1 Introduction

Following the 2008 global financial crisis, investors became increasingly concerned about the financial outlook of a number of countries, including several in the euro area.Footnote 1 During the subsequent European sovereign debt crisis, a number of politicians and regulators accused speculators of using uncovered (or naked) sovereign credit default swaps (CDSs) to exacerbate the fiscal problems of many countries, including Greece, through raising the borrowing costs of governments. The sovereign debt crisis sparked the interest of regulators, and the sovereign CDS provisions in the 2012 European Short Selling Regulation (hereinafter ‘the Regulation’) were predominantly due to the perception that naked sovereign CDS activity contributed to Europe’s sovereign debt problems and that the speculative use of sovereign CDSs could destabilise markets. The final rules were highly contested, and were largely a consequence of political pressures stemming from particular Member States, supported by the European Parliament (hereinafter ‘the Parliament’).Footnote 2 This included the Parliament’s persistent demands with respect to imposing a ban on uncovered sovereign CDSs.Footnote 3

Although the EU regime is now relatively well established, the issue of short selling regulation continues to be a hot topic today, especially when one reflects on the temporary short selling bans imposed by the Greek authorities during 2015 as the country teetered on the brink of financial collapse. Likewise, Chinese regulators also recently pointed the finger of blame at ‘malicious’ short sellers when China’s stock market experienced dramatic declines during 2015 and early 2016. The Chinese authorities (amongst other measures) imposed short selling restrictions and instigated a range of market manipulation probes.

Further, in a broader context, the developments being observed with respect to short selling regulation at the European level also form part of a wider set of regulatory changes witnessed in relation to European capital markets regulation following the recent crises. Specifically, the rules that were in existence at the time of the market downturn were considered inadequate to cope with the various new financial players and products, many of which were perceived to constitute a threat to market stability.Footnote 4 Consequently, the crises prompted the EU down the path of more intensive regulation, and its initial regulatory response included a particular focus on establishing financial and market stability. Such reforms also expanded the EU’s regulatory perimeter to bring within it issues (including the practice of short selling) considered in need of regulation at the EU level. Today, although the high watermark of the post-crisis reforms may now have passed, the kernels of yet a further wave of changes are now also observable. For instance, current proposals include a push to try and widen companies’ financing sources through the EU’s Capital Markets Union project.Footnote 5

With this background in mind, this paper provides an overview of sovereign credit default swaps (CDSs) and their uses and seeks to place the concerns raised about sovereign CDSs in context through a consideration of the relevant economic literature. It then examines the requirements introduced by the Regulation that effectively prohibit naked sovereign CDSs.Footnote 6 Broadly speaking, the rules only permit entering into such a transaction where it does not lead to an uncovered position in a sovereign CDS. This then depends on whether the CDS constitutes a permitted hedge. Aside from ‘pure’ hedging against the risk of decline in the value of the sovereign debt, permissible hedging includes ‘proxy’ hedging (i.e., hedging risks of other assets whose value is correlated to the value of the sovereign debt). However, in this regard there are a complex set of requirements to be complied with, including geographical constraints, correlation and proportionality tests. During the Regulation’s protracted negotiations, the Parliament was also forced to concede to a temporary opt-out from the restrictions if the ban was damaging the government debt markets.

Although the regulator demonstrated a level of sophistication in recognising that there is more than one way to carry out a short sale, this paper suggests that the Regulation’s restrictions are a ‘misconceived response to a non-existent problem’.Footnote 7 There are many benefits to using sovereign CDSs and little to substantiate the accusations that developments in such markets led to higher funding costs for sovereign issuers during the crisis.Footnote 8 Indeed the rules that have been introduced not only prohibit uncovered positions but also restrict much legitimate hedging activity. More generally, the rules may reduce investor interest in the underlying bond markets in many countries and so may come at the detriment of the sovereign issuers that the restrictions were in fact seeking to protect.Footnote 9

2 Terminology: Overview of Credit Derivatives and CDSs

A credit derivative is a general term used to describe various swap and option contracts designed to assume or lay off credit risk on loans, debt securities or other assets, or in relation to a particular reference entity or country, in return for either swap payments or payment of premium.Footnote 10 Credit risk arises from the possibility of default on a pre-agreed payment, and the transfer of credit risk is achieved through the payment obligations of the seller of the swap (also referred to as the ‘protection seller’) that are triggered by specified events of default (‘credit events’) affecting defined assets (also known as ‘reference assets’) or defined entities (also known as ‘reference entities’) such as a government or corporate issuer.Footnote 11

Turning to CDSs, these instruments were conceived as over-the-counter (OTC) products and are quoted in basis pointsFootnote 12 per year. A CDS price indicates the cost per year to buy or sell exposure to the possibility of a default or restructuring.Footnote 13 Under the terms of a CDS contract (that will be laid out in documentation using standard forms),Footnote 14 the purchaser of the CDS (also known as the ‘protection buyer’) will be obliged to make specified fee payments (often referred to as the ‘insurance premium’ or ‘CDS spread’) to the protection seller on an annual basis. The level of protection is usually expressed in terms of a ‘notional’ amount that is being protected and the length of time for which the notional amount is being protected.Footnote 15

Specifically with respect to a sovereign CDS agreement, the seller will receive the premium in exchange for bearing the risk of capital losses if a pre-defined default event occurs (including the sovereign’s failure to pay interest or principal on an obligation) in relation to the referenced sovereign entity and a predefined notional amount.Footnote 16 Sovereign CDS contracts are usually denominated in a currency different from the main currency of the deliverable obligations as it is assumed that, if faced with a credit event, the local currency will come under pressure.Footnote 17 CDSs on euro area sovereigns tend to be denominated in US dollars.

To put these terms in context, if one party wishes to purchase protection on the notional amount of USD one hundred million of debt issued by a sovereign for 5 years, and the agreed CDS rate is five per cent per year, the party will pay a yearly premium to the protection seller of USD five million. If a credit event occurs in the 5 years, the seller will give the buyer the difference between the referenced debt and the market value of the defaulted debt. For example, if, due to the credit event, the debt now has only a market value of USD thirty million, the buyer will collect USD seventy million from the seller.Footnote 18

Where an investor purchases a sovereign CDS without having some kind of exposure to the credit risk associated with the underlying bond (i.e., where the investor does not hold the debt instruments or have some exposure to the debt), this is described as having an uncovered or naked sovereign CDS.Footnote 19

2.1 Uses of Sovereign CDSs

Owners of sovereign debt purchase sovereign CDSs as a direct hedging tool in order to protect them from loss arising from a default or other credit event affecting the value of the underlying sovereign debt.Footnote 20 Sovereign CDSs can also be used for arbitrage opportunities (i.e., the risk-free exploitation of price differences in connected markets) in the government bond markets.Footnote 21 Traders can try and exploit pricing differences between CDSs and the underlying debt obligations by taking offsetting positions between the two (known as ‘basis trading’).Footnote 22

Naked sovereign CDSs are also often purchased as ‘proxy’ risk management tools in order to hedge risks of other assets, such as national banks or utility companies whose value is correlated to the value of the sovereign debt.Footnote 23 For instance, if one invests in a national airline and wants to protect against the downside risk of a sovereign crisis affecting the airline, one could purchase a sovereign CDS without owning the underlying government debt.Footnote 24 Similarly, sovereign CDSs are also often used as a proxy to hedge positions in analogous instruments (e.g., in bank debt) for which a CDS may not be traded (or which may be highly illiquid and therefore expensive).Footnote 25 Such positions help fill a gap by allowing investors to hedge country- or sector-specific risks and also support projects that would not be financed otherwise.Footnote 26 Although, as will be observed at Sect. 5 below, the EU provisions aim to ensure that legitimate proxy hedging activity can still be classified as ‘covered’ positions, the many uncertainties introduced by the complex European rules mean such activity may simply become too cumbersome or costly to be worthwhile for market participants.

Finally, purchasing a naked sovereign CDS can also be used to reflect a negative opinion about the credit outlook of the sovereign issuer of the underlying bonds.Footnote 27 It is economically equivalent to short selling the underlying bonds, and both naked CDS purchases and short selling bonds provide useful functions by increasing the liquidity of the underlying markets.Footnote 28 Further, naked CDS purchases also help to keep prices from merely reflecting the activity of only the most optimistic market participants.Footnote 29

Naked sovereign CDSs provide a relatively simple mechanism for taking a short position and reflecting a negative view of the evolving credit risk associated with a sovereign reference entity: they are a ‘highly visible bellwether of a country’s perceived credit risk’.Footnote 30 Although other mechanisms can also be used to express views on the credit risk associated with a sovereign issuer (including short selling the underlying bonds or using other derivatives), such instruments can also reflect other risk as well as credit risk.Footnote 31 In contrast, the CDS market is more standardised: for example, sovereign CDSs on Greece all have the unique reference, which is the credit risk of Greece.Footnote 32 Equally, there is not the same required outlay to enter into a short position on the CDS market as there is with purchasing a bond.Footnote 33 Finally, in general terms, it can often be harder to short sell bonds than to purchase a naked CDS.Footnote 34 Indeed, this is particularly the case in the corporate bond market, where the secondary market is often illiquid.Footnote 35 In contrast however, the government bond market is generally much more liquid than its corporate counterpart, meaning the bond market may play a bigger role for sovereigns.Footnote 36

2.2 Size of the Sovereign CDS Market

Turning to examine the size of the sovereign CDS market in more detail, this Section will illustrate that the sovereign CDS market is only a relatively minor part of the overall CDS market, which is itself only a small part of the OTC derivatives market. Further, sovereign CDSs are only a small fraction of the total government debt outstanding.Footnote 37 It is also helpful to keep this in mind in Sect. 3 below that will then examine whether sovereign CDS prices are in fact capable of manipulating bond prices.

There are two basic measures of the size of the CDS market: the gross notional amount and the net notional amount. The gross notional amount is the total of all transactions that have not yet matured, prior to taking into consideration offsetting transactions between pairs of counterparties. However, this measure can be misleading as it can significantly overstate the size of the market.Footnote 38 For instance, market participants will commonly enter into offsetting transactions, and this will raise the number of outstanding transactions, resulting in an increase in the overall gross notional amounts.

Instead, the net notional amount takes into account all offsetting transactions between pairs of counterparties. For instance, if an investor has bought protection on USD 10 million of sovereign debt and decides to reduce this position to USD 4 million, it will enter into a new offsetting CDS agreement to sell protection on USD 6 million of sovereign debt, and the investor’s net position will then be USD 4 million.Footnote 39 The net notional amount is the basis for calculating the net notional payment in the event of a credit event and represents the maximum amount that could change hands if the reference entity defaults.Footnote 40 This is a more realistic measure as an increase in net notional exposure indicates there is increased demand for credit risk protection.Footnote 41

2.2.1 BIS: Size of the CDS Market Within the OTC Market

The Bank for International Settlements (BIS) provides information on a semi-annual basis with respect to the OTC derivatives market.Footnote 42 This data helps provide a general overview of the size of the CDS and sovereign CDS market, particularly in comparison with the overall OTC derivatives market. Nonetheless, the data also suffers from limitations: it only provides aggregate market statistics and is based on surveys rather than actual registered positions in the market.Footnote 43

