Skip to main content
Log in

Understanding Agreements on TRIPS and Subsidies in Tandem

  • Research Article
  • Published:
Open Economies Review Aims and scope Submit manuscript

Abstract

We provide a theoretical framework to explain why governments seek stronger protection of IPRs and allow R&D subsidies through multilateral trade agreements such as the TRIPS Agreement and the Agreement on Subsidies. Our analysis indicates that it is globally optimal to disseminate knowledge without IPR protection and to subsidize inventive firms when issues of IPR protection and R&D subsidies are considered in tandem. R&D subsidies are a means of amending for damages to investors’ incentives by weak IPR protection. In addition, the TRIPS Agreement is understood as a victory of the interests of exporting countries over those of importing countries.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Under Article 8.2(a) of the SCM Agreement, R&D subsidies are non-actionable, but Article 31 regulates that non-actionable subsidies be applied until the end of 1999. However, at the formal meeting of the negotiating group on rules on May 6–8 2002, Canada suggested that a non-actionable subsidy category again be pursued, and WTO members are likely to agree that R&D subsidies be non-actionable in the Doha Development Agenda (DDA) negotiations.

  2. See Kang (2006) for the effects of R&D investments and IPR protections on output levels.

  3. See Proposition 1 in Kang (2006). In addition, refer to Kang (2006) for the effects of policy tools, R&D subsidies and IPR protection levels, on R&D investments.

  4. See Appendix B in Kang (2006).

  5. Suppose there are N firms in the home country and M firms in the foreign country. Then a domestic firm i would have the following marginal cost function depending on the R&D levels of domestic and foreign rivals, for instance, \( c_{i} = \alpha + c^{1} {\left( {x_{i} } \right)} + \theta c^{2} {\left( {x_{{ - i}} } \right)} + \theta c^{3} {\left( {{\sum {x*} }} \right)} \). Under these circumstances, each exporting country will provide stronger patent protection to boost the competition over domestic firms.

  6. I would like to thank an anonymous referee for suggesting this setup.

  7. See Appendix A.3 for the proof.

  8. See Appendix A.4 for calculations.

  9. See Appendix A.5 for the proof.

  10. This interpretation has its own limit. In general, IPR protection issues are related to confrontation between Northern and Southern countries having different status of production technology. However, our setup in this paper the third importing country has no ability to produce the final goods.

References

  • Bagwell K, Staiger RW (1994) The sensitivity of strategic and corrective R&D policy in oligopolistic industries. J Int Econ 36:133–150

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bagwell K, Staiger RW (2001) Domestic policies, national sovereignty and international economic institutions. Q J Econ 116:519–562

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Brander JA (1995) Strategic trade policy. In: Grossman GM, Rogoff K (eds) Handbook of International Economics: Volume III. Elsevier, pp 1395–1455

  • Chin JC, Grossman GM (1990) Intellectual property rights and north–south trade. In: Jones R, Krueger AO (eds) The Political Economy of International Trade. Blackwell, New York

    Google Scholar 

  • Deardorff AV (1992) Welfare effects of global patent protection. Economica 59:35–51

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Diwan I, Rodrik D (1991) Patents, appropriate technology, and north–south trade. J Int Econ 30:24–47

    Google Scholar 

  • Eaton J, Grossman GM (1986) Optimal trade and industry policy under oligopoly. Q J Econ 101:383–406

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Kang M (2006) Trade policy mix: IPR protection and R&D subsidies. Can J Econ 39:744–757

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Maggi G (1996) Strategic trade policies with endogenous mode of competition. Am Econ Rev 86:237–258

    Google Scholar 

  • Qiu LD, Tao Z (1998) Policy on international R&D cooperation: subsidy or tax? Eur Econ Rev 42:1727–1750

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Spencer BJ, Brander JA (1983) International R&D rivalry and industrial strategy. Rev Econ Stud 50:707–722

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor MS (1993) TRIPS, trade, and technology transfer. Can J Econ 26:625–637

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Taylor MS (1994) TRIPS, trade, and growth. Int Econ Rev 35:361–381

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The author would like to thank Robert W. Staiger, Robert E. Baldwin, M. Scott Taylor, the Managing Editor, an anonymous referee, and other seminar participants from the University of Wisconsin-Madison, the University of Alberta, Korea Institute for International Economic Policy, and Korea University for their helpful comments and suggestions. Responsibility for errors remains my own.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Moonsung Kang.

