Skip to main content
Log in

Looking for best performers: a pilot study towards the evaluation of science parks

  • Published:
Scientometrics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

Science Parks are complex institutions that aim at promoting innovation and entrepreneurship at local level. Their activities entertain a large set of stakeholders going from internal and external researchers to entrepreneurs, local level public administration and universities. As a consequence, their performances extends on a large set of dimensions affecting each other. This feature makes Science Parks particularly difficult to be properly compared. However, evaluating their performances in a comparable way may be important for at least three reasons: (1) to identify best practices in each activity and allow a faster diffusion of these practices, (2) to inform potential entrepreneurs about institutions better supporting start-ups birth and first stages and (3) to guide public policies in the distribution of funds and incentives. The multidimensional nature of Science Parks raises the problem of aggregating performances in simple indexes that can be accessed by stakeholders willing to compare different structures on the basis of their own preferences. This paper exploits a new dataset on Italian Science Parks to provide a pilot study towards this direction. In particular, we apply Choquet integral based Multi-Attribute Value Theory to elicit stakeholders’ preferences on different dimensions of Science Parks’ performances and construct a robust index allowing to rank them. This tool can be used to support the decision making process of multiple stakeholders looking for best (or worst) performers and allows to account both for subjective nature of the evaluation process and the interactions among decision attributes. Despite the present study employs only a limited number of respondents and performance measures, the procedure we present can be straightforwardly adapted to much richer environments.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2
Fig. 3

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. It is relevant to notice that different points other than the centroid can be used as summary for the population of subjects whose preferences has been elicited; however, our choice guarantees some desirable properties (see “Properties of the aggregation” section).

  2. Note that they carefully distinguish between Science Parks and different entities as Research Parks , Technology Parks, Incubators and other organizations, while we insert all structures sharing both research activities and incubation ones within our broad categorization.

  3. Note that more precise alternatives do exist (Labreuche and Grabisch 2003, see for example the use of MACBETH in) Nevertheless, this task is not trivial and can take a large percentage of the time dedicated to the preference elicitation procedure, making them potentially useless in a very large number of practical situations, stakeholders’ workshops included (Meyer and Ponthière 2011).

  4. The PPI (Fish 2006), an index used to assess the functions and independent position of the parliament, as well as the Severity Index (Reinhart and Rogoff 2014), which refers instead to the magnitude of recession episodes, represent additional examples of naïve methods of aggregation that are relatively common in the economics and politics literatures.

  5. Attributes \(x_1\) and \(x_2\) are mutual preferential independent if \((x_1,x_2^0)\succ (x'_1,x_2^0)\) then \((x_1,x_2)\succ (x'_1,x_2)\,\,\forall x_2\) and \((x_1^0,x_2)\succ (x_1^0,x'_2)\) implies \((x_1,x_2)\succ (x_1,x'_2)\,\, \forall x_1\).

  6. Corresponding to the total number of possible groups of attributes less the empty and full sets.

  7. In a sense, we invoke the principle of insufficient reason Bernoulli (1713).

  8. Notice that this approach is quite in line with the literature. Look for example at Meyer and Ponthière (2011) and references therein.

  9. Note that in different studies both actual/potential entrepreneurs, students and university research personnel have been identified as relevant SPs stakeholders (Vedovello 1997; ANGLE 2003; Link and Scott 2003; Hansson et al. 2005).

  10. The first program has been held at Bocconi University (Milan) while the second at Insubria University (Varese); in both cases students have attended a course on technology transfer and university-industry relations before answering the questionnaire.

  11. In particular the group is composed by 1 full professor, 1 lecturer, 1 assistant professor, 1 Ph.D. candidate and 6 graduate research assistants.

  12. International Association of Science Parks, http://iasp.ws.

  13. Also the data about SPs and their tenants used in this paper largely come from a survey conducted in 2012 and submitted to all Italian SPs. Survey data have then been matched with corporate data from the Bureau van Dijk’s ORBIS database and the PATSTAT database (Ferrara et al. 2012; Lamperti et al. 2015, for additional information).

  14. This time span has been chosen since the last SPs in our sample has been established in 2010 and we did not want to exclude it from the evaluation; moreover, we have planned to enrich and repeat the evaluation every three years to monitor how the set of Italian SPs perform in a reasonable time horizon for parks’ activities.

  15. Industries are identified through the NACE Rev. 2 classification.

  16. The normalization procedure is simple and allows to remove issues due to units of measurement. Therefore, the relative scores of each SPs on different dimensions of performance (e.g. number of job created and sales growth) are directly comparable.

  17. Specifically, they were asked to provide an order, assigning 1 to the SP which is though of be the best performing and 5 to the worst.

  18. This package allows the determination of a set of marginal value functions which are compatible with the respondents’ ranking, to test the presence of an additive numerical model and to calculate the corresponding capacities.

