Elsevier

World Development

Volume 29, Issue 5, May 2001, Pages 841-863
World Development

What Does the `Show Case' Show? Evidence of and Lessons from Adjustment in Uganda

https://doi.org/10.1016/S0305-750X(01)00007-9Get rights and content

Abstract

Uganda is often seen as an African show case for the beneficial effects of structural adjustment. High growth rates have been combined with a high degree of “ownership” of the reforms. At the same time, critics have pointed to continued aid dependence, and limited growth of the important agricultural export sector. The contribution of this paper to this debate is three-fold. First, “ownership” has not always been exemplary and is still fragile in some respects. Second, although aid has indeed been important for bringing about high growth, aid dependence has diminished over time. Third, there have been real supply responses from the agricultural export sector.

Introduction

Uganda is often seen as an African show case for the beneficial effects of structural adjustment and economic reforms, while the Ugandan experience is also commented upon skeptically. On the positive side, we find an evaluation of International Monetary Fund (IMF) policy based lending stating confidently that:

Uganda has evidently been successful both in terms of stabilization and growth. Over the decade the economy was transformed from a stagnant, subsistence orientation to an economy that enjoyed fast growth. Although there were continuous Fund programs through the decade, most of the key decisions were taken by the government on its own initiative (Botchwey, Collier, Gunning, & Hamada, 1998, p. 87).

Apart from its high growth rate (around 6% annually since 1987), Uganda is praised for its high degree of “ownership” of reforms. This usually means that donors and recipient government converge on the reform package to be carried out. Holmgren, Kasekende, Atingi-Ego, and Ddamulira (1999) depict the relationship between Uganda and the donor community in a similar vein as one smooth process. This contrasts sharply with another view by Himbara and Sultan (1995), who depict Uganda as a new Bantustan which is controlled by funds and personnel from the outside: “In the process donor control has extended over the full range of policy mechanisms, feasibility research, project implementations and management of key elements of the Ugandan state” (Himbara & Sultan, 1995, p. 90).1

Recently, the quality of the Ugandan growth has also been challenged. Belshaw, Lawrence, and Hubbard (1999) have two main points of critique. First, they do not think that macroeconomic stabilization has diminished the structural weaknesses of the Ugandan economy. They point to a widening gap in the balance of trade, where imports have grown more than exports. In their view, the macroeconomic stabilization which Uganda has achieved is dependent upon foreign aid and has resulted in an increasing external indebtedness. Second, the fundamental weakness which they discern behind these reservations is the lack of a significant supply response in the agricultural sector.

This article challenges a number of conclusions drawn in these debates. We do not dispute that there is a growing trade gap and increased indebtedness in Uganda and that this is related to foreign aid inflows. These do not indicate structural weaknesses in the economy, however, but are to a large extent the consequence of accounting for foreign aid in the economy. A fixation on trade deficit and debt obscures the positive effects of foreign aid, in particular, on stabilization and economic growth. The growth in the Ugandan economy has not been ephemeral either: There have been significant supply responses in the Ugandan economy. These are related to macroeconomic stabilization, to the liberalization of the foreign exchange market and to the liberalization of markets in agricultural produce.

In addition, we think that the degree of consensus between the donor community and the Ugandan government has been overstated, especially if we consider the period before 1993. Policy dialogue or the conditionalities of aid—different words are used depending upon the position in the debate—have played a role in bringing about stabililization and economic reforms. Currently, there is a genuine consensus in two crucial areas: strict control of the government budget and the dismantling of the parastatal and cooperative marketing structures. These reforms have had beneficial effects, and as such they are beyond political debate: it is politically advantageous to identify with success. It may therefore be better to view the relationships between Uganda and the donor community in terms other than domination or cooptation. Donor pressure may have resulted in taking decisions to which there was resistance, but which proved to be beneficial for the whole of society. Important collective choice issues in Ugandan society—notably controlling the government budget and dismantling the parastatal and cooperative marketing structures—can thus be seen as resolved in a policy dialogue with the donor community.

This paper therefore first discusses the relationship between Uganda and the donor community over time, as this is fundamental in the whole problematic. We distinguish two periods, 1987–92 and 1992–98. In the first period, aid was not accompanied with strict conditionalities and few economic reforms were undertaken. In the second period, the government became committed to monetary stability, and many structural reforms were carried out—although sometimes with delays and not always to the full satisfaction of the donor community. Thereafter, we analyze the effects of aid funds on macroeconomic developments. Aid contributed to growth and stabilization in both periods. But in the first period, the achievement of law and order was a major factor in economic growth, while the reforms had a positive influence on growth in the second. The latter half of this paper analyzes the most significant supply responses that have taken place and identifies the links with economic reform.

Although we think that aid and economic reforms have been beneficial to Uganda, this does not mean that we are blind to weaknesses in the Ugandan economy. These weaknesses are, however, of a different nature than those usually identified. First, the capacity of the Ugandan government to contain political demands is crucial in controlling government expenditure. It may be that the limitations on political competition—Uganda, with its no-party system, may be called a one-party state—have made this curtailment of demands possible. Second, the supply response to liberalization may have run its course. Slack capacity in the economy has been taken into production and further growth requires investments, which are often constrained by poverty at the level of the enterprise. Further growth may also depend upon more structural measures. In the conclusion, we address the question of whether and to what extent the Uganda experience is reproducible in other countries.

Section snippets

Donors and reforms

In 1987, the government of President Museveni—who had then recently come to power—announced its Economic Recovery Program.2 From then on, the IMF and the World Bank began to support Uganda with a

Foreign aid and macroeconomic performance

Uganda received large amounts of foreign aid during 1987–99. Aid increased from US$110 million in 1987–88 to an annual average of US$542 million between 1992–93 and 1996–97. As of 1989–90, total aid has almost always exceeded the value of the country's exports. Similarly, aid has exceeded total tax revenues. Therefore, aid has probably had a large impact on the economy. Some authors argue that “in spite of aid,” large trade deficits remain (Love, 1997; World Bank, 1995a). Belshaw et al. (1999)

The supply response in the agricultural sector

The main goal of aid, policy dialogue and structural adjustment is economic growth. Such growth is expected to come primarily from a supply response to liberalization of produce markets. In Africa, this means particularly growth in agriculture which is by far the biggest economic sector. Liberalization or free entry into markets—especially those for agricultural produce—brings an end to the extraction of rents by a parasitic state through restrictions and regulations. As a result, producers

Conclusion

An examination of the Ugandan case leads to some inescapable conclusions. After the economy stabilized with the help of aid funds, and after some crucial liberalizations, high growth rates returned and export performance improved considerably. This progress is rooted in marked improvements in the real economy: output in crops like coffee and tobacco rose higher than had previously ever been recorded, and new sectors emerged.

This success may be qualified depending upon the standards set: we have

Uncited reference

World Bank (1981).

References (42)

  • D Belshaw et al.

    Agricultural tradables and economic recovery in Uganda: the limitations of structural adjustment in practice

    World Development

    (1999)
  • D.G Maxwell

    Alternative food security strategy: a household analysis of urban agriculture in Kampla

    World Development

    (1995)
  • ADC-IDEA (1998). Sixth semi-annual/end of third year progress report: 1 April 1997–31 March. Kampala: Agribusiness...
  • W Allan

    The African husbandman

    (1965)
  • Botchwey, K., Collier, P., Gunning, J. W., & Hamada, K. (1998). External evaluation of the ESAF. Report by a Group of...
  • Bratton, M., & van de Walle, N. (1997). Neopatrimonial rule in Africa. In M. Bratton, N. van de Walle (Eds.),...
  • Brett, E. A. (1996). Uganda. In P. Engberg-Pedersen, P. Gibbon, P. Raikes, & L. Udholt (Eds.), Limits of adjustment in...
  • H Chenery et al.

    Foreign assistance and economic development

    American Economic Review

    (1966)
  • Collier, P. (1997). A commentary on the Ugandan economy. Mimeo. Oxford: Centre for the Study of African...
  • Ddumba-Ssentamu, J., Dijkstra, G., & van Donge, J. (1999). What does the showcase show? Programme Aid to Uganda. Sida...
  • M Doornbos

    Uganda: a Bantustan?

    Review of African Political Economy

    (1997)
  • Elson, D., & Evers, B. (1997). Gender aware country economic reports: Uganda. Working Paper 2. Manchester: University...
  • Gibbon, P., Havnevik, K. J., & Hermele, K. (1993). Uganda. In P. Gibbon, K. Havnevik, & K. Hermele (Eds.), A blighted...
  • Hansen, H. B., & Twaddle, M. (Eds.) (1988). Uganda now: Between decay and development. Oxford/Nairobi: James...
  • Hansen, H. B., & Twaddle, M. (Eds.) (1991) Changing Uganda: The dilemmas of structural adjustment and revolutionary...
  • Hansen, H. B., & Twaddle, M. (Eds.) (1998). Developing Uganda. Oxford and Kampala: James Currey/Fountain...
  • Harvey, C. Robinson, M. (1995). Economic reform and political liberalization in Uganda. IDS Research Report 20....
  • D Himbara et al.

    Reconstructing the Ugandan state and economy: the challenge of an international Bantustan

    Review of African Political Economy

    (1995)
  • Holmgren, T., Kasekende, L., Atingi-Ego, M., & Ddamulira, D. (1999). Aid and reform in Uganda, Country Case Study,...
  • Jamal, V. (1998). Changes in poverty patterns in Uganda. In H. B. Hansen., M. Twaddle (Eds.), Developing Uganda (pp....
  • L.A Kasekende et al.

    Impact of liberalization on key markets in sub-Saharan Africa: The case of Uganda

    Journal of International Development

    (1999)
  • Cited by (66)

    • Responding to the commodity boom with varieties of resource nationalism: a political economy explanation for the different routes taken by Africa's new oil producers

      2020, Extractive Industries and Society
      Citation Excerpt :

      Led by President Yoweri Museveni, the National Resistance Movement (NRM) established political stability through building a largely inclusive ruling coalition that co-opted political elites from most ethno-regional groups (Lindemann, 2011). Unopposed by organised social and political groups, and apparently driven by a genuine ideological commitment to democracy and development, President Museveni undertook a series of radical economic and political reforms, which, alongside major external support, had a largely positive effect in terms of economic growth and poverty reduction (Dijkstra and van Donge, 2001). This was underpinned by a deal between the executive and leading bureaucrats that gave the Bank of Uganda and the Ministry of Finance the autonomy and capacity to operate as ‘pockets of effectiveness’, which in turn was critical to establishing the conditions for macroeconomic stability and growth (Tumusiime-Mutebile, 2010).

    • Political autonomy and resistance in electricity sector liberalization in Africa

      2019, World Development
      Citation Excerpt :

      Uganda is recognized as having applied more of the standard model of electricity reform than most African countries (Kapika & Eberhard, 2013, p. 8). Indeed, roughly since President Yoweri Museveni came to power in 1986, Uganda has been considered a “showcase of reform” (Dijkstra & van Donge, 2001). As illustrated in Figs. 2 and 3, the World Bank and other donors supported Uganda significantly in the 1990s, with the Bank acting as the principal supporter of the country’s electricity sector.

    • Stitching toward empowerment: A case study of Tabiro Ladies' Club

      2013, Journal of Co-operative Organization and Management
      Citation Excerpt :

      Using this perspective, it is important to represent the experiences of women in the Tabiro Ladies’ Club as they see it, using it to engage with the women to reflect on and extend their empowerment further (Maguire, 1987). What is interesting is that Uganda is often held up in terms of a successful “case” of how structural adjustment policies and economic reforms can bring individuals out of poverty (Dijkstra & Van Donge, 2001). Therefore, by studying a women-only co-operative in Uganda, it will be able to shed light onto whether economic reforms have been able transfer to women and the informal sector, not just the male dominated formal sector.

    • Beyond the Poverty Agenda? Insights from the New Politics of Development in Uganda

      2013, World Development
      Citation Excerpt :

      Along with further measures taken to promote and protect pro-poor expenditures in the budgetary process (e.g., Foster & Mijumbi, 2001; Piron & Norton, 2004), most notably the Poverty Action Fund which ring-fenced finance from debt-relief for areas of government expenditure deemed to be pro-poor, expenditure in the areas of education and health increased from 18% to 35% of the budget between 1997 and 2005 (Piron & Norton, 2004, p. 14). The sense of Uganda as a paragon of pro-poor politics (Mosley, 2012) was further underlined by its earlier success in significantly reducing poverty and vulnerability during the 1990s, most notably through the liberalization of coffee marketing (Dijkstra & van Donge, 2001) and also the strong role played by President Museveni in reducing the prevalence of HIV-AIDS (Putzel, 2004) . However, the story was never quite so straightforward, not least in the apparent air-brushing of the long-running civil conflict in the North and the Government’s complicity with this (Branch, 2005).

    • Theorizing entrepreneurship for the future: Stories from global frontiers

      2023, Theorizing Entrepreneurship for the Future: Stories from Global Frontiers
    View all citing articles on Scopus
    View full text