Skip to main content
Log in

Risk Aversion and Technology Portfolios

  • Published:
Review of Industrial Organization Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper analyzes the choice of a technology portfolio by risk-averse firms. Two technologies with random marginal costs are available to produce a homogeneous good. If the risks that are associated with the technologies are correlated, then the firms might invest in a technology with a negative expected return or, conversely, might not invest in a technology with a positive expected return. If the technology with the lower expected cost is riskier than the other technology, then this “low-cost” technology will be eliminated from the firm’s portfolio if the risks are highly correlated. With imperfect competition, the portfolios of firms are different, and the difference in risk tolerance can explain the full specialization of the industry: The less risk-averse firms use the low-cost technology, and the more risk-averse firms use the less risky, higher-cost technology.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. The similarity of all firms’ portfolios is reminiscent of a feature of the Capital Asset Pricing Model: Any investor’s portfolio is a combination of the market portfolio and a risk-free asset (see Sharpe (1991), for a nice exposition).

  2. For instance risk aversion can explain corporate hedging activity (Amihud and Lev 1981; Nance and Smith 1993; May 1995), and Wolak and Kolstad (1991) have empirically investigated how risk aversion explains the choices of risky coal suppliers by Japanese firms. More recently, Cronqvist et al. (2012) find a positive and robust relationship between corporate and CEOs’ personal leverage, which suggests that firms may inherit the risk attitude of their CEOs or that the riskiness of a company may attract a like-minded CEO.

  3. Appelbaum and Katz (1986) and Haruna (1996) studied long-run industry equilibrium. The monopoly situation has been analyzed by Baron (1971) and Leland (1972). Strategic interactions recently have received attention, notably by Tessitore (1994), Wambach (1999), Asplund (2002) and Banal-Estanol and Ottaviani (2006).

  4. The use of financial portfolio techniques (Markowitz 1952) to evaluate the diversification of power producing utilities was first used in the ‘regulated era’ and was initiated by Bar-Lev and Katz (1976). Such an analysis has additionally been used by several authors to evaluate national portfolios (e.g. Humphreys and McClain 1998; Awerbuch 2003).

  5. The correlation of two random variables is between \(-\)1 and 1:\(\sigma _{12}\leqslant \sigma _1\sigma _2\).

  6. Equivalently, functions \(x \rightarrow p^\prime (x + y)x\) are decreasing for all y.

  7. Formally, if both of the technologies are used, subtracting the first-order condition that is associated with technology 2 from the one that is associated with technology 1 (cf. Eqs. 6) and dividing by total production gives: \((c_2-c_1)/(\lambda q)=\left[ (\sigma _1^2+\sigma _2^2-2\sigma _{12})q_1/q+(\sigma _{12}-\sigma _2^2)\right] \).

  8. The calculations for the linear specification are available upon request to the author.

  9. The mean-variance utility function is a special case that corresponds to either a quadratic utility function, or a constant absolute risk aversion utility function and normally distributed risks, or a more general utility function but sufficiently small risks to allow for a second order approximation of the expected utility.

  10. Condition 10 corresponds to Proposition 3: The price \(p_1\) defined by Eq. (7) is equal to \((rc_2-c_1)/(r-1)\) if \(\theta _1=\epsilon _1+r \theta _2\).

  11. This finding is a direct result of \(\lambda ^i\pi (p,q_1^i,q_2^i,\theta _1,\theta _2)=\pi (p, \lambda ^i q_1^i, \lambda ^i q_2^i,\theta _1,\theta _2)\).

  12. The author would like to thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this possibility.

  13. The two properties—invariance by translation and homogeneity—are satisfied by a coherent risk measure (Artzner et al. 1999). See also the work of Zakamouline and Koekebakker (2009) on the relationship between risk-measures and the expected utility theory.

References

  • Amihud, Y., & Lev, B. (1981). Risk reduction as a managerial motive for conglomerate mergers. The Bell Journal of Economics, 12(2), 605–617.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Appelbaum, E., & Katz, E. (1986). Measures of risk aversion and comparative statics of industry equilibrium. The American Economic Review, 76(3), 524–529.

