Skip to main content
Log in

Economic growth potential creating a real put and the resulting valuation of the firm

  • Original Research
  • Published:
Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

What do innovative new firms in our dynamic economy do to the value of existing firms? Using Schumpeter’s creative destruction idea, we expand the valuation model to incorporate these dynamics. Our model shows that these dynamics should have a greater effect on smaller firms, those in closer to perfect product market competition and those with less financial market following, as they get less market feedback for warning of new competition. This additional consideration in valuation is named the “real put” as it is an optionagainst value. Simply stated, it is an amount subtracted from a firm’s market value of capitalized earnings, plus any growth potential (that might create destructive competition against other producers) to get its net value. Following Schumpeter, new entrepreneurs and larger firms that mimic existing entrepreneurs are the innovators of new products and services. They create the real put against value in their potential competitors. We empirically test this using Morningstar’s “moat” classification of firms. We find firms with “wider moats” meaning greater product market power have much lower delisting rates that indicate smaller puts against value being exercised. While we are not the first in finance to view Schumpeter’s ideas, this is the first paper to consider its direct effect on valuation.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. It is “real” as opposed to a straight financial option in that the actual firm value is affected and not just the payoff of who receives the outcomes. It is “unwritten” as firms must accept this from being in business which invites new competition. It is a “put” as it goes against the existing value. In more general term, it is an option against value.

  2. Others have viewed the ideas of competition and its effect on valuation. For examples see, Akhigbe et al. (2015), Aleksanyan and Karim (2013), Chang and Chen (2012),Chen et al. (2012), Guo and Zhou (2015), Hu and Lee (2013), I and Chuang (2010) and Lin and Chang (2012). While other view the problem from a reporting or accounting perspective such as Caskey and Peterson (2014), Lin and Chang (2012), Mitra et al. (2013) and Sharma (2011).

  3. Several other papers show similar results though the direction of their objectives are different. For examples see, Alam et al. (2014), Chen et al. (2007), and Koussis and Makrominas (2015).

  4. O’Hara (The Journal of Finance 58, 2003), page 1349.

  5. In Schmid (2003), the author posits the same idea while reviewing situations in which the US government protects shareholders through holding this put. After developing a formal model, he reviews returns for quasi federally insured Freddie Mac and Fannie Mae over time as evidence of his idea. They obviously have since gone bankrupt and the government did make whole their debts prior their emergence as profitable enterprises.

  6. Michael Lewis, The New New Thing, (2000, W.W. Norton & Co.), page 98.

  7. FMA Outstanding Financial Executive Award for 1998 was awarded to Samuel Zell, Chairman, Equity Group Investments. He presented these points in his acceptance speech on October 16, 1998, in Chicago. These same points were also presented in “Visions of a Brand-Name Office Empire” by David Barboza in The New York Times, December 16, 2001, Business Section, page 1.

  8. Cataldo (2014) presents are more modern version of looking at risk over varying time periods.

  9. If we model different probabilities, it will actually make our model results more favorable to our argument as small firms will face a larger probability of a “hit”.

References

  • Aghion P, Howitt P (1992) A model of growth through creative destruction. Econometrica 60:323–351

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Akhigbe A, Madura J, Martin A (2015) Intra-industry effects of negative stock price surprises. Rev Quant Financ Account (forthcoming)

  • Alam P, Liu M, Peng X (2014) R&D expenditures and implied equity risk premiums. Rev Quant Financ Acc 43:441–462

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Aleksanyan M, Karim K (2013) Searching for value relevance of book value and earnings: a case of premium versus discount firms. Rev Quant Financ Acc 41:489–511

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Amihud Y, Mendelson H (1986) Asset pricing and the bid-ask spread. J Financ Econ 17:223–249

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Caskey J, Peterson K (2014) Conservatism measures that control for the effects of economic rents on stock returns. Rev Quant Financ Account 42:731–756

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cataldo J (2014) A framework for assessing comprehensive income risk exposure over varying time horizons, 2015. Rev Quant Financ Account (forthcoming)

  • Chang C, Chen M (2012) Re-examining the investment-uncertainty relationship in a real option model. Rev Quant Finance Account 38:241–255

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen S, Chung T, Ho K, Lee C (2007) Intra-industry effects of delayed new product introductions. Rev Pac Basin Financ Mark Polic 10:415–443

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Chen S, Yu C, Su X, Lai S (2012) Organizational form and long-run stock and operating performance following corporate R&D expenditures. Rev Pac Basin Financ Mark Polic 15:1250017-1–1250017-32

    Google Scholar 

  • Chun H, Kim J, Morck R, Young B (2008) Creative destruction and firm-specific performance heterogeneity. J Financ Econ 89:109–135

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dichev I (1998) Is the risk of bankruptcy a systematic risk? J Finance 53:1131–1147

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fama EF, French KR (1995) Size and book-to-market factors in earnings and returns. J Finance 50:131–155

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Guo R, Zhou N (2015) Innovation capability and post-IPO performance. Rev Quant Finance Account (forthcoming)

  • Han I, Chuang C (2010) The impacts of R&D investments on company performance: US vs. Taiwanese technology-intensive industry. Rev Pac Basin Financ Mark Polic 13:19–43