Appendices

Appendices

1.1 A.1 Proof of Proposition 1

Plugging first-order conditions of the non-cooperative Nash setup into those of the global optimum, \( W_{s} + W*_{s} + {\text{CS}}_{s} = 0 \); \( W_{{s*}} + W*_{{s*}} + {\text{CS}}_{{s*}} = 0 \); \( W_{\theta } + W*_{\theta } + {\text{CS}}_{\theta } = 0 \); \( W_{{\theta *}} + W*_{{\theta *}} + {\text{CS}}_{{\theta *}} = 0 \), we can show that Nash equilibrium policy levels are globally inefficient. Even though \( W_{s} = W_{{s*}} = W_{\theta } = W_{{\theta *}} = 0 \), the Nash policy set does not satisfy the first-order conditions of global optimization above because \( W*_{s} + {\text{CS}}_{s} \ne 0,W_{{s*}} + {\text{CS}}_{{s*}} \ne 0,W*_{\theta } + {\text{CS}}_{\theta } \ne 0 \), and \( W_{{\theta *}} + {\text{CS}}_{{\theta *}} \ne 0 \) .

1.2 A.2 Proof of Proposition 2

As discussed before, the sign of the reaction curve of R&D subsidies, ds/ds* = −W ss* /W ss , is identical to the sign of (W ss* ). One can show \( W_{{ss*}} = - bq*_{{z*}} z*_{s} {\left( {q_{z} z_{{s*}} + q_{{z*}} z*_{{s*}} } \right)} - \theta c_{{z*}} z*_{s} {\left( {q_{z} z_{{s*}} + q_{{z*}} z*_{{s*}} } \right)} = {\left( {q_{z} z_{{s*}} + q_{{z*}} z*_{{s*}} } \right)}{\text{ }}z*_{s} {\left( { - bq*_{{z*}} - {\text{ }}\theta c_{{z*}} } \right)} \). Since \( {\left( {q_{z} z_{{s*}} + {\text{ }}q_{{z*}} z*_{{s*}} } \right)} \) and \( z*_{s} \) are negative, the sign of (W ss* ) is equal to the sign of \( {\left( { - bq*_{{z*}} - \theta c_{{z*}} } \right)} \). Using Eq. 6 of Kang (2006), one can show \( - bq*_{{z*}} - \theta c_{{z*}} = {\left( {2 \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {2 3}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} 3} \right)}c*_{{z*}} {\left( {1 - 2\theta } \right)} \). Since \( c*_{{z*}} \) is negative, we can show W ss*  > 0 if θ > 1/2.

1.3 A.3 Effects of IPR Protection Levels on R&D Subsidies

Totally differentiating W s (θ, θ*) with respect to s, s*, and θ, one can form the following equation: \({\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{W_{{ss}} }} & {{W_{{ss*}} }} \\ {{W^{*}_{{s*s}} }} & {{W^{*}_{{s*s*}} }} \\ \end{array} } \right]}{\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{{{\text{d}}s} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\text{d}}s} {{\text{d}}\theta }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {{\text{d}}\theta }}} \\ {{{{\text{d}}s*} \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{{\text{d}}s*} {{\text{d}}\theta }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {{\text{d}}\theta }}} \\ \end{array} } \right]} = {\left[ {\begin{array}{*{20}c} {{ - W_{{s\theta }} }} \\ {{ - W^{*}_{{s*\theta }} }} \\ \end{array} } \right]}.\) Using this, we can have the Eq. 5. Since \( W_{{s\theta }} = G_{{z*\theta }} z*_{s} + G_{{z*}} z*_{{s\theta }} - s{\left( {\theta ,\theta *} \right)}z_{{s\theta }} ,z*_{s} = {G*_{{z*z}} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{G*_{{z*z}} } B}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} B,z*_{{s\theta }} = {G*_{{z*z\theta }} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{G*_{{z*z\theta }} } B}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} B \), and \( z_{{s\theta }} = {G*_{{z*z*\theta }} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{G*_{{z*z*\theta }} } B}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} B \), where \( B \equiv G_{{zz}} G*_{{z*z*}} - G_{{zz*}} G*_{{z*z}} > 0 \), one can show that \( W_{{s\theta }} \) is positive if θ > 1/2, but uncertain otherwise. In addition, using the similar method, one can show that \( W*_{{s*\theta }} = G*_{{z\theta }} z_{{s*}} + G*_{z} z_{{s*\theta }} - s*{\left( {\theta ,\theta *} \right)}z*_{{s*\theta }} \), and \( W*_{{s*\theta }} \) is positive if θ* > 1/2, but uncertain otherwise. Since W ss and W* s*s* are negative as the second-order conditions and \( {\text{W}}_{{{\text{s}}\theta }} \) and \( W*_{{s*\theta }} \) are positive under the weakly enforced IPR regime (θ and θ* > 1/2), ds/dθ and ds*/dθ are positive if (θ, θ*) ≥ 1/2.