    Google Scholar 

  • Artzner, P., Delbaen, F., Eber, J.-M., & Heath, D. (1999). Coherent measures of risk. Mathematical Finance, 9(3), 203–228.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Asplund, M. (2002). Risk-averse firms in oligopoly. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 20(7), 995–1012.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Awerbuch, S. & Berger, M. A. (2003). Mean-variance portfolio approach. IEA research paper: Energy security and diversity in the EU

  • Banal-Estanol, A., & Ottaviani, M. (2006). Mergers with product market risk. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy, 15(3), 577–608.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bar-Lev, D., & Katz, S. (1976). A portfolio approach to fossil fuel procurement in the electric utility industry. The Journal of Finance, 31(3), 933–947.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron, D. P. (1970). Price uncertainty, utility, and industry equilibrium in pure competition. International Economic Review, 11(3), 463–480.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Baron, D. P. (1971). Demand uncertainty in imperfect competition. International Economic Review, 12(2), 196–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Blair, R. (1974). Random input prices and the theory of the firm. Economic Inquiry, 12(2), 214–226.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cronqvist, H., Makhija, A. K., & Yonker, S. E. (2012). Behavioral consistency in corporate finance: Ceo personal and corporate leverage. Journal of Financial Economics, 103(1), 20–40.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dhrymes, P. J. (1964). On the theory of the monopolistic multiproduct firm under uncertainty. International Economic Review, 5(3), 239–257.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diamond, P. A. (1967). The role of a stock market in a general equilibrium model with technological uncertainty. The American Economic Review, 57(4), 759–776.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ehrenmann, A., & Smeers, Y. (2011). Generation capacity expansion in a risky environment: A stochastic equilibrium analysis. Operations research, 59(6), 1332–1346.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Fan, L., Hobbs, B. F., & Norman, C. S. (2010). Risk aversion and co\(_2\) regulatory uncertainty in power generation investment: Policy and modeling implications. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, 60(3), 193–208.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Haruna, S. (1996). Industry equilibrium, uncertainty, and futures markets. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 14(1), 53–70.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Humphreys, H., & McClain, K. (1998). Reducing the impacts of energy price volatility through dynamic portfolio selection. The Energy Journal, 19(3), 107–132.

    Google Scholar 

  • Leland, H. (1972). Theory of the firm facing uncertain demand. The American Economic Review, 62(3), 278–291.

    Google Scholar 

  • Markowitz, H. (1952). Portfolio selection. The Journal of Finance, 7(1), 77–91.

    Google Scholar 

  • May, D. O. (1995). Do managerial motives influence firm risk reduction strategies? The Journal of Finance, 50(4), 1291–1308.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Meunier, G. (2013). Risk aversion and technology mix in an electricity market. Energy Economics, 40, 866–874.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Nance, D. R., Smith, Clifford W., & J., & Smithson, C. W. (1993). On the determinants of corporate hedging. The Journal of Finance, 48(1), 267–284.

    Google Scholar 

  • Neuhoff, K., & De Vries, L. (2004). Insufficient incentives for investment in electricity generations. Utilities Policy, 12(4), 253–267.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Okuguchi, K. (1977). Input price uncertainty and the theory of the firm. Economic Studies Quarterly, 28, 25–30.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roques, F. A., Newbery, D. M., & Nuttall, W. J. (2008). Fuel mix diversification incentives in liberalized electricity markets: A mean-variance portfolio theory approach. Energy Economics, 30(4), 1831–1849.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sandmo, A. (1971). On the theory of the competitive firm under price uncertainty. The American Economic Review, 61(1), 65–73.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sharpe, W. (1991). Capital asset prices with and without negative holdings. The Journal of Finance, 46(2), 489–509.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stewart, M. (1978). Factor-price uncertainty with variable proportions. The American Economic Review, 68(3), 468–473.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tessitore, A. (1994). Market segmentation and oligopoly under uncertainty. Journal of Economics and Business, 46(2), 65–75.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wambach, A. (1999). Bertrand competition under cost uncertainty. International Journal of Industrial Organization, 17(7), 941–951.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Wolak, F., & Kolstad, C. (1991). A model of homogeneous input demand under price uncertainty. The American Economic Review, 81(3), 514–538.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zakamouline, V., & Koekebakker, S. (2009). Portfolio performance evaluation with generalized sharpe ratios: Beyond the mean and variance. Journal of Banking & Finance, 33(7), 1242–1254.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgments

I gratefully acknowledge the support from the Business Sustainability Initiative at European Institute of Finance, and the very helpful comments of the editor Lawrence White.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Guy Meunier.

Appendices

Appendix 1: Supply Curve

1.1 Preliminary Results

The two first-order conditions (4) can be written:

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda \left[ \begin{array}{c@{\quad }c} \sigma _1^2 &{} \sigma _{12}\\ \sigma _{12} &{} \sigma _{2}^2 \end{array} \right] \left[ \begin{array}{c} q_1 \\ q_2 \end{array} \right] =\left[ \begin{array}{c} p-c_1 \\ p-c_2 \end{array} \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(11)

Let us denote \(x_1\) and \(x_2\) the solutions of these Eqs. (11)

$$\begin{aligned} \left[ \begin{array}{c} x_1 \\ x_2 \end{array}\right] = \frac{1}{\lambda \Delta } \left[ \begin{array}{c} \left( \sigma _2^2 - \sigma _{12}\right) \left( p-c_1\right) + \sigma _{12} \left( c_2 - c_1 \right) \\ \left( \sigma _1^2 - \sigma _{12} \right) \left( p-c_1\right) - \sigma _{1}^2 \left( c_2 - c_1 \right) \end{array} \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(12)

where,

$$\begin{aligned} \Delta = \sigma _1^2 \sigma _2^2 - \sigma _{12}^2= \sigma _1^2 \sigma _2^2 \left( 1 - \rho ^2 \right) . \end{aligned}$$
(13)

The threshold prices \(p_1\) and \(p_2\) in (7) are the solutions of the equations \(x_1=0\) and \(x_2=0\) [defined by Eqs. (12)] respectively. Two useful expressions of these prices are:

$$\begin{aligned} p_1=c_1-\frac{\rho \sigma _1}{\sigma _2-\rho \sigma _1}(c_2-c_1) \text { and } p_2=c_1+\frac{\sigma _1}{\sigma _1-\rho \sigma _2}(c_2-c_1). \end{aligned}$$
(14)

Lemma 3

The quantities \(q_1(p,\lambda )\) and \(q_2(p,\lambda )\) that maximize the firm’s objective (3) are:

  • if \(x_2\le 0\), then \(q_2=0\) and \(q_1=(p-c_1)/(\lambda \sigma _1^2)\);

  • if \(x_2>0\) and \(x_1\le 0\), then \(q_1=0\) and \(q_2=(p-c_2)/(\lambda \sigma _2^2)\);

  • if \(x_1>0\) and \(x_2>0\), then \(q_1=x_1\) and \(q_2=x_2\).

where \(x_1\) and \(x_2\) are defined by Eq. (12).

Proof

There is a unique solution to the firm maximization problem because its objective function is strictly concave (because \(\lambda >0\)).

If \((q_1,q_2)\) maximizes the firm’s profit subject to the constraints \(q_t\ge 0\) for \(t=1,2\); then the Kuhn-Tucker conditions are:

$$\begin{aligned}&p-c_1-\lambda \left( \sigma _1^2q_1+\sigma _{12}q_2\right) +\nu _1=0 \end{aligned}$$
(15)
$$\begin{aligned}&p-c_2-\lambda \left( \sigma _1^2 q_2+\sigma _{12}q_1\right) +\nu _2=0 \end{aligned}$$
(16)
$$\begin{aligned}&\nu _t q_t=0 \text { and } \nu _t\ge 0,\; q_t \ge 0 \end{aligned}$$
(17)

in which, \(\nu _t\) is the Lagrange multiplier that is associated with the inequality constraint \(q_t\ge 0\). There is a unique couple \((q_1,q_2)\) solution of these equations.

