Skip to main content
Log in

On the optimal number of representatives

  • Published:
Public Choice Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We propose a normative theory of the number of representatives based on a model of a representative democracy. We derive a formula giving the number of representatives as proportional to the square root of total population. Simple tests of the formula on a sample of a 100 countries yield good results. We then discuss the appropriateness of the number of representatives in some countries. It seems that the United States has too few representatives, while France and Italy have too many. The excess number of representatives matters: it is positively correlated with indicators of red tape and barriers to entrepreneurship.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Institutional subscriptions

Similar content being viewed by others

References

  • Aghion, P., & Bolton, P. (2003). Incomplete social contracts. Journal of the European Economic Association, 1, 38–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Auriol, E., & Gary-Bobo, R. J. (1999). On the optimal number of representatives. Discussion Paper No. 1286. Evanston, Illinois: Center for Mathematical Studies in Economics and Management Science, Northwestern University.

  • Auriol, E., & Gary-Bobo, R. J. (2007). On robust constitution design. Theory and Decision, 62, 241–279.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Auriol, E., & Gary-Bobo, R. J. (2007b). On the optimal number of representatives. Manuscript. http://ces.univ-paris1.fr/membre/Gary-Bobo/.

  • Auriol, E., & Warlters, M. (2005). Taxation base in developing countries. Journal of Public Economics, 89, 625–646.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Austen-Smith, D., & Banks, J. (1996). Information aggregation, rationality and the Condorcet jury theorem. American Political Science Review, 90, 34–45.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Balinski, M. L., & Young, H. P. (2001). Fair representation: meeting the ideal of one man one vote (2nd edn.). Washington: Brookings Institution Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Barbera, S., & Jackson, M. (2004). Choosing how to choose: self-stable majority rules and constitutions. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 119, 1011–1048.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Barro, R., & Lee, J.-W. (1994). Data set for a panel of 138 countries, available at www.nber.org/ftp/barro.lee/.

  • Becker, G. S. (1983). A theory of competition among pressure groups for political influence. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 98, 371–400.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bergemann, D., & Välimäki, J. (2002). Information acquisition and efficient mechanism design. Econometrica, 70, 1007–1033.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bernardo, J., & Smith, A. F. M. (1994). Bayesian theory. New York: Wiley.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Besley, T., & Coate, S. (1998). Sources of inefficiency in a representative democracy: a dynamic analysis. American Economic Review, 88, 139–156.

    Google Scholar 

  • Börgers, T. (2004). Costly voting. American Economic Review, 94, 57–66.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradbury, J. C., & Crain, W. M. (2001). Legislative organization and government spending: cross-country evidence. Journal of Public Economics, 82, 309–325.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bradbury, J. C., & Crain, W. M. (2002). Bicameral legislatures and fiscal policy. Southern Economic Journal, 68, 646–659.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Buchanan, J. M., & Tullock, G. (1962). The calculus of consent. Logical foundations of constitutional democracy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Casella, A. (2005). Storable votes. Games and Economic Behavior, 51, 391–419.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ciccone, A., & Papaioannou, E. (2007). Red tape and delayed entry. Journal of the European Economic Association, 5, 459–469.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Clarke, E. H. (1971). Multipart pricing of public goods. Public Choice, 8, 19–33.

    Google Scholar 

  • Compte, O., & Jehiel, P. (2007). Auctions and information acquisition: sealed-bid or dynamic formats? RAND Journal of Economics, 38, 355–372.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Dahl, R. A. (1970). After the revolution: authority in a good society. New Haven: Yale University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Dixit, A., Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1997). Common agency and coordination: general theory and application to government policy making. Journal of Political Economy, 105, 752–769.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Djankov, S., La Porta, R., Lopez-de-Silvanes, F., & Shleifer, A. (2002). The regulation of entry. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 117, 1–37.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Europa World Year Book (1995). London: Europa Publications Ltd.

  • Feddersen, T., & Pesendorfer, W. (1998). Convicting the innocent: the inferiority of unanimous jury verdicts under strategic voting. American Political Science Review, 92, 23–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gary-Bobo, R. J., & Jaaidane, T. (2000). Polling mechanisms and the demand revelation problem. Journal of Public Economics, 76, 203–238.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gerardi, D., & Yaariv, L. (2008). Information acquisition in committees. Games and Economic Behavior, 62, 436–459.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gersbach, H. (1995). Information efficiency and majority decisions. Social Choice and Welfare, 12, 363–370.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gersbach, H. (2000). Public information and social choice. Social Choice and Welfare, 17, 25–31.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gersbach, H. (2009). Democratic mechanisms. Journal of the European Economic Association, 7, 1436–1469.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, J., & Laffont, J. J. (1977). Imperfect personal information and the demand-revealing process: a sampling approach. Public Choice, 29, 79–94.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Green, J., & Laffont, J. J. (1979). Incentives in public decision-making. Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Groseclose, T. J., & Snyder, J. M. (1996). Buying supermajorities. American Political Science Review, 90, 303–315.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Groves, T. (1973). Incentives in teams. Econometrica, 41, 617–631.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Groves, T., & Loeb, M. (1975). Incentives and public inputs. Journal of Public Economics, 10, 187–217.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hansen, M. H. (1991). The Athenian democracy in the age of Demosthenes. Structures, principles and ideology. Oxford: Blackwell.