  19. Note that the last column does not sum to 30 because for 2 respondents the identification of the final capacity was not possible with any level of k-additivity. Therefore, they have not been considered in the final aggregation (see “Properties of the aggregation” section).

  20. The dendogram is a tree diagram frequently used to illustrate the arrangement of the clusters produced by hierarchical clustering.

  21. These services might include: business, legal and marketing consultancy, facilitated access to credit, facilitated renting fares, participation in sponsored events and fairs.

  22. In the case of firms’ growth, a value of 0 is assigned when the observed performance exhibits a negative value. Note that this is a conservative choice motivated by the willingness of preventing an excessive penalization of bad performers in a comparative evaluation

  23. For sake of simplicity, we assume, for the aggregate decision maker, \(u(x)=x\). However, the approach is robust to different specifications. Comparison tables are available from the authors.

References

  • ANGLE (2003). Evaluation of the past and future economic contribution of the UK science park movement. United Kingdom Science Park Association.

  • Battaglia, R., Lamperti, F., & Siligato, L. (2012). AREA SP: potere alleccellenza. In M. Ferrara & R. Mavilia (Eds.), Dai distretti tecnologici ai poli di innovazione. Milan: Egea.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bernoulli, J. (1713). Ars conjectandi, opus posthumum. Accedit Tractatus de seriebus infinitis, et epistola gallic scripta de ludo pilae reticularis. Basel: Thurneysen Brothers.

  • Brouwer, E., Kleinknecht, A., & Reijnen, J. O. (1993). Employment growth and innovation at the firm level. Journal of Evolutionary Economics, 3(2), 153–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Choquet, G. (1953). Theory of capacities. Annales de l’Institut Furier, 5, 131–295.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Colombo, M. G., & Delmastro, M. (2002). How effective are technology incubators? Evidence from italy. Research policy, 31(7), 1103–1122.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dabrowska, J. (2011). Measuring the success of science parks: performance monitoring and evaluation. In Paper for the XXVIII World Conference on Science and Technology Parks. IASP.

  • Debreu, G. (1960). Topological methods in cardinal utility theory. In Mathematical Methods in the Social Sciences. Stanford University Press.

  • Delmar, F. (2006). Measuring growth: methodological considerations and empirical results. In Entrepreneurship and the Growth of Firms (Vol. 1, pp. 62–84). UK: Edward Elgar Publishing Cheltenham.

  • Felsenstein, D. (1994). University-related science parks, seedbeds or enclaves of innovation. Technovation, 14, 93–110.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferguson, R., & Olofsson, C. (2004). Science parks and the development of ntbfslocation, survival and growth. The Journal of Technology Transfer, 29(1), 5–17.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferrara, M., & Mavilia, R. (2012). Dai distretti industriali ai poli di innovazione : L’Italia nel Mediterraneo. Milan: Egea.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ferrara, M., Lamperti, F., & Mavilia, R. (2014). The impact of technopoles and science parks on the regional and local innovation systems. In Design a Pattern of Sustainable Growth. Innovation, Education, Energy and Environmnent. Asers Publishing.

  • Ferrara, M., Mavilia, R., & Lamperti, F. (2012). The effects of innovation poles and science parks on regional economies in italy. In Proceedings of the 3rd international conference on communication and management in technological innovation and academy (pp. 196–202).

  • Fish, M. S. (2006). Stronger legislatures, stronger democracies. Journal of Democracy, 17(1), 5–20.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Gerardi, D., McLean, R., & Postlewaite, A. (2009). Aggregation of expert opinions. Games and Economic Behavior, 65(2), 339–371.

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Grabisch, M. (1996). The application of fuzzy integrals in multicriteria decision making. European Journal of Operational Research, 89(3), 445–456.

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Grabisch, M., Kojadinovic, I., & Meyer, P. (2008). A review of methods for capacity identification in choquet integral based multi-attribute utility theory: Applications of the kappalab r package. European Journal of Operational Research, 186(2), 766–785.

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Guy, I. (1996). A look at aston science park. Technovation, 16(5), 217–218.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hansson, F., Husted, K., & Vestergaard, J. (2005). Second generation science parks: From structural holes jockeys to social capital catalysts of the knowledge society. Technovation, 25(9), 1039–1049.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson, B. (1996). A methodological framework to analyse the impact of science and technology parks. In M. Guedes & P. Formica (Eds.), The Economics of Science Parks. : IASP and AURRP.

  • Hsu, H.-M., & Chen, C.-T. (1996). Aggregation of fuzzy opinions under group decision making. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 79(3), 279–285.

    Article  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, 47, 263–291.

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Krantz, D., Luce, D., Suppes, P., & Tversky, A. (1971). Foundations of measurement, Vol. I: Additive and polynomial representations. : Dover Books on Mathematics.