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hu C, Lee C (2013) Managerial flexibility and the wealth effect of new product introductions. Rev Quant Finance Account 41:273–294

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • John K, Nair VB, Senbet L (2014) Institutions and incentives to innovate: economic growth and optimal regulation. Stern School of Business, NYU, WP

    Google Scholar 

  • Koussis N, Makrominas M (2015) Growth options, option exercise and firms’ systematic risk. Rev Quant Finance Account 44:243–267

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lewis M (2000) The new new thing. W. W. Norton & Co, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Liang C, McClean RD, Zhao M (2011) Creative destruction and finance: evidence from the last half century. University of Alberta, WP

  • Lin W, Chang S (2012) Corporate governance and the stock market reaction to new product announcements. Rev Quant Finance Account 39:273–291

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Merton RC (1974) On the pricing of corporate debt: the risk structure of interest rates. J Finance 29:449–470

    Google Scholar 

  • Merton RC (1987) Presidential address: “a simple model of capital market equilibrium with incomplete information”. J Finance 42:483–510

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mitra S, Hossain M, Jain P (2013) Product market power and management’s action to avoid earnings disappointment. Rev Quant Finance Account 41:585–610

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Hara MP (2003) Presidential address: Liquidity and price discovery. J Finance 58:1335–1353

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Oakley A (1990) Schumpeter’s theory of capitalist motion. Gower, Brookfield

    Google Scholar 

  • Reisman D (2004) Schumpeter’s market: enterprise and evolution. Edward Elgar, Northampton

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Robichek AA, Myers SC (1966) Conceptual problems in the use of risk-adjusted discount rates. J Finance 21:727–730

    Google Scholar 

  • Schmid FA (2003) Conjectural guarantees loom large: evidence from the stock returns of Fannie mae and Freddie Mac. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis unpublished working paper

  • Schumpeter JA (1934) The theory of economic development: an inquiry into profits, capital, credit, interest and the business cycle [1912, 1926]. Translated, R. Opie. Harvard University Press, Cambridge

  • Schumpeter JA (1939) Business cycles: a theoretical, historical and statistical analysis of the capitalist process, 2 volumes. McGraw-Hill, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Schumpeter JA (1954) Capitalism, socialism and democracy, 4th edn. Allen & Unwin, London, London

    Google Scholar 

  • Sharma V (2011) Stock Returns and Product Market Competition: beyond Industry Concentration. Rev Quant Financ Acc 37:283–299

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shumway T, Warther VA (1999) The delisting bias in CRSP’s NASDAQ data and its implications for size effect. J Finance 54:2361–2379

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yen G, Lee C (2008) Efficient market hypothesis (EMH): past, present and future. Rev Pac Basin Financ Mark Polic 11:305–329

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Zell S (1998) Acceptance speech. FMA outstanding financial executive award for 1998

Download references

Acknowledgments

We would like to thank the Whitcomb Center for Research in Financial Services for data and travel support and Jay B. Abrams for his comments.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Michael S. Long.

Appendix: Morning star economic moat (obtained from morning star website)

Appendix: Morning star economic moat (obtained from morning star website)

Economic Moat is a proprietary Morningstar data point.

The idea of an economic moat refers to how likely a company is to keep competitors at bay for an extended period. One of the keys to finding superior long-term investments is buying companies that will be able to stay one step ahead of their competitors, and it’s this characteristic-think of it as the strength and sustainability of a firm’s competitive advantage-that Morningstar is trying to capture with the economic moat rating.

At Morningstar, one of the first things we do when we’re thinking about the size of a firm’s economic moat is look at the company’s historical financial performance. Companies that have generated returns on capital higher than their cost of capital for many years running usually have a moat, especially if their returns on capital have been rising or are fairly stable. Of course, the past is a highly imperfect predictor of the future, so we look carefully at the source of a company’s excess economic profits before assigning a moat rating.

For example, a competitive advantage created by a hot new technology usually isn’t very sustainable, because it won’t be too long until someone comes along and invents a better widget.

Here are some of the attributes that can give companies economic moats.

1.1 Huge market share

When a firm enjoys economies of scale in areas like manufacturing, sales, and marketing, it can be pretty tough for a competitor to catch up.

1.2 Low-cost producer

The ability to produce products or services at a lower cost than competitors is an advantage that’s especially potent in commodity industries.

1.3 Patents, copyrights, or governmental approvals and licenses

Some companies generate enormous profits when their products or markets are artificially protected by the government.

1.4 Unique corporate culture

Although you should be careful of placing too much emphasis on this attribute, since it’s such a “soft” method of determining competitive advantage, there’s no question it can make a difference.

1.5 High customer-switching costs

If you can make it tough for your customers to use a competitor, it’s usually easy to keep ratcheting prices up just a bit year after year-which can lead to big profits.

1.6 The network effect

This is a relatively rare, but potentially quite potent, source of competitive advantage, and often applies to the first mover in an emerging technology. Since a network’s value increases as more people use it, the company that creates the network can create a massive economic moat.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Wang, X., Long, M.S., Chen, R.R. et al. Economic growth potential creating a real put and the resulting valuation of the firm. Rev Quant Finan Acc 47, 453–474 (2016). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-015-0507-3

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11156-015-0507-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation