Introduction

Worldwide, health policy makers are confronted with ageing populations and rising demand for long-term careFootnote 1 (LTC) and are looking for ways to guarantee access to LTC services in a sustainable way. Barr (2010) argues that there is a strong case for public provision of LTC insurance. Indeed, virtually all OECD countries have at least some publicly provided mandatory coverage against LTC expenditures. Several of these countries have integrated some “medical” LTC services in their public health insurance schemes, e.g. Belgium, Switzerland and the US Medicare and Medicaid programs. Other countries have a separate public LTC insurance scheme, e.g. the Netherlands (since 1968), Germany (since 1995), Japan (since 2000) and South-Korea (since 2002).

Typically, public LTC insurance is provided by public non-competing insurers who are not at risk for the LTC expenses of their enrollees (Costa-Font and Courbage 2012). For instance, in the Netherlands LTC insurance is administered by about 30 regional insurers that are fully reimbursed for the LTC expenses of their clients that are covered by the public scheme. As a consequence, these public insurers have no incentives to secure that high-quality LTC services are provided at low cost. To control expenditures in public LTC insurance, governments have traditionally relied on demand rationing (e.g. means testing, copayments and coverage restrictions), and supply rationing (e.g. price regulation, provider budgets, and capacity restrictions) (Costa-Font and Courbage 2012). Both types of rationing, however, have important drawbacks, which are likely to be exacerbated by the expected increase in demand for LTC. Demand-side rationing may result in access problems for low-income individuals who need LTC; supply-side rationing may result in waiting lists and substandard quality of care.

In several countries, another way to encourage efficient use of LTC has been introduced or proposed: to provide LTC insurers with incentives to contract efficient LTC providers. This could be achieved by putting LTC insurers at risk for providing LTC coverage and allowing them to compete for customers. However, competition among risk-bearing insurers is likely to jeopardize universal access because LTC expenses are typically high and correlated over time (Van Barneveld et al. 1997) and consequently actuarially fair premiums will be unaffordable to many people needing LTC.

To combine competition with universal access in social health insurance markets, several countries have introduced a system of managed competition in which insurers cannot reject applicants and are required to charge community-rated premiums to all applicants. To guarantee affordable access to coverage, insurers receive risk-adjusted premium subsidiesFootnote 2 that eliminate or at least reduce incentives to increase profits through risk selectionFootnote 3. These subsidies reduce differences in expected costs between individuals and thus make all applicants equally attractive for an insurer (Enthoven 1988; Van de Ven and Ellis 2000).

Managed competition has been proposed and implemented to ensure equitable access to public LTC insurance (Medicaid) in the US and increase its efficiency (Lucas 1996). In Switzerland and Belgium, medical LTC is integrated in social health insurance coverage that is offered by risk-bearing competing health insurers, although the financial risk for Belgian insurers is quite limited (OECD 2011; Schokkaert and van de Voorde 2011; Weaver 2012; Willeme et al. 2012). Recently, the Dutch government launched a similar proposal. According to this proposal, managed competition will be introduced for home care in 2015 and after 2 years insurers should bear the full risk for covering home health benefits. To this end, coverage for home care is included in the social health insurance benefit package. Managed competition may also be introduced for nursing home care after 2017 (Rijksoverheid 2013).

An appropriate system of risk-adjusted premium subsidies is crucial to safeguarding universal access in a competitive LTC insurance market. However, whereas risk adjustment in health insurance has been studied extensively, empirical research on risk adjustment in LTC insurance is nearly nonexistent. The aim of this paper is to examine how and to what extent a system of risk adjusted subsidies can reduce the financial incentives for risk selection in LTC insurance within the context of managed competition. To this end, the following five questions are addressed: (1) How do LTC expenditures differ from expenditures on medical care and how do these differences affect the options to use risk adjustment to reduce risk selection? (2) What are the predicted losses and gains on LTC for insurers in case of annual contracts, community rating and no risk adjustment? (3) To what extent are the predicted losses and gains reduced by the most comprehensive risk-adjustment model based on data on: (i) demographic characteristics, (ii) prior LTC use and (iii) prior health care expenditures (HCE) and inpatient hospital diagnoses? (4) What is the contribution of each of these sets of risk adjusters to the reduction of the predicted losses and gains in the most comprehensive risk-adjustment model? (5) How are the predicted losses and gains affected when the risk adjusters that provide substantial perverse incentives to insurers are removed from the risk adjustment model?

