Elsevier

Ecological Economics

Volume 57, Issue 2, 1 May 2006, Pages 253-268
Ecological Economics

Analysis
Sustainable development in a post-Brundtland world

https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ecolecon.2005.04.013Get rights and content

Abstract

Not yet two decades after the publication of Our Common Future, the world's political and environmental landscape has changed significantly. Nonetheless, we argue that the concept and practice of sustainable development (SD)–as guiding institutional principle, as concrete policy goal, and as focus of political struggle–remains salient in confronting the multiple challenges of this new global order. Yet how SD is conceptualized and practiced hinges crucially on: the willingness of scholars and practitioners to embrace a plurality of epistemological and normative perspectives on sustainability; the multiple interpretations and practices associated with the evolving concept of “development”; and efforts to open up a continuum of local-to-global public spaces to debate and enact a politics of sustainability. Embracing pluralism provides a way out of the ideological and epistemological straightjackets that deter more cohesive and politically effective interpretations of SD. Using pluralism as a starting point for the analysis and normative construction of sustainable development, we pay particular attention to how an amalgam of ideas from recent work in ecological economics, political ecology and the “development as freedom” literature might advance the SD debate beyond its post-Brundtland quagmire. Enhanced levels of ecological degradation, vast inequalities in economic opportunities both within and across societies, and a fractured set of institutional arrangements for global environmental governance all represent seemingly insurmountable obstacles to a move towards sustainability. While these obstacles are significant, we suggest how they might be overcome through a reinvigorated set of notions and practices associated with sustainable development, one that explicitly examines the linkages between sustainability policies and sustainability politics.

Introduction

The publication of Our Common Future in 1987 marked a watershed in thinking on environment, development, and governance. The UN-sponsored World Commission on Environment and Development (WCED), led by Gro Harlem Brundtland, issued a bold call to recalibrate institutional mechanisms at global, national and local levels to promote economic development that would guarantee “the security, well-being, and very survival of the planet” (WCED, 1987, p. 23). The call for sustainable development was a redirection of the enlightenment project, a pragmatic response to the problems of the times. While the broad goals were widely embraced, critics argued that steps toward their implementation would be thwarted; first, by fundamental contradictions between the renewed call for economic growth in developing countries and enhanced levels of ecological conservation; and, second, by the inattention to power relations among the local-to-global actors and institutions supporting unsustainable development (see Lélé, 1991, The Ecologist, 1991). In retrospect, 18 years later, the critics appear to be more or less correct. While more attention is being given now to the environmental consequences of particular development projects, the primary drivers of environmental degradation–energy and material use–have burgeoned. The cooperative global environmental governance regime envisioned at the 1992 Earth Summit in Rio is still in an institutional incubator while neoliberal economic globalization has become fully operational (Haque, 1999). And inequalities in access to economic opportunities have dramatically increased within and between most societies, making pragmatic governance toward social and environmental goals increasingly difficult. Why then revisit an effort that was, in many ways, so poorly conceived and that has been so overwhelmed by history?

First, Our Common Future focused on the critical issues of equity and environment and raised important ethical considerations regarding human-environment relationships (Langhelle, 1999) that remain highly relevant. The decline in equity and environmental quality since this report should certainly give pause to proponents and critics alike; the failure to stem the tide of unsustainable human activities can be linked to both ineffective institutions and a general lack of political will on the part of governments and citizens at multiples scales. The rise in our scientific understanding of climate change and other global biophysical transformations and their profound implications for the health of the planet, along with the increasing awareness that solutions will have to address vast inequities in human development capabilities, underscores this point. Thus, the concept and practice of sustainable development (SD)–as guiding institutional principle, as concrete policy goal, and as focus of political struggle–remains salient in confronting the multiple challenges of our new global context.

Second, Our Common Future marked, anchored, and guided the rise of a remarkable political debate, indeed a whole new political discourse across contesting interests, from grounded practitioners to philosophical academics, from indigenous peoples to multinational corporations. Sustainability may yet be possible if sufficient numbers of scholars, practitioners and political actors embrace a plurality of approaches to and perspectives on sustainability, accept multiple interpretations and practices associated with an evolving concept of “development”, and support a further opening up of local-to-global public spaces to debate and enact a politics of sustainability. Ecological economics and other transdisciplinary modes of knowledge production are vital to such endeavors.

