Skip to main content
Log in

Do institutions for collective action evolve?

  • Published:
Journal of Bioeconomics Aims and scope

Abstract

In this paper I will provide an overview of our findings from studying irrigation systems in the field so that readers who are not familiar with our prior research gain at least an initial sense of these findings. I will provide a second short overview —this time of the institutional analysis and development (IAD) framework offering a general method for doing institutional analysis. I will then introduce the possibility of looking at the change of rules as an evolutionary process. The method for studying the evolution of rules will be based on the IAD framework and on our long-term study of rules related to irrigation systems. In the conclusion, I return to the question as to why it is important to authorize resource users’ relative autonomy in the development of their own rules and to learn from the resulting institutional diversity.

This is a preview of subscription content, log in via an institution to check access.

Access this article

Price excludes VAT (USA)
Tax calculation will be finalised during checkout.

Instant access to the full article PDF.

Fig. 1
Fig. 2

Similar content being viewed by others

Notes

  1. Readers who would like to gain an overview of the type of research undertaken at the Workshop over the years may wish to look at the 2005 special issue of the Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization (vol. 57, no. 2) edited by Peter J. Boettke on “Polycentric Political Economy.”

  2. Currently, there is considerable rebel activity in Nepal that is disrupting many activities especially in the countryside and creating many tragedies for Nepali farmers. The findings discussed in this paper are based on data, most of which was collected in earlier peaceful times.

  3. Readers who wish to dig deeper are encouraged to read Lam (1998), Joshi et al. (2000), and Shivakoti and Ostrom (2001) and the extensive references cited therein.

  4. See special issue, Policy Studies Journal 39(1) (2011).

  5. Sue Crawford and I have worked hard over more than a decade to clarify the close link between these three concepts. We have developed a grammar that can be used to “parse” each of them. For example, each rule can be parsed into five components that specify: (1) the attributes of a participant (such as age, education, gender) affected by a rule; (2) the deontic modal verb of the rule, which include “may” (permitted), “must” (obliged), and “must not” (forbidden); (3) where the rule aims—at the set of potential actions or the outcomes of the situation; (4) the conditions specifying when and where an action or outcome is permitted, obligatory, or forbidden; and (5) the consequences specified for not following a rule (the “or else”) (see Crawford and Ostrom 2005).

  6. Ganesh Shivakoti reported on visiting an irrigation system officially under “joint management” in Nepal only to find that the farmers did not know who had been selected to be on their council, whether they had ever met, and what kind of policies had been adopted.

  7. When only a single governing authority makes decisions about rules for an entire region, policymakers have to experiment simultaneously with all of the common-pool resources within a jurisdiction with each policy change. And, once a change has been made and implemented, further changes will not be made rapidly. The process of experimentation will usually be slow, and information about results may be contradictory and difficult to interpret. Thus, an experiment that is based on erroneous data about one key structural variable or one false assumption about how actors will react, can lead to a very large disaster. In any design process where there is substantial probability of error, having redundant teams of designers has repeatedly been shown to have considerable advantage (see Landau 1969, 1973; Bendor 1985).

  8. In a Roman-law country, the default conditions would be entirely different since Roman-law systems presume that most things are forbidden unless specifically permitted.

  9. The proto rule statements for boundary, choice, and payoff rules are the rules that Tang (1992) identified as the most frequently observed rules in his meta-analysis of irrigation cases located in many different countries. The proto rule statements for the other rules are derived from extensive field research regarding irrigation systems in many countries—particularly Nepal. They are the rules that I have frequently encountered (see Joshi et al. 2000; Shivakoti and Ostrom 2001).

  10. We have long relied on the symbols used in deontic logic for modal operators. For background, see Hilpinen (1981) and von Wright (1951); von Wright (1963).

  11. The rules set for any one interaction situation are always affected by rules determined by larger regimes—such as the inheritance rules in force.

  12. To keep this paper from growing exponentially, I will not discuss here their effort to constitute a new association and to establish a mechanism that can make collective-choice decisions regarding the rules that they will use in the future. One could be keeping an inventory of rules at a constitutional, collective choice, and operational level to keep track of the processes and changes involved.

  13. Heterogeneity among resource users can lead to very substantial transaction costs in trying to find rules that most participants find fair and are willing to follow. Varughese and Ostrom (2001) found that when farmers with strong locational heterogeneity were able to devise unique rules for their use of a local forest, the heterogeneity did not lead to lowered performance. Of course, they would have paid somewhat higher transaction costs in working out rules that allowed some farmers to obtain wood based on labor inputs and other farmers to obtain wood based on monetary payments.