1.4 A.4 Global Optimum

Using previous maximization problems for output, R&D investment, and R&D subsidies, one can show \( H_{\theta } = - G_{{z*}} {\left( {{G*_{{z*\theta }} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{G*_{{z*\theta }} } {G*_{{z*z*}} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {G*_{{z*z*}} }} \right)} + G_{\theta } - {\left( {{G_{{z*}} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{G_{{z*}} } {G*_{{z*z*}} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {G*_{{z*z*}} }} \right)}s*_{\theta } \) and \( H_{{*\theta }} = - G*_{z} {\left( {{G_{{z\theta }} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{G_{{z\theta }} } {G_{{zz}} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {G_{{zz}} }} \right)} + G*_{\theta } - {\left( {{G*_{z} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{G*_{z} } {G_{{zz}} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {G_{{zz}} }} \right)}s_{\theta } \). In addition, using a derivative of an integral, we can show the derivative of consumer surplus with respect to IPR protection level: \( {\text{CS}}_{\theta } = P\frac{{d{\left( {q + q*} \right)}}} {{d\theta }} - P\frac{{d{\left( {q + q*} \right)}}} {{d\theta }} - {\left( {q + q*} \right)}\frac{{{\text{d}}P}} {{{\text{d}}\theta }} = - {\left( {q + q*} \right)}{\left[ {\frac{{{\text{d}}P}} {{{\text{d}}q}}\frac{{{\text{d}}q}} {{{\text{d}}\theta }} + \frac{{{\text{d}}P}} {{{\text{d}}q*}}\frac{{{\text{d}}q*}} {{{\text{d}}\theta }}} \right]} \). Since (dP/dq) = (dP/dq*) = −b, we can rewrite this as follows: \( {\text{CS}}_{\theta } = b{\left( {q + q*} \right)}{\left[ {{\left( {z_{s} s_{\theta } + z_{{s*}} s*_{\theta } + z_{\theta } } \right)}{\left( {q_{z} + q*_{z} } \right)} + {\left( {z*_{s} s_{\theta } + z*_{{s*}} s*_{\theta } + z*_{\theta } } \right)}{\left( {q_{{z*}} + q*_{{z*}} } \right)} + q_{\theta } + q*_{\theta } } \right]} \). It turns out \( {\text{CS}}_{\theta } \) is always positive because the third importing country will be better off since weak IPR protection will lead higher subsidies, inducing higher production of the final goods and lower prices. For \( H_{\theta } \) and \( H*_{\theta } \), one can rewrite these as follows: \( H_{\theta } = G_{{z*}} {\left[ {z*_{\theta } - {\left( {{z*_{s} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{z*_{s} } {z_{s} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {z_{s} }} \right)}z_{\theta } } \right]} + G_{\theta } + G_{{z*}} {\left[ {z*_{{s*}} - {\left( {{z*_{s} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{z*_{s} } {z_{s} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {z_{s} }} \right)}z_{{s*}} } \right]}s*_{\theta } \) and \( H*_{\theta } = G*_{z} {\left[ {z_{\theta } - {\left( {{z_{{s*}} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{z_{{s*}} } {z*_{{s*}} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {z*_{{s*}} }} \right)}z*_{\theta } } \right]} + G*_{\theta } + G*_{z} {\left[ {z_{s} - {\left( {{z_{{s*}} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{z_{{s*}} } {z*_{{s*}} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {z*_{{s*}} }} \right)}z*_{s} } \right]}s_{\theta } \). Interestingly, the first two terms, \( G_{{z*}} {\left[ {z*_{\theta } - {\left( {{z*_{s} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{z*_{s} } {z_{s} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {z_{s} }} \right)}z_{\theta } } \right]} + G_{\theta } \) and \( G*_{z} {\left[ {z_{\theta } - {\left( {{z_{{s*}} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{z_{{s*}} } {z*_{{s*}} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {z*_{{s*}} }} \right)}z*_{\theta } } \right]} + G*_{\theta } \), are identical to \( W_{\theta } \) and \( W*_{\theta } \) in Kang (2006) that we considered both exporting countries simultaneously set IPR protection and R&D subsidies, and the final terms, \( G_{{z*}} {\left[ {z*_{{s*}} - {\left( {{z*_{s} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{z*_{s} } {z_{s} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {z_{s} }} \right)}z_{{s*}} } \right]}s*_{\theta } \) and \( G*_{z} {\left[ {z_{s} - {\left( {{z_{{s*}} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{z_{{s*}} } {z*_{{s*}} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {z*_{{s*}} }} \right)}z*_{s} } \right]}s_{\theta } \), are new parts representing the sequential policy moves of governments. Checking signs of every component in \( H_{\theta } \) and \( H*_{\theta } \), one can conclude that \( H_{\theta } + H*_{\theta } + {\text{CS}}_{\theta } > 0 \) implying the globally optimal IPR protection level is 1. In addition, plugging this result to the optimal subsidy rates that we found in the second stage, we conclude the globally optimal subsidies are positive.

1.5 A.5 Joint Optimum

Using results of Appendix A.4., we can rewrite Eq. 17 as follows: \( H_{\theta } + H*_{\theta } + \lambda _{1} - \lambda _{2} = - G_{{z*}} {\left( {{G*_{{z*\theta }} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{G*_{{z*\theta }} } {G*_{{z*z*}} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {G*_{{z*z*}} }} \right)} + G_{\theta } - {\left( {{G_{{z*}} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{G_{{z*}} } {G*_{{z*z*}} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {G*_{{z*z*}} }} \right)}s*_{\theta } - G*_{z} {\left( {{G_{{z\theta }} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{G_{{z\theta }} } {G_{{zz}} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {G_{{zz}} }} \right)} + G*_{\theta } - {\left( {{G*_{z} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{G*_{z} } {G_{{zz}} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {G_{{zz}} }} \right)}s_{\theta } + \lambda _{1} - \lambda _{2} = 0 \). Given this equation, we analyze every possible case for the optimization problem.

Case 1: θ = 0.

In this case, the slackness condition implies that λ 1 ≥ 0 and λ 2 = 0, having \( \lambda _{1} = - {\text{ }}H_{\theta } - H*_{\theta } \). Checking signs of the components when θ = 0, we can show that λ 1 is negative. It violates the slackness condition, which means that it has a contradiction.

Case 2: θ = 1.

In this case, the slackness condition implies that λ 1 = 0 and λ 2 ≥ 0, having \( \lambda _{2} = H_{\theta } {\text{ }} + H*_{\theta } \). Checking the signs of components when θ = 1, we can show that the sign of λ 2 is negative. It violates the slackness condition, which means that it has a contradiction.

Case 3: 0 < θ < 1.

In this case, the slackness condition implies that λ 1 = λ 2 = 0, having \( H_{\theta } + H*_{\theta } = 0 \). One can rewrite this condition as follows: \( - G_{{z*}} {\left( {{G*_{{z*\theta }} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{G*_{{z*\theta }} } {G*_{{z*z*}} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {G*_{{z*z*}} }} \right)} + G_{\theta } - {\left( {{G_{{z*}} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{G_{{z*}} } {G*_{{z*z*}} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {G*_{{z*z*}} }} \right)}s_{{*\theta }} - G*_{z} {\left( {{G_{{z\theta }} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{G_{{z\theta }} } {G_{{zz}} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {G_{{zz}} }} \right)} + G_{{*\theta }} - {\left( {{G*_{z} } \mathord{\left/ {\vphantom {{G*_{z} } {G_{{zz}} }}} \right. \kern-\nulldelimiterspace} {G_{{zz}} }} \right)}s_{\theta } = 0 \). Since \( G*_{{z*\theta }} < 0 \), \( G*_{{z*z*}} < 0,G_{{zz}} < 0,G_{{z\theta }} > 0 \), and \( G_{\theta } + G*_{\theta } > 0 \), we can conclude that G z* and \( G^{*}_{z} \) must be negative to hold the above equation. According to Proposition 1 in Kang (2006), the optimal IPR policy will be given as 0 < θ C < 1/2. In addition, the optimal R&D subsidy is still positive under the strongly enforced IPR regime.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Kang, M. Understanding Agreements on TRIPS and Subsidies in Tandem. Open Econ Rev 20, 225–240 (2009). https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-007-9062-4

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s11079-007-9062-4

Keywords

JEL Classification

Navigation