The historical developments since the publication of Our Common Future bring us to the third point. The early critics of the Brundtland Report did not foresee the decline in the legitimacy of authoritative science or the rise of a more discursive, democratic science. They did not predict the breakdown in the philosophical underpinnings of the market paradigm or the grass-roots opposition to globalization. They did not anticipate the rise of ecological economics and political ecology or the new thinking generally in the social sciences stimulated by failures of equating development with economic growth.

The critics of sustainable development also did not foresee important socio-cultural changes, exemplified by the rise of fundamentalist beliefs and activism, both political and violent, across religious movements, around the world (Almond et al., 2003). While many recognize the rejection of modernity by Islamic fundamentalists and its impact on the development of nations in the Middle East, scholars are almost in denial of the influence of fundamentalist beliefs–or more broadly the “politics of particularistic identities” (Kaldor, 2001, p. 70)–on the politics of the United States, India, and Israel. Fundamentalists do not accept the separation of church, state (and economy), and science. Their religious beliefs determine their values, what they accept as knowledge, and their understanding of appropriate social order. This rejection of religious tolerance, democratic politics, and the role of science is a serious challenge to the enlightenment project, and to people's future on earth. Culturally and politically significant fundamentalisms have arisen, especially within the United States in the late twentieth century, in part due to the “strategic promotion” of a narrowly rational ideology of individualism and competitiveness by the central state and business, which in turn “has produced an accompanying ubiquitous yearning among individuals for social connection and ‘meaning’ in their lives” (Szreter, 2002, p. 607). This yen for social connection has been realized, in part, through the rise of evangelical religious groups, which “tend to be defensive, identity-protecting, self-buttressing forms of bonding social capital, not expansive generous forms of connections with others, who are not like oneself” (Ibid.). The rise of fundamentalisms can thus be tied directly to contemporary social and cultural politics, and can also be seen as evidence of the failure of the modern separation of values, facts, and politics that our own proposal for a renewed approach to sustainable development (SD) addresses.

In light of these widespread socio-cultural transformations, this paper offers rationales for renewed focus on SD as an important discourse that still can help us sort through the hoary environment and development dilemmas of today. A more explicit emphasis on the normative aspects of research, a rigorous understanding of freedom-oriented (as opposed to growth-oriented) development, and an explicit recognition of the critical role of politics inform our understanding of how to push the notion of SD forward into more fruitful conceptual and pragmatic territory1.

We continue with, first, a discussion of the Brundtland Report's crucial arguments and an attempt to place them within the context of political-economic and institutional changes in global society that have transpired in the years since the document's publication. We also pay attention to the ways in which a Brundtland-defined notion of SD has been both supported and deconstructed in subsequent debates. Next, we advance the case for pluralism (Norgaard, 1989) in the analysis and normative construction of sustainable development, highlighting how an amalgam of ideas from recent work in ecological economics, political ecology, and freedom-oriented development might advance the SD debate beyond its post-Brundtland quagmire. A pluralistic, critical approach to sustainable development offers fresh interpretations of intractable environment-development dilemmas. We conclude with an outline of possible routes towards a pluralistic, theoretically informed praxis of sustainable development based on a renewed commitment to practices of deliberative democracy.

Section snippets

Our common future in a turbulent world

The Brundtland Report serves as a vital historical marker for several reasons. First, Brundtland's definition of sustainable development–invoking the needs of future generations counterbalanced to the current unmet needs of much of the world's population–is the most widely accepted starting point for scholars and practitioners concerned with environment and development dilemmas. Second, Brundtland signals the emergence of “the environment” as a critically important facet of international

Unity in plurality? Transcending SD and its critics

How might scholars, development practitioners, environmental managers, sustainability advocates and government planners better confront the turbulent and uncertain conditions that constitute the post-Brundtland world? To move toward a response, this section undertakes, first, an examination of the conceptual evolution of SD since Brundtland, focusing in particular on how both proponents and critics have framed their understandings of SD6

Prospects for sustainability in the post-Brundtland global order

Burgeoning levels of energy consumption, enhanced levels of ecological degradation, a growing public mistrust of science, vast inequalities in economic opportunities both within and across societies, and a fractured set of institutional arrangements for global environmental governance; all represent seemingly insurmountable obstacles to a move towards sustainability. During the nearly 20 years since Brundtland, the world is a vastly different place, in part because of Brundtland but largely

References (105)

  • R. Muradian et al.