What is already known about risk adjustment in long-term care?

The experience with risk adjustment in health insurance cannot be readily used to develop an appropriate risk adjustment system for LTC insurance. LTC expenditures differ from health care expenditures (HCE) in at least two important aspects (Van de Ven 2005). First, LTC expenditures are concentrated among a limited group of beneficiaries, and are, conditional upon use, high and stable over time. Consequently, in the absence of risk adjustment, risk selection based on prior expenditures is much easier in LTC insurance than in health insurance. Second, the availability of informal care is expected to have a much larger impact on LTC expenditures than on HCE. But there is little experience with including informal care availability in risk adjustment and the availability of informal care is difficult to quantify with administrative data. Hence, differences in informal care availability cannot be fully captured by the risk adjustment formula.

Little is known about how these issues can be dealt with and about how to design appropriate risk adjustment for LTC insurance. To date, there is only one study about the feasibility of risk adjustment in Dutch LTC insurance (Van Barneveld et al. 1997). With prior LTC expenditure as a risk adjuster and using data from one sickness fund, Van Barneveld et al. (1997) examine the remaining potential for risk selection in the Dutch public LTC insurance scheme. They find an \(\hbox {R}^{2}\)-statistic of 0.90, which indicates that LTC expenditures are highly predictable at the individual level when information on prior expenditures is available.

Using prior expenditures as a risk adjuster means that the insurer will be partly or fully compensated for higher expenditures through higher future risk-adjusted capitation payments. This compensation may give insurers incentives for overprovision. Hence, compared to the situation of capitation payments that are not based on prior expenditures, insurers face fewer incentives for an efficient provision and allocation of LTC. Marchand et al. (2003) show that despite this drawback, if insurers compete on quality, they receive stronger incentives to be efficient when risk adjustment is based on prior expenditures or prior use than when they are fully reimbursed for all expenditures.

Several studies on risk adjustment in US Medicare and Medicaid have tackled similar issues. While the Medicare benefit package does not include LTC, the target population of Medicare is similar and studies on risk adjustment in Medicare therefore provide a number of relevant insights. First, risk adjustment for Medicare Advantage plans and for the Medicaid Program of All-Inclusive Care for the Elderly (PACE) takes into account frailty as measured by the number of activities of daily living (ADL) problems; a risk adjustment model without frailty was found to systematically underestimate expenditures for the frail elderly and might therefore induce risk selection against this group (Kautter et al. 2009). Second, the relationship between health care use in the past, demographic characteristics and future health expenditures changes upon institutionalization and it is different for those who became eligible for Medicare by reaching the age of 65 and those who became eligible because they were disabled (Pope et al. 2004). This finding implies that risk adjusters should be interacted with institutionalization and age. Third, incentives for risk selection persist despite extensive risk adjustment: while risk selection on expected costs decreased after expanding the risk adjustment formula beyond age and gender, insurers now select profitable enrollees by focusing on characteristics not included in the model. Consequently, the Medicare program has become more expensive spending on those in good health increases vis-à-vis spending on those in bad health (Brown et al. 2011).

Outside the US, experience with risk adjustment in LTC insurance is limited to Switzerland and Belgium. In these countries, medical LTC is included in social health insurance. In Switzerland, the risk adjustment formula comprises age, gender and a dummy variable accounting for a recent stay of at least three days in a hospital or a LTC facility (Von Wyl 2014). This dummy variable is likely to pick up some of the variation in expected LTC expenditures. The Belgian risk adjustment formula includes more LTC-specific risk adjusters. The capitation payment is adjusted for receipt of certain allowances (e.g. for handicapped or because of a need for assistance) or nursing care at home during 3 months (category B or C on the Katz-scale (Katz and Akpom 1976)). In addition, the risk adjustment formula includes a number of indicators related to LTC use, e.g. living alone, being widow/widower, physiotherapy for a severe illness, and Parkinson’s disease (Schokkaert and van de Voorde 2011). While the Belgian risk adjustment formula is more sophisticated than the one used in Switzerland, the financial risk is much more limited for Belgian than for Swiss health insurers (Schokkaert and van de Voorde 2011; Paolucci et al. 2007). Therefore, risk selection against LTC patients appears to be financially attractive in Switzerland but not in Belgium. It is, however, unclear whether the more sophisticated Belgian model would suffice to prevent risk selection if financial risk for insurers were expanded.