Although in 2007 CDSs came close to surpassing foreign exchange derivatives as the second largest segment in the global OTC derivatives market, notional amounts of all CDSs have since declined steadily.Footnote 44 For instance, according to the BIS semi-annual survey, by the end of 2013 the global OTC derivatives market constituted approximately USD 710.2 trillion, and the gross notional amount outstanding of the total CDS market was approximately USD 21 trillion (approximately 3 per cent of the total OTC market), down from its peak of approximately USD 58 trillion at the end of 2007.Footnote 45 CDSs constituted the third segment in the OTC derivatives market, with interest rate derivatives accounting for the majority of OTC derivatives, followed by foreign exchange derivatives. By sector, sovereign CDSs constituted only approximately USD 2.6 trillion of all CDSs at the end of 2013 in terms of gross notional amounts outstanding: approximately 12.53 per cent of the CDS market.Footnote 46

2.2.2 Depository Trust & Clearing Corporation (DTCC) Data

The DTCC provides information on CDSs at the reference entity level.Footnote 47 According to the DTCC, their data captures approximately 95 per cent of globally traded CDSs, making it the most accurate and comprehensive publicly available dataset for CDS positions and trading.Footnote 48

Since October 2008, the DTCC has provided weekly CDS position data, disclosing the aggregate gross notional as well as the aggregate net notional outstanding on a particular reference entity. At the end of 2008, the top ten outstanding net notional sovereign CDS positions included the following EU sovereigns: Italy, USD 18 billion; Spain, USD 14 billion, Germany, USD 10 billion; and Greece, USD 7 billion.Footnote 49 In contrast, by the end of 2010, the sovereign CDS market had increased in size: for instance, the top ten positions outstanding included Italy, USD 26 billion; France, USD 18 billion; Spain, USD 17 billion; Germany, USD 15 billion; UK, USD 12 billion; Portugal, USD 8 billion; and Austria, USD 7 billion.Footnote 50

However, while the market has undoubtedly increased in importance since 2008, it is still small in terms of its relative size to the government debt market. For example, the International Monetary Fund (IMF) calculated that there was approximately USD 50 trillion total government debt outstanding at the end of 2011.Footnote 51 In contrast, there were only approximately USD 3 trillion sovereign CDSs outstanding at that time.Footnote 52 Similarly, a 2012 report on the CDS market by the International Organisation of Securities Commissions (IOSCO) observed that the size of the CDS market relative to public debt for euro area sovereigns had remained relatively stable since 2008, contrary to the perception that the debt crisis had increased the demand for CDSs for hedging purposes.Footnote 53 Indeed, IOSCO also noted that the ratio of net notional to public debt had remained stable or had actually decreased for countries more exposed to the crisis including Greece, Ireland and Portugal.Footnote 54

As observed at the start of this Section, this data helps to illustrate that the sovereign CDS market is only a small part of the overall CDS market, which itself is only a minor segment of the OTC derivatives market. Further, sovereign CDSs represent only a small fraction of the total government debt outstanding.Footnote 55 It is useful to keep these points in mind when moving to examine the interaction between the sovereign CDS and bond markets in Sect. 3. Finally, and more generally, given the very small size of the sovereign CDS market, it is also relevant to ask whether this market should have been such a concern for regulators, particularly in comparison with other, much larger, derivatives markets.

3 Interaction Between the Sovereign CDS and Bond Markets

3.1 Introduction

As already observed, during the sovereign debt crisis, politicians and regulators contended that the interaction between the bond and CDS markets could result in mispricing on the bond market and lead to higher funding costs for governments.Footnote 56 Essentially, when investors are concerned about a country’s financial stability, they will demand higher returns (i.e., higher yields) on government bonds to compensate for the higher level of risk, and this will increase a country’s cost of borrowing.Footnote 57 Further, if the default probability on a bond increases, parties holding CDSs will profit from the increasing value of their position.Footnote 58 The common assertion of regulators and governments is that a rise in CDS prices will lead to a collapse in the underlying bond market prices, leading to higher funding costs for governments.Footnote 59

Consequently, during the crisis, regulators and governments became concerned about the incentives of CDS traders and that they could seek to speculate on a country’s default.Footnote 60 Specifically, a letter from German Chancellor Merkel and French President Sarkozy to the Commission President in March 2010 demanded an inquiry into speculative practices in connection with CDS trading of government bonds. They stated that if such an examination demonstrated that such practices were having an impact on the development of bond yields, it should be considered whether it was necessary to pass appropriate legislation.Footnote 61

With this in mind, the interaction between the two markets should be analysed as to whether CDS prices are capable of manipulating bond prices. Specifically, for some, any evidence that CDS prices can sometimes lead price developments is then interpreted as indirectly demonstrating that CDS prices can manipulate bond prices and that restrictions should be introduced.Footnote 62

This Section discusses the relevant economic literature that broadly suggests that the sovereign CDS market contributes to credit market price discovery but that the market is not perfectly ‘efficient’ or necessarily more price informative than the bond market with respect to credit risk.Footnote 63 Further, the findings that the CDS market sometimes incorporates information faster than the bond market is not evidence that there is anything the matter with the CDS market, and nor should the findings be used as indirect evidence that CDS prices are capable of manipulating bond prices, driving up the cost of government funding.Footnote 64 Indeed the European Commission’s (hereinafter ‘the Commission’) own Task Force that was set up to examine the effects of CDS trading during the sovereign debt crisis concluded that there was no conclusive evidence that developments in the sovereign CDS market had caused higher funding costs for Member States.Footnote 65