  • Labreuche, C., & Grabisch, M. (2003). The choquet integral for the aggregation of interval scales in multicriteria decision making. Fuzzy Sets and Systems, 137, 11–16.

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Lamperti, F., Mavilia, R., & Castellini, S. (2015). The role of science parks: A puzzle of growth, innovation and R&D investments. The Journal of Technology Transfer, 1–26.

  • Liberati, D., Marinucci, M., & Tanzi, G. (2015). Science and technology parks in italy: main features and analysis of their effects on the firms hosted. The Journal of Technology Transfer, pp 1–36.

  • Link, A. N., & Link, K. R. (2003). On the growth of us science parks. The Journal of Technology Transfer, 28(1), 81–85.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Link, A. N., & Scott, J. T. (2003). Us science parks: The diffusion of an innovation and its effects on the academic missions of universities. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 21(9), 1323–1356.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Löfsten, H., & Lindelöf, P. (2002). Science Parks and the growth of new technology-based firms-academic-industry links, innovation and markets. Research Policy, 31(6), 859–876.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Luger, M. I., & Goldstein, H. A. (1991). Technology in the garden: Research parks and regional economic development. Chapel Hill: Univ of North Carolina Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Marichal, J.-L. (2000). Behavioral analysis of aggregation in multicriteria decision aid. In Preferences and decisions under incomplete knowledge (pp. 153–178). Springer.

  • Massey, D., Quintas, P., & Wield, D. (1992). High-tech fantasies. Science parks in society, science and space. London: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Meyer, P., & Ponthière, G. (2011). Eliciting preferences on multiattribute societies with a choquet integral. Computational Economics, 37(2), 133–168.

    Article  MATH  Google Scholar 

  • Minguillo, D., & Thelwall, M. (2015). Which are the best innovation support infrastructures for universities? Evidence from R&D output and commercial activities. Scientometrics, 102(1), 1057–1081.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Minguillo, D., Tijssen, R., & Thelwall, M. (2015). Do science parks promote research and technology? A scientometric analysis of the UK. Scientometrics, 102(1), 701–725.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Monck, C. (2010). Performance monitoring and evaluation. In UKSPA conference proceedings.

  • Monck, C., & Peters, K. (2009). Science parks as an instrument of regional competitiveness: Measuring success and impact. In IASP 2009 annual conference proceedings.

  • Moon, J. H., & Kang, C. S. (1999). Use of fuzzy set theory in the aggregation of expert judgments. Annals of Nuclear Energy, 26(6), 461–469.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Murofushi, T., & Soneda, S. (1993). Techniques for reading fuzzy measures (iii): Interaction index. In Proocedings of the 9th Fuzzy System Symposium, Sapporo (Japan).

  • Pinar, M., Cruciani, C., Giove, S., & Sostero, M. (2014). Constructing the feem sustainability index: A choquet integral application. Ecological Indicators, 39, 189–202.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Reinhart, C. M., & Rogoff, K. S. (2014). Recovery from financial crises: Evidence from 100 episodes. American Economic Review, 104(5), 50–55.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Saublens, C. et al. (2007). Regional research intensive clusters and science parks. European Commission, ec. europa. eu/research/regions/pdf/sc\_park. pdf.

  • Shapley, L. S. (1953). Stochastic games. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America, 39(10), 1095.

    Article  MATH  MathSciNet  Google Scholar 

  • Siegel, D. S., Westhead, P., & Wright, M. (2003). Assessing the impact of university science parks on research productivity: Exploratory firm-level evidence from the united kingdom. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 21(9), 1357–1369.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Smith, J. H. (1973). Aggregation of preferences with variable electorate. Econometrica: Journal of the Econometric Society, pp 1027–1041.

  • Squicciarini, M. (2009). Science parks, knowledge spillovers, and firms innovative performance. evidence from finland. Economics Discussion Paper 2009-32, Kiel Institute for the World Economy.

  • Sugeno, M. (1974). Theory of fuzzy integrals and its applications. Ph.D. Thesis, Tokio Institute of Technology.

  • Vedovello, C. (1997). Science parks and university-industry interaction: Geographical proximity between the agents as a driving force. Technovation, 17(9), 491–531.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

This work has been partially funded by “POLIcs - POLI di innovazione Competence building System” supported by “Istituto di Ricerca per l’Innovazione e la Tecnologia nel Mediterraneo”, Reggio Calabria (Italy). The authors would like to thank Andrea Foroni, Viviana Trimarchi, Giorgio Tripodi and, with special mention, Simona Castellini for excellent research assistantship. Moreover, they want to thank all participants to the XXXVII AMASES annual meeting for helpful suggestions and comments. All errors are the authors ones.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to M. Ferrara.

Electronic supplementary material

Below is the link to the electronic supplementary material.