Data and methods

Data

We use information from five nationwide administrative registries and one survey which are all linked by Statistics Netherlands at the individual levelFootnote 4 . The administrative data would be readily available if risk adjustment were implemented and include (1) health care expenditures in 2000–2004 from the health insurance data collected by Vektis; (2) use of LTC in 2004 and 2005, which includes home care, social assistance, assistance with activities of daily living and inpatient stays in either a residential home or a nursing home and which comes from the Central Administration Office of the LTC insurance scheme (CAK); (3) hospital admissions in 2002, 2003 and 2004 from the hospital discharge register (LMR); (4) demographic information for 2004 from the municipal register (GBA) and (5) mortality from the cause-of-death registry (CBS). In addition, the General Survey of Living Conditions (POLS) held in 2004 provides details on health, disability, and other individual characteristics for a randomly drawn, representative sample of the non-institutionalized population. Prior health care expenditures are registered for sickness fund enrollees only (two-thirds of the population)Footnote 5 and LTC use is registered for adults only (\(\ge \)18 years of age); the other administrative data sets comprise the entire Dutch population.

The sample was further reduced for two reasons. First, the records for one third of those eligible for sickness fund coverage cannot not be linked. Second, 1.7 % of the sample was excluded because of item non-response which always was the result of missing co-residence status. As a result, the final sample consists of individuals who were insured through a sickness fund, did not die in 2004 and whose records could be linked to the municipality register. The total study population was 5,719,934, which is 45 % of the Dutch adult population in 2004. From this subset of the population, 7,790 individuals were included in the 2004 POLS survey; 3,619 of these respondents also completed the more specific health module.

Methods

A good risk adjustment system should reduce insurers’ incentives for risk selection while maintaining their incentives for efficiency. Ideally, after risk adjustment there are no easily identifiable subgroups for which insurers are undercompensated or overcompensated. In addition to an accurate prediction of individual expenditures, good risk adjusters should provide appropriate incentives and should be administratively feasible (Van de Ven and Ellis 2000). Partly following Beck et al. (2010) and Shen and Ellis (2002) among others, we identify the extent to which a risk adjustment model can reduce incentives for risk selection in three steps. First, we measure the insurers’ incentives to select against subgroupsFootnote 6 based on individual characteristics in case of community-rated annual contracts but in the absence of risk adjustment. To quantify the insurers’ incentives for risk selection, we calculate the difference between the average actual expenditures by subgroup and the average expenditures for the entire population in 2005. We consider the incentives for risk selection to be strong when the number of users in the subgroup is substantial \((>\)300), the predicted loss for a person in this group—the difference between observed expenditures for this subgroup and average expenditures for the entire population—is large (\(>\)1,000 euro) and significantly \((p < 0.05)\) different from zero. When these criteria are met, the benefits of risk selection are likely to exceed the costs and therefore the subgroup is included in the risk-adjustment model.

Second, we build the full risk adjustment model in a stepwise manner to examine to what extent each set of individual characteristics contributes to explaining individual variation in LTC use. To this end, we estimate a series of four models. We first test the impact of a basic model based on demographic characteristics on the predicted loss for all subgroups. Next, we add subgroups based on (i) prior LTC use, and (ii) prior health care expenditures and hospital admissions to this basic model variables. The full model includes all subgroups that were identified in the first model. For each risk adjustment model, the remaining predicted loss is the difference between the observed expenditures for these subgroups and the expenditures predicted by the risk adjustment model.

Third, for each subgroup that is included in the full model, we assess the impact of including this subgroup in the risk adjustment formula on the insurers’ incentives for efficiency—a commonly used selection criterion (see e.g. Van Kleef and Van Vliet (2010), Van de Ven and Ellis (2000) and Pope et al. (2000)). Subgroups that are likely to have a negative impact on the insurers’ incentives for efficiency are those for which conditions of eligibility can be easily manipulated by insurers and for which it is highly attractive for them to do so. Manipulation may be financially attractive when the expected benefits exceed the costs, which consist of the required effort and the cost of the additional treatment that the enrollee is required to receive to be eligible for the subgroup. Excluding these subgroups from the full model results in an incentive compatible risk adjustment model. This third step thus sheds light on the tradeoff between creating incentives for efficiency and incentives for risk selection.

All five models described above are estimated by ordinary least squares regression (OLS) in order to facilitate interpretation of the results (Van de Ven and Ellis 2000)Footnote 7. Moreover, all current Dutch risk adjustment models use OLS, so using OLS increases the comparability and compatibility with these models.

The POLS sample was very small compared to the population of sickness fund enrollees and therefore the subgroups based on detailed information about health status, disability and socio-economic status from the POLS survey are not included in the risk adjustment model. Instead these subgroups are used as a benchmark to evaluate the impact of the risk adjustment model on incentives for risk selection.

Variables

In each of the models, the dependent variable measures public LTC expenditures in 2005. In case the individual dies in 2005, expenditures are annualized by dividing expenditures by the share of the year the individual was alive. The data set provides information on the quantity of LTC that was provided in kind, which was 95 % of the publicly financed LTC in the Netherlands in 2006Footnote 8 (CVZ 2011). The quantities provided, i.e. days institutionalized or hours of home care, are multiplied by the maximum prices as set by the government in order to calculate expenditures; co-payments are not taken into account. The data contains information about institutional care use in 2004 and 2005 and about all use of six types of home care in 2004. For 2005, the data contained information about use of only four out of six types of home careFootnote 9.

The set of subgroups that make up the basic model are based on three demographic characteristics: age, gender and co-residence, i.e. whether someone lived in a single-person household. Age and gender are the backbone of any risk-adjustment model, while co-residence proxies informal care availability. Informal care availability is an element of the eligibility assessment procedure for homecare (CIZ 2005) and formal LTC use is known to be correlated with informal LTC use (Bonsang 2009; Van Houtven and Norton 2004).

The subgroups of LTC users are based on prior LTC use rather than expenditures because using prior LTC use as a risk adjuster rewards insurers for negotiating lower prices with providers. Subgroups are created for each type of home care and each type of institutional care separately. Each of the subgroups of home care users consists of individuals who used this specific type of home care at least 1 hour per week on average. In selecting subgroups of institutional care users, we aim at balancing responsiveness to changes in LTC use against incentives for overreporting and oversupply resulting from the (partial) reimbursement of additional expenditures in the future. Therefore, for each of the four types of institutional care, four subgroups are generated consisting of individuals who stayed in an LTC institution for \(\ge \)1 day, 91–180 days, 181–365 days, and the entire year (366 days), respectively. These subgroups reflect differences in expected future expenditures between long-term and short-term residents: future expenditures are positively correlated with the number of days that the individual is institutionalized. Furthermore, following Van Barneveld et al. (1997), two subgroups are created consisting of patients who received home care and institutional care, respectively, on the last day of 2004, which shows the size of the predictable loss for enrollees who only use a very small amount of LTC in the prior year.

We also include subgroups based on prior HCE. Each of these subgroups measures health care expendituresFootnote 10 that are associated with LTC use: expenditures on hospital and outpatient care, prescription drugs, paramedical care, transportation, and durable medical equipment. For each of these categories, three subgroups are constructed that consist of persons who are among the 15 % who had the highest expenditures during the last year (omitted for hospital and outpatient expenditures), during each of the last 3 years, and during each of the last 5 years. Because the data only includes HCE covered by sickness funds, we also include a variable indicating which persons were not insured through a sickness fund in one of the 4 years preceding 2004. If someone was no longer registered with a sickness fund during a year, e.g. because of losing his/her eligibility status due to exceeding the income threshold, and hence is not in the data set for the entire year, expenditures are annualized.

In addition to the subgroups based on prior HCE, we also create subgroups based on hospital admissions because information on hospitalization and diagnosis information may help to predict LTC use (Wong et al. 2010). Subgroups are based on 94 diagnoses (based on a grouping algorithm of ICD-9 codes, see Polder et al. 2002) and on 48 types of treatments (based on ICD-9-CM volume 3 codes) using hospital admission data from 2002–2004. In addition, we create 12 Diagnostic Cost Groups (DCGs). DCGs are used for risk adjustment in the Dutch health insurance scheme and consist of clinically homogenous inpatient diagnoses for chronic health problems that have similar future HCE (Van de Ven and Ellis 2000). Using the ICD-code of the main diagnosis and the medical specialty that set this diagnosis, each individual is assigned to either the reference group (DCG 0)—people with no hospital admission or an incidental admission (e.g. fractures)—or the highest DCG they are eligible for (Rijksoverheid 2005; Prinsze and van Vliet 2007)Footnote 11. We include the DCGs but not the separate subgroups based on diagnoses and treatments in the risk adjustment model because the subgroups based on diagnosis and treatments and the DCGs overlap. Furthermore, the impact of the DCGs on the incentives for efficiency is known to be limited in the context of health insurance (Lamers 1998) while including all subgroups separately will increase incentives for oversupply and over-reporting.

As the administrative data do not provide detailed information on personal characteristics, subgroups based on health, disability and socio-economic characteristics could only be created using the smaller set of respondents that completed the POLS survey. Although it is much smaller and persons in nursing homes are not sampled, this survey allows investigating incentives for insurers to use such questionnaires for risk selection purposes. The same subgroups are used as in De Meijer et al. (2011), who study determinants of LTC expenditures among the elderly, and in Stam and van de Ven (2008), who identify subgroups that generate losses for health insurers. Of these subgroups, only those are selected for which the predicted loss deviates significantly from zero in the absence of risk adjustment. Because the average predicted profit without risk adjustment for the POLS sample and the subsample answering the health module are positive, the predictions for these samples are adjusted by subtracting the mean deviation from zero for the relevant sample multiplied by the ratio of the individual’s observed expenditures to the sample mean observed expenditures in order to ensure that the average predicted profit was zero for this subsample.

Results

Descriptive statistics

Figure 1 and Table 1 show that the distribution of LTC expenditures is highly skewed. The median is at 4,598 euro; 2 out of 3 LTC users spend less than 10,000 euro. Furthermore, there are two spikes, one at 32,000 euro (a full year of care in a residential home) and one at approximately 91,000 euro (a full year of care in a nursing home). The average cost per LTC user (15,677 euro) is much higher than the average cost per user of medical care (about 2000 euro in 2004). Furthermore, LTC expenditures are strongly correlated with prior use of LTC: average LTC expenditures in 2005 are higher for home care users in 2004 than for non-users and highest for nursing home residents in 2004 (Table 1).

Fig. 1
figure 1

Distribution of LTC expenditures in 2005 of LTC users in 2005

Table 1 Descriptive statistics population

Analysis

The regression analysis reveals that the included covariates explain a large share of the variation in aggregate expenditures of LTC use in 2005: the \(\hbox {R}^{2}\)-statistics are generally higher than those obtained in similar studies on medical care and mental health care (see e.g. Van de Ven and Ellis 2000)Footnote 12. Most of the explanatory power derives from the demographic variables and prior LTC use. The model that only includes demographics has an \(\hbox {R}^{2}\) of 0.23. Including prior LTC use increases the \(\hbox {R}^{2}\)-statistic to 0.73, while variables related to prior HCE contribute only marginally to the overall goodness of fit, regardless of whether prior LTC use is included. A Copas test (Copas 1983) did not detect overfitting and therefore we do not need to split the sample in two. Nearly all coefficients are significant in each of the models and show the expected sign. The DCGs sometimes violate the monotonicity requirement: being assigned to a higher DCG with a more severe diagnosis does not in all cases lead to a higher capitation payment. This is undesirable as it generates disincentives for providing more care in cases in which more care might be desirable. The most prominent example is DCG 4, which includes diagnoses related to a cardiovascular accident; myocardial infarct; and angina pectoris among other things, and which has the third largest coefficient. These results highlight that the relationship between prior hospital stays and LTC expenditures is different from the relationship between prior hospital stays and HCE, on the basis of which these DCGs were constructed.

No risk adjustment model

In case of annual contracts with community rated premiums but no risk adjustment, the predicted losses would be very large for subgroups based on prior LTC use or based on prior health care expenditures (Table 2)Footnote 13. These predicted losses, together with the large size of most of these subgroups (last column), signal that incentives for risk selection against these subgroups would be huge. Other results (available upon request) show that some diagnoses are indicators of a persistent loss: for four diagnoses that yield a large predicted loss in the next year, the predicted loss is still larger than 1,000 euro 2 years later and 3 years later.