    Google Scholar 

  • Harsanyi, J. C. (1955). Cardinal welfare, individualistic ethics, and interpersonal comparisons of utility. Journal of Political Economy, 63, 309–321.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Holmström, B. (1979). Groves schemes on restricted domains. Econometrica, 47, 1137–1147.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ledyard, J. O. (1978). Incentive compatibility and incomplete information. Journal of Economic Theory, 18, 171–189.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Li, H. (2001). A theory of conservatism. Journal of Political Economy, 109, 617–636.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Manin, B. (1997). The principles of representative government. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Matthews, S. A. (1984). Information acquisition in discriminatory auctions. In: M. Boyer & R. Kihlstrom (Eds.), Bayesian models in economic theory (pp. 181–207). Amsterdam: North-Holland,

    Google Scholar 

  • McCormick, R. E., & Tollison, R. D. (1978). Legislatures as unions. Journal of Political Economy, 86, 63–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • McCormick, R. E., & Tollison, R. D. (1981). Politicians, legislation and the economy. Boston: Martinus Nijhoff.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • McCormick, R. E., & Turner, C. S. (2001). On legislatures and legislative efficiency wages. In: W.F. Shughart II & Laura Razzolini (Eds.), The Elgar companion to public choice. London: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Morgan, J., & Stocken, P. C. (2008). Information aggregation in polls. American Economic Review, 98, 846–896.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Morgan, J., & Vardy, F. (2007). On the buyability of voting bodies. Manuscript. Berkeley: University of California.

  • Moulin, H. (1986). Characterizations of the pivotal mechanism. Journal of Public Economics, 31, 53–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Moulin, H. (1988). Axioms of cooperative decision-making. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. C., Tollison, R. D., & Willett, T. D. (1972). Representative democracy via random selection. Public Choice, 12, 57–68.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Mueller, D. C. (2003). Public choice III. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Myerson, R. B. (1993). Effectiveness of electoral systems for reducing government corruption: a game-theoretic analysis. Games and Economic Behavior, 5, 118–132.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • O’Connor, K., & Sabato, L. (1993). American government, roots and reform. New York: McMillan.

    Google Scholar 

  • Osborne, M. J., & Slivinski, A. (1996). A model of political competition with citizen-candidates. Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111, 65–96.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Osborne, M. J., Rosenthal, J. S., & Turner, M. A. (2000). Meetings with costly participation. American Economic Review, 90, 927–943.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Palfrey, T. R., & Rosenthal, H. (1985). Voter participation and strategic uncertainty. American Political Science Review, 79, 62–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Penrose, L. S. (1946). The elementary statistics of majority voting. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, 109, 53–57.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Persico, N. (2004). Committee design with endogenous information. Review of Economic Studies, 71, 165–191.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Pole, J. R. (1987). The American constitution, for and against, the federalist and anti-federalist papers. New York: Hill and Wang.

    Google Scholar 

  • Roberts, K. (1979). The characterization of implementable choice rules. In: J.-J. Laffont (Ed.), Aggregation and revelation of preferences (Chap. 18). Amsterdam: North Holland.

    Google Scholar 

  • Stigler, G. (1976). The size of legislatures. Journal of Legal Studies, 5, 17–34.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Storing, H. J. (1981). The anti-federalist: writings by the opponents of the constitution. Selected by M. Dry from: The complete anti-federalist. Chicago: Chicago University Press.

  • de Tocqueville, A. (1835). De la démocratie en Amérique (Vol. 1). Reprinted 1981. Paris: Garnier-Flammarion.

    Google Scholar 

  • Treisman, D. (2000). The causes of corruption: a cross-national study. Journal of Public Economics, 76, 399–457.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Tullock, G. (1977). Practical problems and practical solutions. Public Choice, 39, 27–35.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Weingast, B.R., Shepsle, K.A. & Johnsen, C. (1981). The political economy of benefits and costs: a neoclassical approach to distributive politics. Journal of Political Economy, 89, 642–664.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • World Bank (1998). World development indicators, 1998. Washington, DC.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Robert J. Gary-Bobo.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Auriol, E., Gary-Bobo, R.J. On the optimal number of representatives. Public Choice 153, 419–445 (2012). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-011-9801-3

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127-011-9801-3

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation