expressed within the community is evidenced by the recent debate between Remig (2015, 2017) and Söderbaum (2015) on the unified and radical nature of ecological economics with regard to mainstream economics. The latter denounces the attempt at “mainstreaming” the “big tent” of ecological economics (Howarth, 2008: 469),2 while the former considers that sustainability economics, as it is shaped, cannot claim to found a radical branch of ecological economics.

    • A History of Ecological Economic Thought

      2022, A History of Ecological Economic Thought
    • Research on Digital Inclusive Finance Promoting the Integration of Rural Three-Industry

      2022, International Journal of Environmental Research and Public Health
    View full text