Table 2 Predicted losses for selected subgroups

Demographic model

The results for the Demographic Model, which adjusts subsidies for the age, gender and co-residence status of the enrollee, show that including demographic characteristics in the risk adjustment model does not sufficiently reduce the predicted losses for subgroups based on prior LTC use and prior HCE (Table 2). Therefore, it seems imperative to include the latter subgroups in the risk adjustment model to reduce incentives for risk selection.

Prior LTC model

Including variables on prior LTC use as risk adjusters by definition reduces the predicted losses on these subgroups to zero. But risk adjustment based on prior LTC use not only reduces predicted losses for prior LTC users but also for many subgroups based on prior HCE and for several subgroups of individuals who were hospitalized for diagnoses that were associated with the highest predicted loss without risk-adjustment (Table 2). This finding implies that it is no longer attractive for insurers to select against any of these groups of patients. For some other subgroups based on prior health care use and on HCE, however, including variables on prior LTC use as risk adjusters does not substantially reduce the predicted losses. Therefore, insurers have an incentive to detect and avoid these subgroups, which are not included in the risk adjustment formula and which are expected to generate a loss to the insurer.

Prior HCE and DCG model

Subsequently, we examine the effect of adding information on prior health care use and HCE patterns in the risk adjustment formula on the predicted losses. The predicted losses for the subgroups of insured that used LTC in 2004 all remain above the threshold of 1,000 euro when DCGs are added to the model, along with variables indicating high expenditures (top 15 %) on hospital and outpatient care for the last three and the last five years, and high expenditures on prescription drugs, transport, and durable medical equipment for the last year, the last 3 and the last 5 years (Table 2). But while these variables only have a small impact on the predicted loss for subgroups of LTC users, including HCE is important for reducing the predicted loss for subgroups based on prior hospital admissions for several diagnoses, e.g. heart failure, and asthma and COPD. So while for some diagnoses prior LTC use is more important in reducing the predicted loss, for other diagnoses prior HCE and DCGs causes the largest drop in the predicted losses.

Full model

When all information is combined in the full risk adjustment model, the predicted losses are substantially reduced for many of the subgroups we distinguished. For example, this full model reduces predicted losses sufficiently for all but seventeen diagnoses and for all but one type of treatment. Yet, including information on prior HCE and the variables on LTC use also leads to predicted profits larger than 1,000 euro for three diagnoses: hip fracture, chronic ulcers of skin including decubitus (Table 2) and other lower extremity fracture (not in Table 2).

The initial predicted losses also vanish for the subgroups based on self-reported disability, health and socio-economic status when prior LTC use and prior HCE are included in the risk adjustment formula. Although the loss is still larger than 1,000 euro for persons who are unable able to perform at least one ADL, it is no longer significantly different from zero (Table 2).

Incentive compatible model

All subgroups based on prior LTC use and listed in Table 2 are large and generate a large predicted loss in the absence of risk adjustment. Yet, some of these subgroups are expected to give insurers perverse incentives because inclusion of enrollees in these subgroups is financially attractive and can be easily manipulated. For example, the required additional spending for admitting a person for a single day in a nursing home (about 190 euro—see Table 3 in Appendix) is much lower than the subsequent increase in the risk-adjusted capitation payment of 11,299 euro for the subgroup of people who are admitted to a nursing home for 1–90 days. Table 3 in Appendix shows that when an individual uses LTC during a given year, in the next year the insurer would be compensated for most of the loss if risk adjustment were based on prior LTC utilization.

The trade-off between incentives for efficiency and incentives for risk selection is also relevant for some subgroups based on prior HCE and health care use. For some subgroups, the inclusion criteria are set at low levels because very few individuals use these services, e.g. individuals with high expenditures on transportation or medical equipment. As a result, for these groups the minimum amount of expenditures is lower than the increase in the risk adjustment payment. Therefore, the subgroups based on only high expenditures in the previous year are omitted in the incentive compatible model. For DCGs and subgroups with high HCE in successive years the incentive problem is expected to be limited (Van de Ven and Ellis 2000).

Leaving subgroups that were expected to compromise insurers’ incentives for efficiency out of the incentive compatible model has a small effect on the overall predictive power of the model: the incentive compatible model has an \(\hbox {R}^{2}\)-statistic of 0.70, compared to 0.73 for the full model. A comparison of the results of the full model and the incentive compatible model at the subgroups level reveals that removing these risk adjusters does not only affect the predicted losses for the subgroups that are no longer included but also the predicted losses for subgroups based on hospital diagnoses and treatments and for the subgroups based on detailed survey information on health and disability. Yet, the impact on the predicted losses for these other subgroups is often fairly limited. Therefore, further reduction of the number of subgroups in the risk adjustment model may be considered.

