Skip to main content
Log in

Home Price, Time-on-Market, and Seller Heterogeneity Under Changing Market Conditions

  • Published:
The Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

This paper develops a formal model to examine the effect of changing market conditions and individuals’ selling constraints on selling price and time-on-market. Using the concept of Relative Liquidity Constraint (RLC)—a stochastic variable that captures the randomness of future individual constraints and market conditions—the study presents the first ex ante analysis that extends the investigation of the issue of seller heterogeneity to the point of the buying decision, that is, from the perspective of the buyer’s (future seller’s) point of view. We show that seller constraint, as well as the uncertainty of such a constraint, significantly depresses the expected selling price and increases risk. Our closed-form formulas provide a set of simple quantitative tools that enable buyers and sellers to adjust the “market average” to their ex ante “individual expectations”.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. We thank an anonymous referee for his knowledgeable insight that directed our attention to the studies cited in this paragraph.

  2. Of course, in some cases, once a property is placed on the market and an investor has received insufficient interest given her motivation to sell, she may revise her listing price downward based upon a revised perspective of the underlying bid distribution. In addition, in a recent paper Cheng, Lin and Liu (2008) also adopt this assumption to study a model of time-on-market and real estate price under sequential search with recall.

  3. Early studies in labor economics literature often rely on this assumption (e.g. Stigler (1962), Whipple (1973) and Barron (1975)), and it has been extensively applied to the real estate market since the 1980s (e.g. Yinger (1981), Read (1988), Quan and Quigley (1991), Yavas (1992), Arnold (1999), Lin and Vandell (2007)).

  4. In fact, our essential results would hold under a wide variety of more complex distribution function assumptions.

  5. In certain circumstances, it is well recognized that potential buyers can get into a “bidding war” in which they bid a price above the asking price; however, this happens rarely and only when the market is exceptionally “hot” or a property is dramatically underpriced. Based on the data from the National Association of Realtors, Green and Vandell (1998) find that such a situation occurs in about five percent of transactions.

  6. Statistics principles state that the exponential distribution occurs naturally when describing the lengths of the inter-arrival times in a homogeneous Poisson process.

  7. In this paper, we use the term “unconstrained sellers” interchangeably with the term “typical sellers” or “normal sellers”. An “unconstrained seller” is “typically” or “normally” constrained. Thus a “constrained seller” is one who is subject to higher-than-normal constraints.

  8. The conditional variance formula for any two stochastic variables of x and y is \({\text{Var}}\left( {x_y } \right) = E\left[ {{\text{Var}}\left( {x_y \left| y \right.} \right)} \right] + {\text{Var}}\left( {E\left[ {x_y \left| y \right.} \right]} \right)\). See Ross (2002), p 379.

  9. A formal analysis of this observation can be found in Appendix 2.

References

  • Anglin, P. (2006). Value and liquidity under changing market conditions. Journal of Housing Economics, 15, 293–304. doi:10.1016/j.jhe.2006.10.003.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Arnold, M. (1999). Search, bargaining and optimal asking prices. Real Estate Economics, 27, 453–481. doi:10.1111/1540-6229.00780.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barron, J. (1975). Search in the labor market and the duration of unemployment: some empirical evidence. The American Economic Review, 65, 934–942.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bond, S., Hwang, S., Lin, Z., & Vandell, K. (2007). Marketing period risk in a portfolio context: theory and empirical estimates from the UK commercial real estate market? Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 34, 447–461. doi:10.1007/s11146-007-9022-1.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cheng, P., Lin, Z., & Liu, Y. (2008). A model of time-on-market and real estate price under sequential search with recall. Real Estate Economics, 36, 813–843. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6229.2008.00231.x.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ferreira, E., & Sirmans, G. (1989). Selling price, financing premiums, and days on the market. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 2, 209–222. doi:10.1007/BF00152349.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Forgey, F., Rutherford, R., & Vanbuskirk, M. (1994). Foreclosure status and its effect on residential selling price. The Journal Of Real Estate Research, 9, 313–318.

    Google Scholar 

  • Forgey, F., Rutherford, R., & Springer, T. (1996). Search and liquidity in single-family housing. Real Estate Economics, 24, 273–392. doi:10.1111/1540-6229.00691.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Genesove, D., & Mayer, C. (1997). Equity and time to sale in the real estate market. The American Economic Review, 87, 255–269.

    Google Scholar 

  • Glower, M., Haurin, D., & Hendershott, P. (1998). Selling price and selling time: the impact of investor motivation. Real Estate Economics, 26, 719–740. doi:10.1111/1540-6229.00763.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, R., & Vandell, K. (1998). Optimal asking price and bid acceptance strategies for residential sales. Working Paper, Center for Real Estate and Urban Land Economics, University of Wisconsin–Madison.

  • Hardin, W., & Wolverton, M. (1996). The relationship between foreclosure status and apartment price. The Journal of Real Estate Research, 12, 101–109.

    Google Scholar 

  • Huang, J., & Palmquist, R. (2001). Environmental conditions, reservation prices, and time on the market for housing. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 22, 203–219. doi:10.1023/A:1007891430162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kluger, B., & Miller, N. (1990). Measuring residential real estate liquidity. AREUEA Journal, 18(2), 145–159.

    Google Scholar 

  • Knight, J. (2002). Listing price, time on market, and ultimate selling price: causes and effects of listing price changes. Real Estate Economics, 30, 215–237. doi:10.1111/1540-6229.00038.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Krainer, J. (2001). A theory of liquidity in residential real estate markets. Journal of Urban Economics, 49, 32–53. doi:10.1006/juec.2000.2180.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lazear, E. (1986). Retail pricing and clearance sales. The American Economic Review, 76, 14–32.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lin, Z. (2004). Liquidity and pricing biases in the real estate market. Unpublished Ph.D. Dissertation, University of Wisconsin–Madison, Real Estate and Urban Land Economics.

  • Lin, Z., & Vandell, K. (2007). Illiquidity and pricing biases in the real estate market. Real Estate Economics, 35(3), 291–330. doi:10.1111/j.1540-6229.2007.00191.x.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lin, Z., & Liu, Y. (2008). Real estate returns and risk with heterogeneous investors. Real Estate Economics, 36, 753–776.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Lippman, S., & McCall, J. (1986). An operational measure of liquidity. The American Economic Review, 76, 43–55.

    Google Scholar 

  • Merlo, A., & Ortalo-Magne, F. (2004). Bargaining over residential real estate: evidence from England. Journal of Urban Economics, 56, 192–216. doi:10.1016/j.jue.2004.05.004.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Miceli, T. (1989). The optimal duration of real estate listing contracts. Journal of the American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association, 17, 267–277. doi:10.1111/1540-6229.00491.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Quan, D., & Quigley, J. (1991). Price formation and the appraisal function in real estate markets. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 4, 127–146. doi:10.1007/BF00173120.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Read, C. (1988). Price strategies for idiosyncratic goods—the case of housing. Journal of the American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association, 16, 379–395. doi:10.1111/1540-6229.00462.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ross, S. (2002). A first course in probability (6th ed.). Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall.

    Google Scholar 

  • Rutherford, R., Springer, T., & Yavas, A. (2005). Conflicts between principals and agents: evidence from residential brokerage. Journal of Financial Economics, 76, 627–665. doi:10.1016/j.jfineco.2004.06.006.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shilling, J., Benjamin, J., & Sirmans, C. (1990). Estimating net realizable value for distressed real estate. The Journal of Real Estate Research, 5(1), 129–140.

    Google Scholar 

  • Sirmans, C., Turnbull, G., & Dombrow, J. (1995). Quick house sales: investor mistake or luck? Journal of Housing Economics, 4, 230–243.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Sirmans, S., Macpherson, D., & Zietz, E. (2005). The composition of hedonic pricing models. Journal of Real Estate Literature, 13, 3–43.

    Google Scholar 

  • Springer, T. (1996). Single-family housing transactions: seller motivations, price and marketing time. Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, 13, 236–254. doi:10.1007/BF00217393.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. (1962). Information in the labor market. Journal of Political Economy, 70, 94–105. doi:10.1086/258727.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor, C. (1999). Time-on-the-market as a sign of quality. Review of Economic Studies, 66, 555–578. doi:10.1111/1467-937X.00098.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Turnbull, G., Sirmans, C., & Benjamin, J. (1990). Do corporations sell houses for less? A test of housing market efficiency. Applied Economics, 22, 1389–1398. doi:10.1080/00036849000000109.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Whipple, D. (1973). A generalized theory of job search. Journal of Political Economy, 81, 1170–1188. doi:10.1086/260112.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yavas, A. (1992). A simple search and bargaining model of real estate markets. Journal of the American Real Estate and Urban Economics Association, 20, 533–548. doi:10.1111/1540-6229.00595.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Yinger, J. (1981). A search model of real estate broker behavior. The American Economic Review, 71, 591–605.

    Google Scholar 

  • Zuehlke, T. (1987). Duration dependence in the housing market. Review of Economics and Statistics, 69, 701–704. doi:10.2307/1935966.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We wish to thank editor James Kau, two anonymous referees at the Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics, David Beltran-del-Rio and Paul Obrecht at Fannie Mae for their insightful comments and suggetions. All errors remain our own. The views expressed in this article are our own and do not necessarily represent the views of the authors affiliated organizations.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Zhenguo Lin.

Appendices

Appendix 1

One potential difficulty with application of Theorem 1 and 2 is that the time series return data, when broken down to sub-periods of different market conditions (Good, Bad, and Normal), are not long enough to estimate \(u_\tau \), \(\sigma _\tau \) for each sub-period when the holding period is long. One way to get around this problem is to use the common assumptions on holding-period return and risk: \(u_\tau = \tau u\) and \(\sigma _\tau = \tau \sigma ^2 \), where τ is the total holding period until sale; u and σ 2 are the single holding-period expected return and variance, respectively. Then we can rewrite Eqs. 20 and 21 as follows:

$$u_{L,\tau } = \tau u - \sqrt 3 \left( {L - 1} \right)\sqrt \tau \sigma ,$$
(43)
$$\sigma _{L,\tau }^2 = L^2 \tau \sigma ^2 .$$
(44)

Therefore, the average return and volatility per period can be expressed:

$$u_{L,\tau }^{{\text{period}}} = u - \frac{{\sqrt 3 \left( {L - 1} \right)\sigma }}{{\sqrt \tau }},$$
(45)
$$\sigma _{L,\tau }^{{\text{period}}} = L\sigma $$
(46)

The above two formula can be used to compute Table 1 with an assumed holding-period (5 years in our demonstration).

Similarly, from Eqs. 27 and 29 we can readily obtain:

$${\text{Var}}\left( {\tilde r_{\tilde L,\tau } } \right) = \left[ {\left( {E\left[ {\tilde L} \right]} \right)^2 + 4{\text{Var}}\left( {\tilde L} \right)} \right]\tau \sigma ^2 ,$$
(47)
$$E\left[ {\tilde r_{\tilde L,\tau } } \right] = \tau u - \sqrt 3 \left( {E\left[ {\tilde L} \right] - 1} \right)\sqrt \tau \sigma .$$
(48)

The average return and volatility per period can thus be written as:

$$u\left[ {\tilde r_{\tilde L,\tau } } \right]^{{\text{period}}} = u - \frac{{\sqrt 3 \left( {E\left[ {\tilde L} \right] - 1} \right)\sigma }}{{\sqrt \tau }},$$
(49)
$$\sigma \left( {\tilde r_{\tilde L,\tau } } \right)^{{\text{period}}} = \sqrt {\left[ {\left( {E\left[ {\tilde L} \right]} \right)^2 + 4{\text{Var}}\left( {\tilde L} \right)} \right]} \sigma .$$
(50)

The above two formula can be used to compute Table 2 with an assumed holding-period of 5 years.

Appendix 2

For demonstration purposes, we consider Scenario 3, where T max < NST and the allowable expected TOM is a uniform distribution over [T min, T max]. From Eq. 23, we have:

$$E\left[ {\tilde L} \right] = \frac{{{\text{NST}}\left( {T_{\max } + T_{\min } } \right)}}{{2T_{\max } T_{\min } }}.$$
(23′)

As we know, the “corresponding” allowable expected TOM in Table 2 is equal to \(\frac{{T_{\min } + T_{\max } }}{2}\), which is deterministic. As a result:

$$L = \frac{{{\text{NST}}}}{{\left[ {{{\left( {T_{\max } + T_{\min } } \right)} \mathord{\left/{\vphantom {{\left( {T_{\max } + T_{\min } } \right)} 2}} \right.\kern-\nulldelimiterspace} 2}} \right]}}$$
(51)

Since:

$$\begin{array}{*{20}l} {} \hfill & {\left( {T_{\max } - T_{\min } } \right)^2 > 0 \Rightarrow \frac{{T_{\max } + T_{\min } }}{2} > \frac{{2T_{\max } T_{\min } }}{{T_{\max } + T_{\min } }}} \hfill \\ \Rightarrow \hfill & {\frac{{{\text{NST}}\left( {T_{\max } + T_{\min } } \right)}}{{2T_{\max } T_{\min } }} > \frac{{{\text{NST}}}}{{\left[ {{{\left( {T_{\max } + T_{\min } } \right)} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{\left( {T_{\max } + T_{\min } } \right)} 2}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} 2}} \right]}}} \hfill \\ \end{array} $$

From Eqs. 23′ and 51, we thus have:

$$E\left[ {\tilde L} \right] >L.$$
(52)

Equation 52 together with Theorems 1 and 2 suggest that the expected returns under uncertain \(\tilde L\) are less than those with certain L even though the mean of “Possible distribution of expected TOM” in Table 2 is the same as the “Seller expected TOM” in Table 1, which is in fact consistent with the results in Tables 1 and 2.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Cheng, P., Lin, Z. & Liu, Y. Home Price, Time-on-Market, and Seller Heterogeneity Under Changing Market Conditions. J Real Estate Finan Econ 41, 272–293 (2010). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-009-9167-1

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11146-009-9167-1

Keywords

Navigation