  14. Several scholars have been studying customary law and multiple countries. Bosselman (2005) has been particularly concerned with what characteristics of the process of customary law lead to relatively resilient systems. Bosselman asks this question in Chap. 6 of a book with Peter Ørebech. He reviews a large number of cases and identifies five characteristics of those systems that he thinks have demonstrated a capacity to adapt in sustainable ways. These are:

    1. 1.

      Does the system have a good historical record, oral or written, of the way the system has worked in the past under different environmental conditions?

    1. 2.

      Is an effective procedural mechanism for making rule changes built into the system?

    2. 3.

      Does the system feed back the right information on current operations into the rule modification process?

    3. 4.

      Are the rules sufficiently finely detailed that they can be “tweaked” without wholesale revision?

    4. 5.

      Do the rules facilitate negotiation of modifications by providing for a balance of rights and responsibilities relating to a wide range of ecosystem functions? (Bosselman 2005, p. 176).

    In our effort to code rule change processes, we will add some of these questions to our coding forms as well as the seven characteristics that I have identified in the text.

References

  • Acheson, J., & Gardner, R. (2004). Strategies, conflict, and the emergence of territoriality: The case of the Maine lobster industry. American Anthropologist, 106(2), 296–307.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Alchian, A. A. (1950). Uncertainty, evolution, and economic theory. Journal of Political Economy, 58(3), 211–221.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • APROSC and JMA. (1995). Nepal agriculture perspective plan (final report)—Main document. Kathmandu, Nepal: Agricultural Projects Service Center and John Miller Associates.

  • Arthur, W. B. (1989). Competing technologies, increasing returns, and lock-in by historical events. Economic Journal, 99, 116–131.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Axelrod, R. (1984). The evolution of cooperation. New York: Basic Books.

    Google Scholar 

  • Baker, M. (2005). The Kuhls of Kangra: Community managed irrigation in the western Himalaya. Seattle: University of Washington Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bardhan, P. K. (2000). Irrigation and cooperation: An empirical analysis of 48 irrigation communities in South India. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 48(4), 847–865.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Bardhan, P. K., & Dayton-Johnson, J. (2002). Unequal irrigators: Heterogeneity and commons management in large-scale multivariate research. In E. Ostrom, T. Dietz, N. Dolšak, P. Stern, S. Stonich, & E. Weber (Eds.), The drama of the commons (pp. 87–112). National Research Council (Committee on the Human Dimensions of Global Change). Washington, DC: National Academies Press.

  • Bendor, J. (1985). Parallel systems: Redundancy in government. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Benjamin, P., Lam, W. F., Ostrom, E., & Shivakoti, G. (1994). Institutions, incentives, and irrigation in Nepal. Decentralization: Finance & management project report. Burlington, VT: Associates in Rural Development.

    Google Scholar 

  • Bosselman, F. (2005). Adaptive resource management through customary law. In P. Orebech, F. Bosselman, J. Bjarup, D. Callies, M. Chanock, & H. Petersen (Eds.), The role of customary law in sustainable development (pp. 176–200). Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

  • Bousquet, F., Barreteau, O., d’Aquino, P., Etienne, M., Boissau, S., Aubert, S., Le Page, C., Babin, D., & Castella, J.-C. (2002). Multi-agent systems and role games: Collective learning processes for ecosystem management. In M. Janssen (Ed.), Complexity and ecosystem management: The theory and practice of multi-agent systems (pp. 248–285). Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

  • Boyd, R., & Richerson, P. J. (1985). Culture and the evolutionary process. Chicago, IL: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, D. T. (1969). Reforms as experiments. American Psychologist, 24(4), 409–429.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Campbell, D. T. (1975). On the conflicts between biological and social evolution and between psychology and moral tradition. American Psychologist, 30(11), 1103–1126.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cardenas, J.-C. (2000). How do groups solve local commons dilemmas? Lessons from experimental economics in the field. Environment, Development and Sustainability, 2, 305–322.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cardenas, J.-C., & Ostrom, E. (2004). What do people bring into the game? Experiments in the field about cooperation in the commons. Agricultural Systems, 82(3), 307–326.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cardenas, J.-C., Stranlund, J., & Willis, C. (2000). Local environmental control and institutional crowding-out. World Development, 28(10), 1719–1733.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Cox, J. (2004). How to identify trust and reciprocity. Games and Economic Behavior, 46, 260–281.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Crawford, S., & Ostrom, E. (2005). A grammar of institutions. In E. Ostrom (Ed.), Understanding institutional diversity (pp. 137–174). Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. (Originally published in American Political Science Review, 89(3), 582–600, 1995.)

  • Easterly, W. (2001). The elusive quest for growth: Economists’ adventures and misadventures in the tropics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Eggertsson, T. (1990). Economic behavior and institutions. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ensminger, J., & Knight, J. (1997). Changing social norms: Common property, bridewealth, and clan exogamy. Current Anthropology, 38(1), 1–24.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Evans, P. (2004). Development as institutional change: The pitfalls of monocropping and the potentials of deliberation. Studies in Comparative International Development, 39(4), 30–52.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Faysse, N. (2005). Coping with the tragedy of the commons: Game structure and design of rules. Journal of Economic Surveys, 19(2), 239–261.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frohlich, N., Oppenheimer, J., & Kurki, A. (2004). Modeling other-regarding preferences and an experimental test. Public Choice, 119(1–2), 91–117.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Frohlich, N., Oppenheimer, J., & Young, O. (1971). Political leadership and collective goods. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gautam, U., Agrawal, N. K., & Subedi, R. (Eds.). (1992). Nepal: Managing large surface irrigation project: A participatory review. Study document NEP/89/006. Kathmandu, Nepal: Department of Irrigation and Consolidated Management Services.

  • Gibson, C., Andersson, K., Ostrom, E., & Shivakumar, S. (2005). The Samaritan’s dilemma: The political economy of development aid. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Gibson, C., McKean, M., & Ostrom, E. (Eds.). (2000). People and forests: Communities, institutions, and governance. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Gibson, C. C., Williams, J. T., & Ostrom, E. (2005). Local enforcement and better forests. World Development, 33(2), 273–284.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Gintis, H. (2004). The genetic side of gene-culture coevolution: Internalization of norms and prosocial emotions. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 53(1), 57–67.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Greif, A., & Laitin, D. D. (2004). A theory of endogenous institutional change. American Political Science Review, 98(4), 633–652.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Güth, W., & Kliemt, H. (1998). The indirect evolutionary approach: Bridging the gap between rationality and adaptation. Rationality and Society, 10(3), 377–399.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hardin, G. (1968). The tragedy of the commons. Science, 162, 1243–1248.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Hayes, T. M., & Ostrom, E. (2005). Conserving the world’s forests: Are protected areas the only way? Indiana Law Review, 38(3), 595–617.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hilpinen, R. (Ed.). (1981). New studies in deontic logic: Norms, actions, and the foundations of ethics. Dordrecht: D. Reidel.

    Google Scholar 

  • Hodgson, G. M. (2004). The evolution of institutional economics: Agency, structure and Darwinism in American institutionalism. London: Routledge.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Jacob, F. (1977). Evolution and tinkering. Science, 196(4295), 1161–1166.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Janssen, M. A. (Ed.). (2002). Complexity and ecosystem management: The theory and practice of multi-agent systems. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.

    Google Scholar 

  • Janssen, M. A. (2007). Coordination in irrigation systems: An analysis of the Lansing–Kremer model of Bali. Agricultural Systems, 93, 170–190.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Janssen, M., Anderies, J. M., & Ostrom, E. (2007). Robustness of social-ecological systems to spatial and temporal variability. Society and Natural Resources, 20(4), 307–322.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Janssen, M., & Ostrom, E. (2006). Governing social-ecological systems. In L. Tesfatsion & K. L. Judd (Eds.), Handbook of computational economics: Agent-based computational economics (Vol. 2, pp. 1465–1509). Amsterdam: Elsevier.

    Google Scholar 

  • Joshi, N. N., Ostrom, E., Shivakoti, G., & Lam, W. F. (2000). Institutional opportunities and constraints in the performance of farmer-managed irrigation systems in Nepal. Asia-Pacific Journal of Rural Development, 10(2), 67–92.

    Google Scholar 

  • Kiser, L., & Ostrom, E. (1982). The three worlds of action: A metatheoretical synthesis of institutional approaches. In E. Ostrom (Ed.), Strategies of political inquiry (pp. 179–222). Beverly Hills, CA: Sage.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lam, W. F. (1998). Governing irrigation systems in Nepal: Institutions, infrastructure, and collective action. Oakland, CA: ICS Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lam, W. F., Lee, M., & Ostrom, E. (1994). An institutional analysis approach: Findings from the NIIS on irrigation performance. In J. Sowerwine, G. Shivakoti, U. Pradhan, A. Shukla, & E. Ostrom (Eds.), From farmers’ fields to data fields and back: A synthesis of participatory information systems for irrigation and other resources (pp. 69–93). Colombo, Sri Lanka: International Irrigation Management Institute, and Rampur, Nepal: IAAS.

  • Lam, W. F., & Shivakoti, G. P. (2002). Farmer-to-farmer training as an alternative intervention strategy. In G. P. Shivakoti & E. Ostrom (Eds.), Improving irrigation governance and management in Nepal (pp. 204–221). Oakland, CA: ICS Press.

  • Landau, M. (1969). Redundancy, rationality, and the problem of duplication and overlap. Public Administration Review, 29(4), 346–358.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Landau, M. (1973). Federalism, redundancy, and system reliability. Publius, 3(2), 173–196.

    Google Scholar 

  • Lansing, J. S. (1991). Priests and programmers: Technologies of power in the engineered landscape of Bali. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Levi, M. (1988). Of rule and revenue. Berkeley: University of California Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Libecap, G. D. (1989). Contracting for property rights. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • McCay, B. J., & Acheson, J. M. (1987). The question of the commons: The culture and ecology of communal resources. Tucson: University of Arizona Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Miller, G. (1992). Managerial dilemmas: The political economy of hierarchy. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Nelson, R., & Winter, S. G. (1982). An evolutionary theory of economic change. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Netting, R. M. C. (1974). The system nobody knows: Village irrigation in the Swiss Alps. In T. E. Downing & M. Gibson (Eds.), Irrigation’s impact on society (pp. 67–75). Tucson: University of Arizona Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Netting, R. M. C. (1981). Balancing on an Alp: Ecological change and continuity in a Swiss mountain community. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (1990). Institutions, institutional change and economic performance. New York: Cambridge University Press.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • North, D. C. (2005). Understanding the process of institutional change. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • NRC (National Research Council). (1986). Proceedings of the conference on common property resource management. Washington, DC: National Academies Press.

  • NRC (National Research Council). (2002). The drama of the commons. In E. Ostrom, T. Dietz, N. Dolšak, P. Stern, S. Stonich, & E. Weber (Eds.), Committee on the human dimensions of global change. Washington, DC: National Academies Press.

  • Orbell, J. M., Schwarz-Shea, P., & Simmons, R. T. (1984). Do cooperators exit more readily than defectors? American Political Science Review, 78, 147–162.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ørebech, P., Bosselman, F., Bjarup, J., Callies, D., Chanock, M., & Petersen, H. (2005). The role of customary law in sustainable development. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1992). Crafting institutions for self-governing irrigation systems. San Francisco, CA: ICS Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1995). Self-organization and social capital. Industrial and Corporate Change, 4(1), 131–159.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1998). A behavioral approach to the rational choice theory of collective action. American Political Science Review, 92(1), 1–22.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (1999). Coping with tragedies of the commons. Annual Review of Political Science, 2, 493–535.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (2005). Understanding institutional diversity. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (2007). A diagnostic approach for going beyond panaceas. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 104(39), 15181–15187.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E. (2010). Beyond markets and states: Polycentric governance of complex economic systems. American Economic Review, 100(3), 641–672.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E., Gardner, R., & Walker, J. (1994). Rules, games, and common-pool resources. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, E., Lam, W. F., Pradhan, P., & Shivakoti, G. (2011). Improving irrigation in Asia: Sustainable performance of an innovative intervention in Nepal. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.

    Book  Google Scholar 

  • Ostrom, V. (1997). The meaning of democracy and the vulnerability of democracies: A response to Tocqueville’s challenge. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pitman, G. (2002). Bridging troubled waters: Assessing the WB water resources strategy. Washington, DC: WP-Operations Evaluation Department.

    Google Scholar 

  • Poteete, A., Janssen, M., & Ostrom, E. (2010). Working together: Collective action, the commons, and multiple methods in practice. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pradhan, P. (1989). Increasing agricultural production in Nepal: Role of low-cost irrigation development through farmer participation. Kathmandu, Nepal: International Irrigation Management Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Pritchett, L., & Woolcock, M. (2004). Solutions when the solution is the problem: Arraying the disarray in development. World Development, 232(2), 191–212.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Rapoport, A. (1966). Two-person game theory: The essential ideas. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Regmi, A. (2007). The role of group heterogeneity in collective action: A look at the intertie between irrigation and forests. Case studies from Chitwan, Nepal. PhD dissertation, Indiana University.

  • Richerson, P. J., & Boyd, R. (2005). Not by genes alone: How culture transformed human evolution. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Satz, D., & Ferejohn, J. (1994). Rational choice and social theory. Journal of Philosophy, 91(2), 71–87.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K. A. (1979). Institutional arrangements and equilibrium in multidimensional voting models. American Journal of Political Science, 23(1), 27–59.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shepsle, K. A. (1989). Studying institutions: Some lessons from the rational choice approach. Journal of Theoretical Politics, 1(2), 131–149.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • Shivakoti, G., & Ostrom, E. (2001). Improving irrigation governance and management in Nepal. Oakland, CA: ICS Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Shukla, A., Gajurel, K., Shivakoti, G. P., Poudel, R., Pandit, K. N., Adhikari, K. R., Thapa, T., Shakya, S. M., Yadav, D. N., Joshi, N. R., Shrethsa, A. P. (1993). Irrigation resource inventory of East Chitwan. Rampur, Chitwan, Nepal: Institute of Agriculture and Animal Science, Irrigation Management Systems Study Group.

  • Stake, J. E. (2004). The property ‘instinct’. Working paper. Indiana University, Maurer School of Law, Bloomington.

  • Tang, S. Y. (1992). Institutions and collective action: Self-governance in irrigation. San Francisco, CA: ICS Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Tsebelis, G. (1990). Nested games: Political context, political institutions and rationality. Berkeley: University of California Press.

  • Turral, H. (1995). Recent trends in irrigation management: Changing directions for the public sector. London: Overseas Development Institute.

    Google Scholar 

  • Varughese, G., & Ostrom, E. (2001). The contested role of heterogeneity in collective action: Some evidence from community forestry in Nepal. World Development, 29(5), 747–765.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Wright, G. H. (1951). Deontic logic. Mind, 60, 1–15.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • von Wright, G. H. (1963). Norm and action: A logical enquiry. London: Routledge and Kegan Paul.

    Google Scholar 

  • Walker, J. M., Gardner, R., Herr, A., & Ostrom, E. (2000). Collective choice in the commons: Experimental results on proposed allocation rules and votes. Economic Journal, 110(460), 212–234.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  • WECS/IIMI (Water and Energy Commission Secretariat, Nepal, and International Irrigation Management Institute). (1990). Assistance to farmer-managed irrigation systems: Results, lessons and recommendations from an action-research project. Colombo, Sri Lanka: International Irrigation Management Institute.

  • Williamson, O. E. (1985). The economic institutions of capitalism: Firms, markets, relational contracting. New York: Free Press.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, D. S. (2007). Evolution for everyone: How Darwin’s theory can change the way we think about our lives. New York: Random House.

    Google Scholar 

  • Wilson, D. S., & Gowdy, J. (2011). Evolution as a general theory for economics and public policy. Working paper, Binghamton University, Binghamton, NY.

  • Winpenny, J. T. (1994). Managing water as an economic resource. New York: Routledge.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yoder, R. D. (1991a). Assistance to farmer managed irrigation systems: Experiences from WECS/IIMI/FORD action research project in Indrawati Watershed Basin. In N. Ansari & P. Pradhan (Eds.), Assistance to farmer-managed irrigation systems: Experience from Nepal. Kathmandu, Nepal: Ministry of Water Resources, Department of Irrigation, Planning Design and Research Division.

    Google Scholar 

  • Yoder, R. D. (1991b). Peer training as a way to motivate institutional change in farmer-managed irrigation systems. In Proceedings of the workshop on democracy and governance, decentralization: Finance & management project report (pp. 53–67). Burlington, VT: Associates in Rural Development.

  • Yudelman, M. (1985). The World Bank and agricultural development: An insider’s view. World Resources Paper no. 1. Washington, DC: World Resources Institution.

Download references

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Additional information

This paper draws sections from the annual Neale Wheeler Watson Lecture presented at the Nobel Museum, Stockholm, Sweden, April 12, 2008, and “Crafting Analytical Tools to Study Institutional Change” (with Xavier Basurto), 2011. I am appreciative of support from the National Science Foundation, the MacArthur Foundation, and a current project with David Sloan Wilson supported by the Templeton Foundation. Thanks also to the colleagues who have given me excellent feedback on earlier drafts—Sue Crawford, Nicolas Faysse, Robert Holahan, Marco Janssen, and Brian Steed—and to Patty Lezotte for all of her great spirit and editing skills.

Rights and permissions

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Ostrom, E. Do institutions for collective action evolve?. J Bioecon 16, 3–30 (2014). https://doi.org/10.1007/s10818-013-9154-8

Download citation

  • Published:

  • Issue Date:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1007/s10818-013-9154-8

Keywords

Navigation