Conclusion and discussion

In the Netherlands and several other countries, public LTC insurance is offered by non-competing agents that are not at risk for providing coverage. This situation is suboptimal because it provides these agents with little or no incentive for efficiency and cost containment. In the Netherlands, the government proposed to incentivize insurers to increase efficiency and innovation of LTC provision by putting them at risk for providing LTC coverage and allowing them to compete for customers and thus let them reap the benefits of improvements in quality and reduced expenditures. Introducing financial risk would be easy but might lead to socially undesired outcomes in terms of equity and efficiency.

To maintain universal access in a competitive LTC insurance market, an adequate system of risk-adjusted premium subsidies is imperative. Without adequate risk adjustment insurers face strong incentives to deter subgroups that generate predictable losses, e.g. by excluding relevant benefits from the benefit package or by lowering the service level or the quality of the contracted provider network that they offer to these subgroups (Cao and McGuire 2003). We have investigated the scope for risk selection and the feasibility of a LTC risk adjustment formula that sufficiently reduces insurers’ financial incentives for risk selectionFootnote 14. The attractiveness of managed competition vis-à-vis alternative ways to organize LTC insurance depends inter alia on the ability to prevent risk selectionFootnote 15. Little is known, however about the feasibility of adequate risk adjustment for LTC. Hence, improved knowledge about the extent to which risk adjustment can successfully reduce insurers’ incentives for risk selection helps us to better evaluate the feasibility of managed competition in LTC insuranceFootnote 16.

Our findings demonstrate that a model that is only based on demographic characteristics performs poorly: subgroups that may be identified based on their prior LTC use, prior HCE or other individual characteristics are predicted to generate large losses to the insurer in case of annual contracts with community rated premiums. This means that in this case, insurers will face very strong financial incentives to discourage these subgroups from joining their plan.

Subsequently, we investigated the impact of (1) including individual-level information on prior health care and LTC use and (2) excluding risk adjusters that compromise insurers’ incentives for efficiency. Not surprisingly, prior use of LTC services is the best available predictor of future LTC use and its inclusion substantially reduces incentives for risk selection. The main drawback of this risk adjuster is that it simultaneously reduces incentives for efficiency. This problem may at least partially be overcome by (i) including indicators for having used LTC for multiple years because it may be harder for insurers to manipulate use and expenditures for multiple subsequent years than for just one yearFootnote 17 and (ii) by optimizing the DCGs for predicting LTC expendituresFootnote 18.

An important finding is that in addition to prior LTC use, prior HCE and inpatient diagnosis and treatment information also prove to be vital: predicted losses persist for certain categories of HCE and for some inpatient diagnoses that occur mostly among the frail elderly even when prior LTC use is taken into account. These diagnoses probably indicate a negative health shock that leads to increased formal LTC use. However, including all available risk adjusters in the model does not fully eliminate the potential for risk selection. While the predicted losses disappear for health, disability and socio-economic characteristics that can be obtained from a survey, risk selection on the basis of some inpatient diagnoses and treatments as well as prior LTC use remains feasible. An insurer can easily identify most of these subgroups, e.g. the subgroup of patients who received short-term institutional LTC, were admitted to a hospital for a hip fracture, dementia-related problems or asthma or COPD, or who had high HCE in 2004 but not in 2003 or 2002. Yet, including these variables in the risk adjustment formula is not an option, as it would give insurers an incentive to overprovide these types of health care.

Ideally, risk adjustment is based on data on individuals’ underlying needs for care but such information is rarely included in administrative data and insurers’ LTC claims data. As a consequence, in the Netherlands and elsewhere, risk adjustment in LTC will have to rely on prior utilization and expenditure data, which is likely to not only reduce incentives for risk selection but also incentives for efficiency. Most of all, our findings highlight the interrelatedness of elderly care, medical care and social care. This implies that, in order to prevent risk selection, any risk adjustment formula needs to take into account the potential simultaneous or subsequent use of these other types of care. Therefore, our findings also have implications for the reverse relationship: taking into account prior LTC use should also be considered and studied for optimizing risk adjustment in health insurance.