3.2 Does One Market Lead the Other?

3.2.1 Overview

CDSs relate to the credit risk of an issuer: the risk of default of the issuer on its obligations towards its creditors. Equally, a bond purchaser is also exposed to various risks, including the credit risk that the issuer of the bond may not return the bond’s principal amount at maturity.Footnote 66 More technically, economists explain the relationship as follows: if one takes the yield of a bond with a credit risk and subtracts the yield of a comparable bond that is free from credit risk, the credit risk spread component can be isolated.Footnote 67 The credit spread of a bond of a particular sovereign and the CDS spread (or premium) for that sovereign should be closely linked as they both measure credit risk compensation for the sovereign (this is described as the ‘no arbitrage’ relationship).Footnote 68 The academic literature suggests that in a perfect market without frictions, both markets should be equally efficient and should adjust simultaneously when there is new information on credit risk: price discovery should occur at the same time.Footnote 69

In practice, however, due to various market imperfections,Footnote 70 the difference between the CDS spread and the bond spread (the basis) tends not to be zero in the short run and can at times become sizeable.Footnote 71 Such imperfections have led to researchers investigating, amongst other issues, which of the markets (the CDS or the bond market) is the more informationally efficient (i.e., which market leads price movements and reflects credit risk more efficiently).Footnote 72 There was already some existing consensus that the CDS market was more efficient than the bond market regarding price discovery for corporate reference entities.Footnote 73 Such findings are in line with the greater liquidity of the corporate CDS market compared with the secondary corporate bond market (which is often illiquid), making it more straightforward to buy a CDS than to trade the bond.Footnote 74 However, the economic empirical findings have been much more mixed for sovereign entities.

Appendix 2 to this paper summarises the main empirical work in this relatively young field of literature, and it is clear that the mixed findings in this area can, to an extent, be attributed to different methodological choices, including the use of different samples, time periods and data sources.Footnote 75 Nevertheless, overall, the literature (including, crucially, the report of the Commission’s own Task Force) broadly illustrates that the changes in spreads in the sovereign CDS and the bond market are mainly contemporaneous and that each market is equally likely to lead the other.Footnote 76

Notably, some of the findings also illustrate the relevance of counterparty risk in impeding the role of CDSs in price discovery: a factor that is particularly relevant given the over-the-counter (OTC) nature of the CDS market. Counterparty risk will have a negative effect on CDS prices: specifically the ability of the CDS market to lead the price discovery process will be impaired when levels of counterparty risk are high due to the perception of a lower quality of protection being sold.Footnote 77 Consequently, proposals to push such sovereign CDSs into centralised clearing under related European legislative developments would help improve the role of sovereign CDSs in price formation by reducing counterparty credit risk.Footnote 78

3.2.2 Sovereign Debt Crisis: Main Empirical Findings

Broadly, the literature suggests that the informational value of sovereign CDSs has become more important as the market has matured, but that the market is not perfectly ‘efficient’ or necessarily more price informative than the bond market with respect to credit risk.Footnote 79 The sovereign CDS market sometimes leads the bond market, the bond market sometimes leads the CDS market, and price discovery is equally likely to occur in either market.Footnote 80

Among the most directly relevant papers is the report of the Commission’s Task Force on Sovereign CDSs that was mandated to examine sovereign CDS activity during the sovereign debt crisis. The report found no evidence of obvious mispricing in either the CDS or the bond market. It stated that CDS spreads for more troubled countries were cheap relative to the bond spreads, implying that CDS spreads could hardly be considered to be causing the high bond yields in these countries.Footnote 81 This was also consistent with a sufficient supply of insurance being offered to troubled countries and with speculators acting as insurance providers at such times. This could be considered beneficial as it allowed institutional investors to take on more debt and keep the yields for such countries lower than otherwise would be possible.Footnote 82 Next, the spreads in the two markets were mainly contemporaneous and the vast majority of countries showed no lead or lag behaviour. When not changing contemporaneously, either the CDS or the bond market was equally likely to lead or lag the other, and the report concluded that price discovery was equally likely to occur on the CDS or the bond market.Footnote 83

Likewise, a 2013 paper by Arce et al. suggested that although the CDS market led price discovery in most euro areas in normal times, during periods of acute stress in the eurozone, the bond market led the price discovery process. The authors also re-emphasised the importance of levels of counterparty risk in explaining some of the variation in the price discovery process. In particular, they observed that increased levels of counterparty risk impaired the ability of the CDS market to lead the price discovery process due to the perception of a lower quality of protection being sold.Footnote 84 Finally, research conducted by the IMF observed that sovereign CDSs tended to reveal information quicker during times of stress but not at other times, and that the informational value of CDSs had become more important but varied widely over countries and over time.Footnote 85 Notably, the IMF concluded that, overall, the evidence did not support the need to ban purchases of naked CDS protection.Footnote 86

The findings that the CDS market sometimes incorporates information faster than the bond market does not provide evidence that there is anything wrong with the CDS market, nor should it be used as indirect evidence that CDS prices are capable of manipulating bond prices, driving up the cost of government funding.Footnote 87 Indeed, a qualitative paper by Duffie observed that in the case of financially weaker European sovereigns, as the aggregate net CDSs represented such an insufficient portion of the total debt outstanding, CDSs would not be able to manipulate and affect the underlying debt.Footnote 88

Duffie noted that setting aside the fact that it was very difficult to profit from manipulation, achieving a sizeable price impact (through aggressive purchases of naked CDSs) would require manipulators to take positions that were large relative to the underlying debt.Footnote 89 The author specifically analysed the case of Greece and observed that the aggregate of net CDS positions for Greece had remained well under three per cent of the total amount of Greek debt outstanding between October 2008 and July 2010.Footnote 90 He concluded that even if all the holders of CDSs on Greece had been pure speculators, this would only have had a minor effect on bondholders.Footnote 91

Ultimately, the literature broadly demonstrates that the sovereign CDS market contributes to credit market price discovery,Footnote 92 but that there is no strong evidence conclusively linking sovereign CDS trading with instability in the bond market.Footnote 93 Indeed, in line with Duffie’s paper, given the tiny size of the sovereign CDS market compared with the underlying bond market, manipulation of the latter by the former would be very difficult to achieve.Footnote 94

Further, on a related point to these findings, given that counterparty risk can clearly impede the ability of the CDS market to lead the price discovery process, moving sovereign CDSs through centralised clearing would reduce counterparty risk and help improve the contribution of sovereign CDSs to price discovery.Footnote 95 However, it is also recognised in this regard that it is trickier to centrally clear sovereign CDSs than other derivatives. Specifically central counterparties (CCPs) are reluctant to clear sovereign CDSs due to concerns about ‘wrong-way’ risks. Clearing participants are required to post collateral to cover losses, and as this will be in the same currency as that underlying the sovereign CDS contract, the distress of a sovereign could lead to a vicious cycle that will impair the value of the collateral while increasing the risk in the CDS contract.Footnote 96 Aside from this concern and on a more practical point, sovereigns are also likely to be out of scope of the centralised clearing requirements introduced in the European Market Infrastructure Regulation (EMIR).Footnote 97

4 Banning Naked Sovereign CDSs?

In March and April 2010, the German regulator BaFin and the Chair of CESR commented that there was no evidence of CDSs being used to speculate on government bonds.Footnote 98 Despite this, both Chancellor Merkel and President Sarkozy started to raise concerns as to the possible role played by CDSs in relation to the price of Greek government bonds. Subsequently, in May 2010, concerns that naked sovereign CDSs were being used to ‘gamble’ on the health of sovereigns led to BaFin introducing a ban on naked sovereign CDSs on euro-area government bonds.Footnote 99 BaFin justified the ban on the basis of exceptional volatility in euro-area bonds and the danger that excessive price shifts could trigger significant disadvantages for financial markets and threaten the stability of the entire financial system.Footnote 100 Nevertheless, given the unilateral nature of the act, it was likely to have been politically driven, especially caused by pressure on Chancellor Merkel within her own political party in relation to the German response to the Greek debt crisis. Indeed, the feeling that Germany had also acted to improve its own finances was compounded by its ability to simultaneously issue new debt at the cheapest rate since 1998, aided by the short squeeze created by the ban.Footnote 101

4.1 Impact of the German Ban

A 2012 paper by Pu and Zhang specifically analysed the global impact of the German ban on the sovereign CDS market and examined five-year sovereign CDS spreads over the period 12 October 2000 to 5 April 2011.Footnote 102 The authors considered the time trend of CDS spreads, volatility, liquidity, and macroeconomic conditions across fifty-four countries, including the ‘PIIGS’ countries (Portugal, Ireland, Italy, Greece and Spain).Footnote 103 In line with the majority of the wider short selling literature that analysed the impact of short selling bans during the financial crisis, the authors found that CDS spreads continued to rise after the ban in the debt crisis region and that market liquidity was also impaired for the PIIGS countries.Footnote 104 However, in contrast to the effect of short sale bans on the equity markets, the authors did observe that the ban helped reduce CDS volatility.Footnote 105 The authors also observed that sovereign CDS spreads were closely related to a country’s macroeconomic conditions: for instance, the PIIGS countries, whose CDS spreads had increased considerably since early 2010, had slower economic growth, lower reserves and higher debt in gross domestic product (GDP).Footnote 106

Overall the authors’ findings demonstrated that where a sovereign entity could not improve its economic condition, banning speculation on naked CDSs or short bond positions was not capable of ‘suppressing the rampantly rising sovereign yields’.Footnote 107

4.2 Impact of a Permanent Prohibition?

With this in mind, before turning to examine the provisions now introduced by the Regulation, it is also helpful to reflect on the possible implications of a permanent prohibition on naked sovereign CDSs. First, it is likely that a permanent prohibition would destroy the market.Footnote 108 For instance, if the CDS market consisted of only hedgers, these market participants would not find counterparties, as the market would have no liquidity.Footnote 109 Indeed, the presence in the market of those who previously purchased naked sovereign CDSs and were then able to take the other side and sell protection could also help mitigate volatility during crisis times.Footnote 110 Hence, the absence of such market participants could in fact lead to less rather than more stability.Footnote 111 Further, in a 2010 paper, Stulz observed that there was no evidence that removing naked purchases of CDSs would help the economy ‘any more than attempts to reduce stock short-sales did during the crisis’.Footnote 112

A 2010 paper by Duffie reiterated these points, noting that regulations restricting speculation in the CDS market could have the unintended consequence of reducing market liquidity and this would raise trading execution costs for other investors who were not speculating.Footnote 113 Indeed, in line with Pu and Zhang’s findings, imposing restrictions could in fact have the opposite effect to that which is intended and increase the borrowing costs for sovereign issuers.Footnote 114 Equally, making the hedging of sovereign debt more challenging could also discourage the purchase of sovereign debt, which could also have knock-on effects on interest rates and public deficits.Footnote 115 Further, by attempting to ban traders with negative information or beliefs, economic problems could also be delayed by ‘closing the collective eyes of the market’.Footnote 116

Next, introducing a prohibition on naked sovereign CDSs would likely be ineffective. For instance, as will be discussed further in Sect. 5 below, as there are substitute strategies that can be used, such a ban (particularly in the absence of supranational coverage) may only encourage market participants to engage in regulatory arbitrage and move their positions into other assets correlated with sovereign risk that could also involve less transparent instruments, or to offshore jurisdictions.Footnote 117 Indeed, spillover into other markets could come with the unintended consequence of reducing financial stability.Footnote 118 With this in mind, if the intention of the regulators is to simply discourage all and any speculation against a sovereign issuer, then the net should in fact be cast much further than naked sovereign CDSs to also encompass all such instruments that allow taking positions on the credit risk of an issuer that benefit from the worsening of a country’s credit risk.Footnote 119

Ultimately it is clear that a ban on naked CDSs will not prevent markets reacting to adverse information, and in the case of sovereigns it would seem far more prudent to focus on tackling the underlying fiscal problems of a country rather than seeking to ban the symptoms of the problem.Footnote 120

4.3 Burning Down Your Neighbour’s House?

It is also relevant here to observe an analogy that particularly surfaced in the media during the sovereign debt crisis. This suggested that the purchase of a naked sovereign CDS was akin to buying insurance on your neighbour’s house.Footnote 121 It was argued that just as such a situation would give a policyholder an incentive to then burn down their neighbour’s house, equally a purchaser of a naked sovereign CDS would prefer to then see the borrower default. This can also be described as creating a risk of ‘moral hazard’. For instance, if a market participant purchased a sovereign CDS without having a proportionate insurable interest in the underlying debt obligation or exposure to the underlying credit risk, the holder of the CDS could have a perverse incentive to precipitate a default and obtain the pay-out from the CDS.Footnote 122

This analogy starts to breaks down, however, when one bears in mind that the buyer of the naked sovereign CDS is unlikely to be able to increase the chance of, or in fact trigger, a borrower defaulting. This is particularly the case given that, as already observed, the sovereign CDS market only represents a tiny fraction of the underlying bond market.Footnote 123 Indeed, as Duffie observed, Greece had already borrowed far more than it could pay back before CDS rates rose significantly.Footnote 124 Further, a greater moral hazard may also potentially arise if a CDS protection buyer is a lender who is hedging its large loan to a sovereign borrower using a sovereign CDS. Such a lender may no longer be as interested in monitoring the borrower’s credit quality and could in fact have more of an incentive than a purchaser of a naked CDS to force the borrower to default: the ‘empty creditor’ problem.Footnote 125

4.4 Legal Recharacterisation as an Insurance Contract?

Separately, the relationship between naked CDSs and contracts of insurance should also be considered. Specifically it is clear that the economic effect of a naked CDS is similar to the effect of an insurance contract against the risk of default without an insurable interest. Consequently, if such a CDS contract were to be also legally characterised as an insurance contract it would be void, whereas if termed as a CDS (in the absence of a ban) it would be valid.Footnote 126

This question of whether credit derivatives might be legally recharacterised as insurance contracts was widely debated in the 1990s, and Robin Potts QC was instructed, on behalf of the International Swaps and Derivatives Association (ISDA), to provide an Opinion with respect to these concerns. Broadly, he advised that although insurance contracts and credit derivatives were functionally similar, credit derivatives were legally distinct as the payment obligation was not conditional on the payee’s loss and there was no requirement for an insurable interest.Footnote 127 With this in mind he concluded that for regulatory purposes, entering them could not be characterised as insurance business.Footnote 128 The Potts Opinion was relied on by the whole industry as conclusive,Footnote 129 and it was subsequently observed that due to the huge growth of the credit derivatives market the point of no return had long passed: the consequences of a recharacterisation would be too far-reaching to be contemplated.Footnote 130 Further, the correctness of the Potts Opinion was also subsequently assumed in European legislation, where CDSs have been regulated as derivative rather than as insurance contracts.Footnote 131

More generally, however, it should also be noted that the fact that CDSs resemble insurance is not sufficient to merit regulating them as such. First, many contracts contain an element of risk sharing or insurance but are not regulated as insurance contracts.Footnote 132 Next, the reason insurance regulation does not extend to all such contracts is due to the precise purpose of insurance regulation.Footnote 133 In particular, one of the main justifications for a separate insurance law relates to concerns about unsophisticated consumers who need protection from entering contracts they do not understand, and such an argument does not extend to CDSs where the average market participant is sophisticated and capable of bearing losses.Footnote 134 Finally, even if one sought to regulate CDSs that look like insurance, there would be considerable difficulty in accurately drawing the dividing lines, and parties could simply contract around the lines and enter equivalent ‘synthetic’ and unregulated transactions that had the same economic effect.Footnote 135 Indeed, as will be observed below, this issue of regulatory arbitrage is now also of particular relevance with the new European rules.

4.5 Legal Recharacterisation as a Gaming Contract?

A related issue in this context is whether CDS contracts could be recharacterised as ‘gaming’ or ‘wagering’ contracts, as such contracts were historically unenforceable.Footnote 136 It is unlikely, however, that naked CDSs could be so classified. First, English case law has held that speculation must be the sole purpose of both parties to the contract for the term to apply.Footnote 137 With this in mind it would be very difficult to show that both parties to a CDS contract were intending purely to gamble. For instance, many CDS purchasers would be using the contract as a hedge, whereas the sellers would be seeking to provide a service for a price to make a profit.Footnote 138 Further, and more practically, this is no longer an open question as the Gambling Act 2005 now provides that ‘the fact that a contract relates to gambling shall not prevent its enforcement’.Footnote 139

5 EU Regulation: A Ban on Naked Sovereign CDSs

5.1 Articles 4 and 14

Turning to then consider the precise rules introduced by the Regulation, the final rules are complex, reflecting the Parliament’s desire to prohibit naked sovereign CDS activity, whilst also seeking to try and enable legitimate hedging behaviour. Article 14 provides that a person may enter into sovereign CDS transactions only where the transaction does not lead to an uncovered position in a sovereign CDS as referred to in Article 4.Footnote 140 Article 4 then provides for two types of permitted hedging. First, hedging is permitted where the sovereign CDS serves to hedge against the risk of default of the issuer where the person has a long position in the sovereign debt of that issuer to which the sovereign CDS relates.Footnote 141 Secondly, proxy hedging is permitted where the sovereign CDS serves to hedge against the risk of the decline of the value of the sovereign debt where the person holds assets, or is subject to liabilities, including but not limited to financial contracts, a portfolio of assets, or financial obligations, the value of which is correlated to the value of the sovereign debt.Footnote 142

Proxy hedging is crucial to hedging and risk management in the CDS market; however, in many cases it can be difficult to clearly distinguish between legitimate and illegitimate hedging activities.Footnote 143 Consequently, as will be considered in Sect. 5.2 below, the related technical rules introduce a complex set of requirements that are tricky for market participants to meet with complete certainty in practice.

5.2 Delegated Regulation 918/2012: Conditions

5.2.1 Geographical Scope

First, although a wide range of exposures can be hedged,Footnote 144 the use of sovereign CDS to hedge cross-border risks is not generally permissible. ESMA stated that it was the intention of the co-legislators that the geographical scope of the rules should not be drawn too broadly,Footnote 145 and there are only very limited exceptions to this (provided the correlation test is also met).Footnote 146

The geographical requirements are problematic, particularly as such constraints could limit responsible risk management. Specifically, there may be several legitimate reasons for hedging a risk in one Member State with a sovereign CDS related to a reference entity in another Member State.Footnote 147 For instance, a market participant may have sovereign debt exposure to Germany but may want to buy sovereign CDS protection on Denmark, as the Danish sovereign CDS is highly correlated with, but is also a cheaper proxy for, German debt.Footnote 148

Further, it is also likely that such geographical restrictions could contradict core principles of the EU’s single market: for instance, even if market participants meet the correlation test, they could still be prohibited from trading in a particular sovereign CDS simply because the instruments were issued in a different Member State.Footnote 149 This sits uncomfortably with the vision of a single European financial market and could in fact provide a disincentive in relation to cross-border business.Footnote 150

Likewise, despite ESMA observing that it was the co-legislators’ intention that the geographical scope of the rules should not be drawn too widely, when one considers the wording of the Regulation itself, it does not explicitly state that hedging can only be within one Member State.Footnote 151 Article 4 is silent on this issue, and Recital 21 states that such interests ‘include’ hedging against the risk of default of a sovereign issuer. Recital 21 then provides examples of a wide range of exposures that could be eligible for hedging and although the Recital does refer to hedging exposure ‘in the Member State concerned’ this is arguably an example rather than a requirement that hedging can only be within one Member state.Footnote 152

5.2.2 Proportionality

Next, there is a broad proportionality requirement: the size of the sovereign CDS position must be proportionate to the size of the exposure that is being hedged. As matching assets and liabilities to create a perfect hedge is difficult in practice due to the diverse characteristics of different assets and liabilities, as well as the volatility in their values, an exact match is not required under the rules.Footnote 153 If the exposure being hedged is liquidated or redeemed, however, it must either be replaced by equivalent exposures, or the CDS position must be reduced or otherwise disposed of.Footnote 154

The proportionality requirement reflects ESMA’s technical advice and has the benefit of avoiding overly narrow rules.Footnote 155 However, on a more practical note, the position holder cannot be hedged only when the transaction is entered into, it must maintain a continuously hedged position proportionate to the size of the exposure.Footnote 156

5.2.3 Correlation

Finally, correlation is a key test to eligibility. The test is one of ‘simple correlation’Footnote 157 and the Delegated Regulation sets out alternative quantitative or qualitative correlation tests.Footnote 158 ESMA’s earlier technical advice proposed a purely qualitative approach, but the Commission chose to include both tests, observing that this was in line with the only EU precedent: the unilateral German ban.Footnote 159

The quantitative correlation test is met by showing a ‘Pearson’s correlation coefficient’ of at least 70 per cent between the price of the assets or liabilities and the price of the sovereign debt calculated on a historical basis using data for at least a period of 12 months of trading days immediately preceding the date when the sovereign CDS position was taken out.Footnote 160 Although this test benefits from being precise and objective,Footnote 161 the requirement that it be calculated on a historical basis fails to take into account the fact that past correlation may change over time, or the correlation may not yet exist in relation to situations of legitimate hedging of future risks.Footnote 162

The qualitative correlation test provides that the test shall be met by showing ‘meaningful’ correlation: this is a correlation which is based on ‘appropriate’ data and is not evidence of a ‘merely temporary dependence’.Footnote 163 However, it is unclear what will be sufficient to satisfy this test. Although the qualitative limb has likely been included so that market participants can capture a broader range of correlated assets, relying on this test could be risky in practice.Footnote 164 For instance, where a market participant is called on to justify that the qualitative test has been met, a party could breach the prohibition if it cannot then demonstrate to the regulator that the data relied on was appropriate.Footnote 165 Indeed, due to the uncertainties as to whether either correlation test will be satisfied, sovereign CDSs may not be used to hedge exposures, and this will lead to a shift to other instruments.Footnote 166

These concerns have been borne out in practice. Specifically, from August 2011 onwards, volumes of net notional European CDSs started to sharply decline, and this could have been in part due to short positions being unwound in advance of the Regulation’s introduction.Footnote 167 In fact, some market participants indicated that positions were being unwound as it was feared that the hedging rules were ‘so vague’ that they could be viewed as speculating even if they were not.Footnote 168 Market participants also observed anecdotally that Asian participation in the European bond market had fallen to under fifty per cent since the Regulation’s introduction, suggesting that the restrictions could be driving investors away.Footnote 169

Further, there has also been a sharp decline in the volumes traded on the European sovereign CDS indices, resulting in significantly reduced liquidity. Broadly speaking, CDS contracts on a basket of reference entities are known as ‘so called index and tranche’ CDSs.Footnote 170 Such indices comprise of many reference entities with a theme in common (e.g., European sovereigns). The index is composed of the fifteen constituents with the largest sum of weekly trading activity, and entities are weighted equally in the index.Footnote 171 Every 6 months, a new ‘series’ of the index is introduced, updating the set of constituents in the index. Since the Regulation came into force, volumes traded on the main European sovereign CDS index, the Markit iTraxx SovX Western Europe Index (‘SovX’ index), have declined one hundred per cent (i.e., the index has essentially been shut down).Footnote 172 Markit (the index provider) also announced that, until further notice, no new series of the index would be published.Footnote 173 This has also resulted in the creation of a new sub-index for SovX, known as ‘ex-EU’: constituents that do not form part of the European Economic Area.Footnote 174 Again, this only serves to further demonstrate that the Regulation’s constraints have negatively impacted the use of sovereign CDS indices, including for responsible risk management.Footnote 175

5.2.4 Opt-out

Turning then to the ability to temporarily suspend the restrictions, the Parliament was forced to concede to this possibility during the Regulation’s negotiations, and the rules provide for a temporary ‘opt-out’ provision. Consequently, the constraints may be temporarily suspended by a national competent authority (NCA) where it has objective grounds for believing that its debt market is not functioning properly and that such restrictions may have a negative impact on the sovereign CDS market, especially by increasing the cost of borrowing for sovereign issuers or affecting the ability to issue new debt.Footnote 176 Such grounds include high or rising interest rates on the sovereign debt, and a widening of sovereign CDS spreads compared with other issuers.Footnote 177

Before suspending any restrictions, the authority must notify ESMA and the other NCAs (and ESMA shall issue an opinion within twenty-four hours but has no veto option).Footnote 178 A suspension is valid for an initial twelve-month period and can be renewed for six-month periods.Footnote 179 Where an NCA suspends restrictions, notifications of uncovered positions will then be required on reaching or falling below relevant thresholds.Footnote 180 Further, it should also be observed that although ESMA has been granted broad powers in the Regulation with respect to other financial instruments in emergency situations, sovereign debt is expressly excluded.Footnote 181 In such scenarios ESMA has very limited powers, including, for instance, the right to be fully informed of relevant developments.Footnote 182

It is somewhat ironic that an opt-out has been included in the rules in the event that the CDS restrictions increase the cost of borrowing for sovereign issuers when this was precisely the rationale behind introducing the provisions in the first place. Indeed, there is also an added paradox here in that it is precisely at the times when such opt-out powers can be exercised with respect to sovereign CDSs that regulators may also be restricting other forms of short selling.Footnote 183

5.3 Impact of the Sovereign CDS Restrictions

Regulatory intervention brings significant risks with it, and the imposition of restrictions in the area of sovereign CDSs is all the more concerning when there is little indication that such activity raises sovereign funding costs.Footnote 184 Indeed, there are many benefits to using sovereign CDSs, yet little to substantiate the allegations aired by governments and regulators during the sovereign debt crisis. With this in mind, the EU rules that have been introduced in this area are an example of a ‘misconceived response to a non-existent problem’.Footnote 185

It is recognised that, given the relatively short period the Regulation has been in operation, plus the improved situation in the sovereign debt markets, it is hard to fully ascertain the effect that the sovereign CDS restrictions have had.Footnote 186 Nevertheless, as ESMA’s evaluation of the Regulation (hereinafter ‘the Evaluation’) also demonstrates, it does appear clear that the sovereign CDS restrictions seem to be driving participants away from using the sovereign CDS market in practice. In particular, ESMA’s Evaluation illustrates that the sovereign CDS constraints have led to a predictable shift to other asset classes: for instance, open interest in futures contracts has increased (especially on French and Italian bonds).Footnote 187 Indeed, such activity will always occur when regulation covers only one aspect of a market: market participants will seek to avoid the additional costs of regulation and will redirect their market activity to the unregulated market: the ‘boundary problem’.Footnote 188

In the context of sovereign CDSs this poses a problem for regulators since there are ‘literally an infinite number of potential contracts and contract forms that can be used by investors to share and transfer credit risk’.Footnote 189 Indeed, aside from the observed shifts to government future contracts, participants can also choose to short the underlying bonds, use corporate CDSsFootnote 190 as a proxy for a sovereign CDS, and also utilise more opaque and customised OTC derivatives contracts. Further, there are also regulatory inconsistencies that enhance this issue through policymakers choosing to treat sovereign CDSs differently to corporate CDSs. With this in mind, regulators should not hold too much confidence in the European sovereign CDS restrictions proscribing contracting in the marketplace.Footnote 191

It is also clear that the rules may reduce investor interest in the underlying bond market in many countries, and this could raise the cost of debt issuance for such sovereign issuers: precisely what the rules were seeking to prevent.Footnote 192 Finally, although commercial parties may work out with time how to ‘game’ the rules to their advantage,Footnote 193 this does not excuse the introduction of an unreasonable ban in the first place.

6 Conclusion

The unsubstantiated accusations that speculative CDS activity aggravated the financial problems of sovereign issuers during the sovereign debt crisis resulted in the introduction of a permanent prohibition on all naked sovereign CDS activity. Indeed, the Regulation’s restrictions go much further than only prohibiting uncovered positions and also eliminate much legitimate hedging activity. Market participants are rightly anxious of not satisfying opaque correlation tests, and the geographical limitations are also of concern, running counter to the principles behind a single European market.

The paper suggests that this regulatory intervention is unjustified, and that market participants, including those not targeted by the ban, are withdrawing from the market.Footnote 194 Activity will simply be transferred to other, less transparent markets, and the restrictions may also have the unintended consequence of reducing interest in the sovereign bond market. The economic literature and evidence that the paper has considered does not support the introduction of a ban: rather, it would have been far more sensible to have engaged in tackling the underlying fiscal problems of particular Member States than simply seeking to prohibit the symptoms of the problem.

Finally, although commercial parties may work out how to use the rules to their advantage, this does not merit the introduction of the rules in the first place. One should always remain wary of ‘knee-jerk’ regulatory reforms, and in this regard it is perhaps the policymakers and not the speculators who have sold us short.