  1. a.

    \(q_1=0, q_2=0\) if and only if \(p<c_1\);

  2. b.

    \(q_1>0,q_2>0 \Leftrightarrow q_1=x_1,q_2=x_2\Leftrightarrow x_1>0,\; x_2>0;\)

  3. c.

    \(q_1>0 \text { and } q_2=0 \Leftrightarrow q_1=(p-c_1)/\lambda \sigma _1^2,\; (p-c_2)-\lambda \sigma _{12}q_1 \le 0 \Leftrightarrow p>c_1\text { and } x_2\le 0;\)

  4. d.

    \(q_1=0 \text { and } q_2>0 \Leftrightarrow q_2=(p-c_2)/\lambda \sigma _2^2,\; x_1 \le 0 \Leftrightarrow p>c_2\text { and } x_1\le 0.\)

Therefore, for \(p>c_1\), the signs of \(x_1\) and \(x_2\) indicates what is the solution. If \(x_2\le 0\), then \(q_2=0\) and \(q_1=(p-c_1)/\lambda \sigma _1^2\) (by c). Otherwise, \(x_2>0\), and \(x_1\) is either positive or negative; if it is positive, then \(x_1\) and \(x_2\) are the solutions of the Kuhn-Tucker solutions (point b) and if \(x_1\) is negative, then the only possibility left is \(q_1=0\) and \(q_2=(p-c_2)/\lambda \sigma _2^2\) (point d).

Note that, for \(p>c_1\) the situation \(x_1\le 0\) and \(x_2>0\) is possible only if \(\sigma _{12}>0\) and \((p-c_2)>0\). Furthermore, it is possible that \(p>c_1\) and both \(x_1\) and \(x_2\) are negative; in that case \(q_2=0\) and \(q_1>0\).

1.2 Proof of Lemma 1

Let us show that \(q_1(p,\lambda )/\left( q_1(p,\lambda )+ q_2(p,\lambda )\right) \) is increasing with respect to \(p\). This function if continuous and differentiable by parts because \(q_1\) and \(q_2\) are differentiable. For \(p>c_1\) three situations can arise: Either both quantities are strictly positive, or only one of them is positive. In the latter case the share of technology 1 is constant w.r.t. \(p\) (it is either 1 or 0). In the former case the two first-order conditions (4) are satisfied, and both quantities are equal to \(x_1\) and \(x_2\) given by Eqs. (12). Taking the derivative of the Eqs. (12) gives

$$\begin{aligned} \left[ \begin{array}{c} \partial q_1/\partial p \\ \partial q_2/\partial p \end{array} \right] = \frac{1}{\lambda \Delta } \left[ \begin{array}{c} \sigma _2^2 - \sigma _{12}\\ \sigma _1^2 - \sigma _{12} \end{array} \right] . \end{aligned}$$
(18)

And the sign of the derivative of the share of technology 1 in the firm’s portfolio is the sign of (the numerator of its derivative):

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial q_1}{\partial p}q_2-\frac{\partial q_2}{\partial p}q_1 \end{aligned}$$
(19)

which is equal to (from (12) and (18) and the expression of \(\Delta \) from (13)):

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{1}{(\lambda \Delta )^2} \left[ \left( \sigma _2^2-\sigma _{12} \right) (-\sigma _1^2)-\left( \sigma _1^2- \sigma _{12}\right) \sigma _{12}\right] = \frac{-1}{\lambda ^2 \Delta }<0. \end{aligned}$$
(20)

1.3 Proof of Proposition 1

If \(\rho < \min \left\{ \sigma _1/\sigma _2,\sigma _2,\sigma _1\right\} \), then \(p_1<p_2\):

  • if \(\rho \ge 0\) then from (14) \(p_1<c_1 < p_2\);

  • if \(\rho <0\) then, \((-\rho )(\sigma _1 - \rho \sigma _2) < \sigma _2 - \rho \sigma _1\) because \(\rho ^2<1\), and from (14), using \(\rho <0\), \(p_1<p_2\).