Supplementary material 1 (docx 42 KB)

Appendices

Appendix 1

In this Appendix, we present in greater details the technical features of the methodology involved in the evaluation of SPs. As we have seen, the application of MAVT based on the Choquet integral requires the identification of a capacity. In what follows, we firstly describe an alternative representation of the the Choquet integral, then we will formally specify the definition of the two indexes of aggregation which have been used in the analysis.

Any set function \(\mu :\mathcal{P}(N)\rightarrow \mathbb {R}\) can be uniquely expressed in terms of its Möbius transform by:

$$\mu (T)=\sum _{S\subseteq T}m_{\mu }(S),\ \forall T\subseteq N$$

where the set function \(m_{\mu }:\mathcal{P}(N)\rightarrow \mathbb {R}\) is called Möbius transform of a capacity \(\mu\) and it is defined by:

$$m_{\mu }(S)=\sum _{T\subseteq S}(-1)^{s-t}\mu (T),\ \forall S\subseteq N$$

Now we can rewrite the Choquet integral in terms of the Möbius representation of a capacity. For any \(u(x):=(u_{1}(x_{1}),\ldots ,u_{n}(x_{n}))\in \mathbb {R}\), the Choquet intergral of x w.r.t \(\mu\) is given by:

$$C_{m_{\mu }}(u(x))=\sum _{T\subseteq N}m_{\mu }(T)\bigwedge _{i\in T}u_{i}(x_{i})$$

where \(\bigwedge\) represents the minimum operator. The notation \(C_{m_{\mu }}\) clarifies the fact that the Choquet integral is computed w.r.t. the Möbius transform of the capacity \(\mu\).

As we have mentioned before, the concept of k-additivity can capture the trade-off between the complexity of the capacity and its modeling ability. A capacity \(\mu\) on N, indeed, is totally defined by a reasonably large number of coefficients, i.e. \(2^{n}-2\), and therefore such complexity ma result prohibitive in some applications.

Definition

Let \(k\in 1,\ldots ,n\). A capacity \(\mu\) on N is said to be k-additive if its Möbius representation satisfies \(m_{\mu }(T)=0\) \(\forall T\subseteq N\) such that \(t\ge k\) and there exists at least one subset T of cardinality k such that \(m_{\mu }(T)\ne 0\).

Clearly, the notion of 1-additivity coincides with that of additivity. Moreover, a capacity that is k-additive \((k<n)\) turns out to be completely defined by the knowledge of \(\sum _{l=1}^{k}\left( {\begin{array}{c}n\\ l\end{array}}\right)\).

In order to clarify the behaviour of the Choquet integral as an aggregation operator, we relied on two different measures:

  • The Importance Index

  • The Interaction Index

Here, we will define them more formally.

As we have seen, the overall importance of an attribute \(i\in N\) can be captured by means of its Shapley value which is formally defined by:

$$\begin{aligned} \phi (\mu ,i):=\sum _{T\subseteq N\setminus i}\frac{(n-t-1)!t!}{n!}[\mu (T\cup i)-\mu (T)] \end{aligned}$$

where for each subset of attribute \(S\subseteq N\), \(\mu (S)\) can be interpreted as the importance os S in the decision problem. Therefore, the Shapley value can be defined as a weighted average value of the marginal contribution \(\mu (T\cup i)-\mu (T)\) of element i alone in all combinations.

Moreover, in terms of its Möbius transform the Shapley value takes a really simple form:

$$\begin{aligned} \phi (\mu ,i)=\sum _{T\ni i}\frac{1}{t}m_{\mu }(T) \end{aligned}$$

For what concerns the interaction index, instead, following Murofushi and Soneda (1993), we can consider the interaction index for i and j as the average value of this marginal interaction. Therefore, setting

$$\begin{aligned} (\Delta _{ij}\mu ):=\mu (T\cup ij)-\mu (T\cup i)-\mu (T\cup j)+\mu (T) \end{aligned}$$

we have that the interaction index of attributes i and j related to \(\mu\) is given by:

$$\begin{aligned} I(\mu ,ij):=\sum _{T\subseteq N\setminus ij}(\Delta _{ij}\mu )(T) \end{aligned}$$

Clearly, such index takes a negative value as long as i and j are positively correlated and, as a consequence, a positive value when i and j are negative correlated. Furthermore, \(I(\mu ,ij)\in [-1,1]\ \forall i,\, j\subseteq N\). The value 1(respectively, -1) denotes maximum complementarity (substitutivity) between attributes i and j.

Appendix 2

See Tables 10 and 11.

Table 10 Choquet integral for all actual science parks
Table 11 Choquet integral for all actual science parks

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Ferrara, M., Lamperti, F. & Mavilia, R. Looking for best performers: a pilot study towards the evaluation of science parks. Scientometrics 106, 717–750 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11192-015-1804-2

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11192-015-1804-2

Keywords

JEL Classfications

Navigation