    Trade and environment: from a ‘Southern’ perspective

    Ecological Economics

    (2001)
  • A. Nelson

    The poverty of money: Marxian insights for ecological economists

    Ecological Economics

    (2001)
  • R.B. Norgaard

    The case for methodological pluralism

    Ecological Economics

    (1989)
  • R.B. Norgaard

    Learning and knowing collectively

    Ecological Economics

    (2004)
  • S.U. O'Hara

    Discursive ethics in ecosystem valuation and environmental policy

    Ecological Economics

    (1996)
  • E. Padilla

    Intergenerational equity and sustainability

    Ecological Economics

    (2002)
  • G. Peterson

    Political ecology and ecological resilience: an integration of human and ecological dynamics

    Ecological Economics

    (2000)
  • J. Robinson

    Squaring the circle? Some thoughts on the idea of sustainable development

    Ecological Economics

    (2004)
  • T. Shi

    Ecological economics as a policy science: rhetoric or commitment towards an improved decision-making process on sustainability

    Ecological Economics

    (2004)
  • C. Spash

    Ecosystems, contingent valuation and ethics: the case of wetland re-creation

    Ecological Economics

    (2000)
  • J. Agyeman et al.

    Towards just sustainability in urban communities: building equity rights with sustainable solutions

    Annals of American Academy of Political and Social Science

    (2003)
  • G.A. Almond et al.

    Strong Religion: the Rise of Fundamentalism Around the World

    (2003)
  • L. Amorre et al.

    Overturning globalisation: resisting the teleological, reclaiming ‘the political’

  • G. Arrighi et al.

    Introduction

  • S. Bell et al.

    Sustainability indicators

    Measuring the Immeasurable

    (1999)
  • S. Bernstein

    Liberal environmentalism and global environmental governance

    Global Environmental Politics

    (2002)
  • K.A. Brekke et al.

    Status, Growth and the Environment: Goods as Symbols in Applied Welfare Economics

    (2002)
  • R. Bryant et al.

    Third World Political Ecology

    (1997)
  • P. Bukett

    The value problem in ecological economics: lessons from the physiocrats and Marx

    Organization and Environment

    (2003)
  • J. Burg

    The World Summit on Sustainable Development: empty talk or call to action?

    Journal of Environment and Development

    (2003)
  • W. Clark
  • K. Conca

    The WTO and the undermining of global environmental governance

    Review of International Political Economy

    (2000)
  • R. Costanza et al.

    The value of the world's ecosystem services and natural capital

    Nature

    (1997)
  • H. Daly et al.

    Ecological Economics: Principles and Applications

    (2004)
  • N.K. Dawe et al.

    The faulty three-legged stool model of sustainable development

    Conservation Biology

    (2003)
  • D. Demeritt

    What is the ‘social construction of nature’? A typology and sympathetic critique

    Progress in Human Geography

    (2002)
  • I. Drummond et al.

    The Condition of Sustainability

    (1999)
  • J. Dryzek

    Transnational democracy

    The Journal of Political Philosophy

    (1999)
  • J. Dryzek

    Deliberative Democracy and Beyond: Liberals, Critics, Contestations

    (2000)
  • R. Eckersley

    Markets, the state and the environment: an overview

  • J. Emel et al.

    Resource management and natural hazards

  • A. Escobar

    Encountering Development: the Making and Unmaking of the Third World

    (1995)
  • A. Escobar

    Constructing nature: elements for a poststructural political ecology

  • J. Fernando

    The power of unsustainable development: what is to be done?

    Annals of the American Association of Political and Social Sciences

    (2003)
  • F. Fischer

    Citizens, Experts, and the Environment: the Politics of Local Knowledge

    (2000)
  • Cited by (0)

    View full text