Also \(x_t\), for \(t=1,2\), is increasing with respect to \(p\) because \(\sigma _t^2 > \sigma _{12}\).

Then, for \(p\in (c_1,p_2]\), \(x_2\le 0\) so \(q_2\)=0 and \(q_1>0\) by Lemma 3; for \(p\ge p_2\), then \(p\ge p_1\) so \(x_1>0\) and \(q_t=x_t\) for \(t=1,2\), and both quantities increase as the price increases. Furthermore, from (7) \(p_2=c_2+\rho (c_2-c_1) \sigma _2/(\sigma _1 - \rho \sigma _2)\), so \(p_2<c_2\) if and only if \(\rho <0\).

1.4 Proof of Proposition 2

If \(\rho >\sigma _2/\sigma _1\), then \(\sigma _2<\sigma _1\) because \(\rho <1\). And, from (7)

  • \(p_2<p1\): \(\rho (\sigma _1-\rho \sigma _2) > \rho \sigma _1- \sigma _2)\) because \(0<\rho <1\); then, \(p_2<p_1\) from the expressions (14) of \(p_1\) and \(p_2\) and because \(\sigma _1-\rho \sigma _2>0\) and \(\rho \sigma _1 - \sigma _2>0\).

  • the proposition follows from the application of Lemma 3.

1.5 Proof of Proposition 3

If \(\rho >\sigma _1/\sigma _2\), then \(\sigma _1<\sigma _2\) and \(x_2<0\) for any \(p\) larger than \(c_1\) from (12) and by Lemma 3 the firm only invests in technology 1.

Appendix 2: Market Equilibrium

Let us introduce a new notation to ease the exposition: \(\varPhi (p)\) is the total production of a firm with risk aversion 1 facing a price \(p\):

$$\begin{aligned} \varPhi (p)=q_1(p,1)+q_2(p,1). \end{aligned}$$
(21)

This function is increasing with respect to \(p\): \(\varPhi ^\prime =\frac{1}{\Delta } \left[ \sigma _1^2+\sigma _2^2-2\sigma _{12}\right] >0.\)

1.1 Proof of Lemma 2

The quantities that are produced with each technology by a price-taking firm facing price \(p\), with risk aversion \(\lambda \) are \(q_1(p,\lambda )\) and \(q_2(p,\lambda )\). From Lemma 3 these functions satisfy:

$$\begin{aligned} q_t(p,\lambda )=\frac{1}{\lambda } q_t(p,1)\text { for }t=1,2. \end{aligned}$$
(22)

At the industry level, for any price \(p\) the supply of the industry with technology \(t=1,2\) is:

$$\begin{aligned} Q_t=\sum _{i\in I} q_t(p,\lambda ^i)=q_t(p,1)\sum _{i \in I} \frac{1}{\lambda ^i}=\frac{1}{\varLambda } q_t(p,1)=q_t(p,\varLambda ). \end{aligned}$$
(23)

At the market equilibrium, the price \(p^*\) satisfies:

$$\begin{aligned} p^*=P( q_1(p^*,\varLambda )+q_2(p^*,\varLambda )). \end{aligned}$$
(24)

The equilibrium production of firm \(i\) is

$$\begin{aligned} q^i_t=q_t(p^*,\lambda ^i)=\frac{1}{\lambda ^i} q_t^i(p^*,1)=\frac{\varLambda }{\lambda ^i} q_t^i(p^*,\varLambda ). \end{aligned}$$

1.2 Proof of Corollary 1

At the market equilibrium, the price \(p^*\) satisfies:

$$\begin{aligned} p^*=P( q_1(p^*,\varLambda )+q_2(p^*,\varLambda ))=P(\varPhi (p^*)/\varLambda ) \end{aligned}$$
(25)

taking the derivative w.r.t. \(\varLambda \):

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial p^*}{\partial \varLambda }&=-\frac{P^\prime }{\varLambda ^2}\varPhi +\frac{P^\prime }{\varLambda } \varPhi ^\prime \frac{\partial p^*}{\partial \varLambda }. \end{aligned}$$
(26)

Then, the sum \(\varPhi \) is increasing with respect to \(p\) (from (18)), and \(P^\prime \) is negative, so \(p^*\) is increasing with respect to \(\varLambda \).

A reduction of the risk aversion of one firm or the entry of a new firm are both equivalent to a reduction of \(\varLambda \) and induce a reduction of the equilibrium price. From Lemma 1, the share of technology 1 increases in each firm’s portfolio and in the industry portfolio.

1.3 Existence and Uniqueness of a Cournot Equilibrium

Let us first show that there is a unique Cournot equilibrium. To do so we write the reaction function of firms as functions of the total production and look for a fixed point.

Let us denote \(R(Q,\lambda )\) as the solution of the equation:

$$\begin{aligned} R=\frac{1}{\lambda } \varPhi (P(Q)+P^\prime (Q)R). \end{aligned}$$
(27)

The solution to this equation is unique because the right-hand side is continuous and decreasing w.r.t. \(R\) (because \(P^\prime <0\) and \(\varPhi \) is increasing). \(R(Q,\lambda )\) is the production of a firm with risk aversion \(\lambda \) when total production is \(Q\). This function is differentiable by parts and

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial R}{\partial Q}=-\frac{\varPhi ^\prime }{\lambda }\left( P^\prime +P^{\prime \prime }R\right) +\frac{\varPhi ^\prime }{\lambda } P^\prime \frac{\partial R}{\partial Q}. \end{aligned}$$
(28)

Therefore, \(R(Q,\lambda )\) is decreasing w.r.t to \(Q\) because \(P^\prime +P^{\prime \prime }R<0\) by assumption A.

At a Cournot equilibrium the total production \(Q\) and each firm production \(q^i\) satisfy \(q^i=R(Q,\lambda ^i)\); therefore, the total production is a solution of the equation:

$$\begin{aligned} Q=\sum _{i\in I} R(Q,\lambda ^i). \end{aligned}$$
(29)

This equation as a solution which is unique (the R.H.S. is decreasing w.r.t. \(Q\) because so is \(R(Q,\lambda )\)). Therefore, there is a unique Cournot equilibrium. The total production is the solution of (29) and firms’ production quantities are the unique solutions of

$$\begin{aligned} q^i&=R(Q,\lambda ^i) \end{aligned}$$
(30)
$$\begin{aligned} q^i_t&=q_t(P+P^\prime q^i,\lambda ^i)=\frac{1}{\lambda ^i}q_t(P+P^\prime q^i,1). \end{aligned}$$
(31)

1.4 Proof of Proposition 4

At the Cournot equilibrium \(q^i=R(Q,\lambda ^i)\) and the function \(R(Q,\lambda )\) is striclty decreasing w.r.t. \(\lambda \) when positive (by differentiation of (27)). So,

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda ^i \leqslant \lambda ^j \Leftrightarrow q^i \geqslant q^j. \end{aligned}$$
(32)

Then, let us show that

$$\begin{aligned} \lambda ^i \leqslant \lambda ^j \Rightarrow \frac{q^i_1}{q^i} \geqslant \frac{q^j_1}{q_j}. \end{aligned}$$
(33)

We proceed by contradiction and assume that there are two firms \(i,j\in I\), \(i\ne j\) such that \(\lambda ^i < \lambda ^j\) and \(q_1^i/q^i < q_1^j/q^j\). By Lemma 1 \(q_1(p,1)/\varPhi (p)\) is increasing w.r.t. to \(p\), so (by (31)) \(P+P^\prime q^i > P+P^\prime q^j\) and \(q^i<q^j\), which is a contradiction.

The Proposition follows from (32) and (33).

1.5 Proof of Corollary 2

We consider a decrease of the risk aversion of firm \(i \in I\). The cournot equilibrium production is the solution of Eq. (29). A decrease of \(\lambda ^i\) increases the right-hand-side for all \(Q\), so the total production increases. We prove the three first points of the Corollary:

  • For firm \(j\ne i\), its production \(R(Q,\lambda ^j)\) decreases because \(R\) decreases w.r.t. \(Q\) (point (ii)).

  • Concerning firm \(i\), its production increases because the total production increases and all other firms’ production decreases (point(i)).

  • The marginal revenue of all firms decreases:

    • for firm \(i\), \(P(Q)+P^\prime (Q) q^i\) decreases because \(Q\) and \(q^i\) increases;

    • for firm \(j\ne i\), \(P(Q)+P^\prime (Q)q^j\) decreases because \(q^j\) decreases and \(q^j=\varPhi (P+P^\prime q^j)/\lambda ^j\), and \(\lambda ^j\) remains unchanged and \(\varPhi \) is decreasing.

    So, from Lemma 1, the share of technology 1 in all firms portfolio increases (point(iii)).

Appendix 3: Generalisation

1.1 Expected Utility

Technology 1 is not used at equilibrium if there is \(q_2\) such that

$$\begin{aligned} \mathbb {E}[ U'(\pi )(p-\theta _2-c_2)]=0\text { and } \mathbb {E}[U'(\pi )(p-\theta _1-c_1)]\le 0. \end{aligned}$$
(34)

The left equality should be rewritten: \(0=\mathbb {E}[\pi ](p-c_2) -\text {cov}(U'(\pi ), \theta _2) \) and the inequality:

$$\begin{aligned} 0&\le \mathbb {E}[U'(\pi )(p-\theta _1-c_1)]=\mathbb {E}[\pi ](p-c_1) -\text {cov}(U'(\pi ), \theta _2) \nonumber \\&\le \text {cov}(U'(\pi ), \theta _2)\frac{p-c_1}{p-c_2} -\text {cov}(U'(\pi ), \theta _2). \nonumber \end{aligned}$$

1.2 Coherent Risk Measure

Consider the function \(\tilde{\rho }(q_1,q_2)=\rho (\theta q_1+\theta _2 q_2)\). We assume that it is homogeneous of degree one; consequently its derivatives are homogeneous of degree zero:

$$\begin{aligned} \frac{\partial \tilde{\rho }}{\partial q_t} (rq_1,rq_2)=\frac{\partial \tilde{\rho }}{\partial q_t} (q_1,q_2). \end{aligned}$$

Let us also assume that \(\tilde{\rho }\) is strictly convex. For each firm there is a unique couple of maximizing quantities; if firm \(i\) invests in both technologies, the first-order conditions are

$$\begin{aligned} p-c_t=\lambda ^i\tilde{\rho }(q_1^i,q_2^i)\frac{\partial \tilde{\rho }}{\partial q_t}(q_1^i,q_2^i) = \tilde{\rho }(\lambda ^i q_1^i,\lambda ^i q_2^i) \frac{\partial \tilde{\rho }}{\partial q_t}(\lambda ^i q_1^i,\lambda ^i q_2^i). \end{aligned}$$

The quantities \(\lambda ^i q^i_1\) are the solutions of a couple of equations that are independent of \(\lambda _i\) so that they are independent of \(\lambda ^i\). This ensures that the functions \(q_t(p,\lambda )\) are homogeneous of degree -1 with respect to \(\lambda \).

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Meunier, G. Risk Aversion and Technology Portfolios. Rev Ind Organ 44, 347–365 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-014-9420-5

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11151-014-9420-5

Keywords

Navigation